首页 > 最新文献

Review of Industrial Organization最新文献

英文 中文
The Expansion of Incentive (Performance-Based) Regulation of Electricity Distribution and Transmission in the United States 美国配电和输电激励性(基于绩效)监管的扩展
IF 1.1 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-06-17 DOI: 10.1007/s11151-024-09973-x
Paul L. Joskow

I examine developments in the application of performance-based regulation (PBR) to electricity distribution and transmission in the United States. Applications of comprehensive PBR to electricity distribution had been slow to diffuse in the U.S. prior to roughly 2000. PBR mechanisms are now being applied more frequently to electricity distribution, which reflects the changing structure of the electric power industry and the increasing obligations that are being placed on electric distribution companies. The new obligations are a consequence primarily of aggressive targets for decarbonizing the electricity sector in nearly half the states and the goal of using “clean” electricity to electrify transportation, buildings, and other sectors. PBR should be viewed as a set of “building blocks” that can be adopted in various combinations and should recognize that PBR and traditional cost-of-service regulation (COSR) are properly viewed as complements rather than substitutes. Recent reforms in the regulation of distribution companies in Great Britain—“RIIO”—have been influential in the U.S. The main reforms contained in RIIO are discussed. There has been essentially no application of PBR by the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) to owners of transmission assets or to independent transmission operators. FERC has applied targeted incentives to encourage investment in transmission facilities and membership in independent system operator organizations. However, the regulation of transmission rates relies primarily on COSR in the form of formula rates and has poor incentive properties. Regulation of independent system operators is a challenge because they are non-profit organizations with no equity to put at risk. Reforms here are suggested.

我研究了美国在配电和输电领域应用基于绩效的监管(PBR)的发展情况。大约在 2000 年之前,美国在配电领域应用全面的 PBR 的速度一直很慢。现在,基于绩效的监管机制越来越多地应用于配电领域,这反映了电力行业结构的变化以及配电公司承担的义务越来越多。新义务的产生主要是由于近半数州对电力行业去碳化的积极目标,以及利用 "清洁 "电力实现交通、建筑和其他行业电气化的目标。应将 PBR 视为一套 "构件",可以通过不同的组合加以采用,并应认识到 PBR 和传统的服务成本监管 (COSR) 是互补而非替代的。英国最近对配电公司监管的改革--"RIIO"--对美国产生了影响。联邦能源管理委员会 (FERC) 基本上没有对输电资产所有者或独立输电运营商实施 PBR。联邦能源管理委员会采取了有针对性的激励措施,鼓励对输电设施进行投资和加入独立系统运营商组织。然而,对输电费率的监管主要依赖于公式费率形式的 COSR,其激励性较差。对独立系统运营商的监管是一项挑战,因为它们是非营利组织,没有股权风险。建议在此进行改革。
{"title":"The Expansion of Incentive (Performance-Based) Regulation of Electricity Distribution and Transmission in the United States","authors":"Paul L. Joskow","doi":"10.1007/s11151-024-09973-x","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-024-09973-x","url":null,"abstract":"<p>I examine developments in the application of performance-based regulation (PBR) to electricity distribution and transmission in the United States. Applications of comprehensive PBR to electricity distribution had been slow to diffuse in the U.S. prior to roughly 2000. PBR mechanisms are now being applied more frequently to electricity distribution, which reflects the changing structure of the electric power industry and the increasing obligations that are being placed on electric distribution companies. The new obligations are a consequence primarily of aggressive targets for decarbonizing the electricity sector in nearly half the states and the goal of using “clean” electricity to electrify transportation, buildings, and other sectors. PBR should be viewed as a set of “building blocks” that can be adopted in various combinations and should recognize that PBR and traditional cost-of-service regulation (COSR) are properly viewed as complements rather than substitutes. Recent reforms in the regulation of distribution companies in Great Britain—“RIIO”—have been influential in the U.S. The main reforms contained in RIIO are discussed. There has been essentially no application of PBR by the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) to owners of transmission assets or to independent transmission operators. FERC has applied targeted incentives to encourage investment in transmission facilities and membership in independent system operator organizations. However, the regulation of transmission rates relies primarily on COSR in the form of formula rates and has poor incentive properties. Regulation of independent system operators is a challenge because they are non-profit organizations with no equity to put at risk. Reforms here are suggested.</p>","PeriodicalId":47454,"journal":{"name":"Review of Industrial Organization","volume":"170 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2024-06-17","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141506184","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Getting Merger Guidelines Right 正确掌握合并准则
IF 1.1 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-05-19 DOI: 10.1007/s11151-024-09967-9
Keith N. Hylton

This paper is on the new (2023) Merger Guidelines. It makes several arguments: First, that the Guidelines should be understood as existing in a political equilibrium. Second, that the new structural presumption of the Merger Guidelines–HHI = 1,800—is too strict, and that an economically reasonable revision in the structural presumption would have increased rather than decreased the threshold. Whereas the new Guidelines lowers the threshold to HHI 1,800 from HHI 2,500, an economically reasonable revision would have increased the threshold to HHI 3,200. I justify this argument using a bare-bones model of Cournot competition. Third, it seems unlikely, as an empirical matter, that merger enforcement under the existing Guidelines is socially desirable. Fourth, that federal merger enforcement raises serious constitutional issues–which were originally discussed in 1904—and that it may be time now, in view of the new Guidelines, to return to these foundational constitutional questions.

本文是关于新的《合并准则》(2023 年)。它提出了几个论点:首先,《指南》应被理解为存在于政治平衡之中。其次,新《并购指南》的结构性推定--HHI=1,800--过于严格,如果对结构性推定进行经济上合理的修订,应该提高而不是降低门槛。新《指南》将门槛从 HHI 2,500 降至 HHI 1,800,而经济上合理的修订则会将门槛提高至 HHI 3,200。我使用库诺竞争的基本模型来证明这一论点。第三,从经验来看,根据现行《指南》实施兼并似乎并不符合社会利益。第四,联邦兼并执法引发了严重的宪法问题--这些问题最初是在 1904 年讨论的--鉴于新《指南》的出台,现在也许是时候回到这些基础性的宪法问题上来了。
{"title":"Getting Merger Guidelines Right","authors":"Keith N. Hylton","doi":"10.1007/s11151-024-09967-9","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-024-09967-9","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This paper is on the new (2023) Merger Guidelines. It makes several arguments: First, that the Guidelines should be understood as existing in a political equilibrium. Second, that the new structural presumption of the Merger Guidelines–<i>HHI</i> = 1,800—is too strict, and that an economically reasonable revision in the structural presumption would have increased rather than decreased the threshold. Whereas the new Guidelines lowers the threshold to <i>HHI</i> 1,800 from <i>HHI</i> 2,500, an economically reasonable revision would have increased the threshold to <i>HHI</i> 3,200. I justify this argument using a bare-bones model of Cournot competition. Third, it seems unlikely, as an empirical matter, that merger enforcement under the existing Guidelines is socially desirable. Fourth, that federal merger enforcement raises serious constitutional issues–which were originally discussed in 1904—and that it may be time now, in view of the new Guidelines, to return to these foundational constitutional questions.</p>","PeriodicalId":47454,"journal":{"name":"Review of Industrial Organization","volume":"15 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2024-05-19","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141145864","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The 2023 Merger Guidelines: Law, Fact, and Method 2023 年合并指南:法律、事实和方法
IF 1.1 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-05-18 DOI: 10.1007/s11151-024-09963-z
Herbert Hovenkamp

The final version of the 2023 Merger Guidelines, which were issued in December 2023, is a vast improvement over an earlier draft—which indicates that the Agencies took the many comments that they received on a draft very seriously. These Guidelines break some new ground that older Guidelines did not address, and make many positive contributions, which this paper spells out. They are also excessively nostalgic for a past era, however, and this may explain their propen sity to treat empirical questions as issues of law: This is one way to insulate these Guidelines from further revision. The excessive reliance on one decision, Brown Shoe, is unfortunate—particularly since that decision has been so often repudiated, even by the Supreme Court itself. This paper pays particular attention to: the Guidelines’ treatment of structural triggers and direct measures of competitive effects; their aggressive position on potential competition mergers; their willingness to weigh a “trend” toward concentration as a factor; and their treatment of serial acquisitions. The Guidelines include a welcome new section on mergers involving multi-sided networks, although their view of networks is too one-sided; and the Guidelines also contain an expanded section on mergers with harmful effects on suppliers—including labor. The Guidelines’ treatment of market definition is likely to lead to underenforcement because they define markets too broadly. Finally, the Guidelines could have made better use of recent retrospective studies—many of which would have provided further support for the substantive positions that the Guidelines take.

2023 年合并指南》的最终版本于 2023 年 12 月发布,与之前的草案相比有了很大的改进,这表明各机构非常认真地对待了他们收到的关于草案的许多意见。这些《指南》突破了旧版《指南》没有涉及的一些新领域,并做出了许多积极贡献,本文对此进行了详细阐述。然而,它们也过分怀念过去的时代,这也许是它们倾向于把经验问题当作法律问题来 处理的原因:这是使这些准则免于进一步修订的一种方式。过度依赖布朗鞋案这一判决是不幸的,尤其是该判决经常遭到否定,甚至遭到最高法院本身的否定。本文特别关注:《指导原则》对结构性触发因素和竞争效应直接衡量标准的处理;对潜在竞争兼并的积极立场;将集中 "趋势 "作为衡量因素的意愿;以及对连续收购的处理。指南》新增了关于涉及多方网络的兼并的章节,尽管其对网络的看法过于片面,但仍值得欢迎;《指南》还新增了关于对供应商(包括劳动力)产生有害影响的兼并的章节。指南》对市场定义的处理很可能导致执行力度不足,因为它们对市场的定义过于宽泛。最后,《指南》本可以更好地利用近期的回顾性研究--其中许多研究本可以为《指南》所采取的实质性立场提供进一步的支持。
{"title":"The 2023 Merger Guidelines: Law, Fact, and Method","authors":"Herbert Hovenkamp","doi":"10.1007/s11151-024-09963-z","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-024-09963-z","url":null,"abstract":"<p>The final version of the 2023 Merger Guidelines, which were issued in December 2023, is a vast improvement over an earlier draft—which indicates that the Agencies took the many comments that they received on a draft very seriously. These Guidelines break some new ground that older Guidelines did not address, and make many positive contributions, which this paper spells out. They are also excessively nostalgic for a past era, however, and this may explain their propen sity to treat empirical questions as issues of law: This is one way to insulate these Guidelines from further revision. The excessive reliance on one decision, <i>Brown Shoe</i>, is unfortunate—particularly since that decision has been so often repudiated, even by the Supreme Court itself. This paper pays particular attention to: the Guidelines’ treatment of structural triggers and direct measures of competitive effects; their aggressive position on potential competition mergers; their willingness to weigh a “trend” toward concentration as a factor; and their treatment of serial acquisitions. The Guidelines include a welcome new section on mergers involving multi-sided networks, although their view of networks is too one-sided; and the Guidelines also contain an expanded section on mergers with harmful effects on suppliers—including labor. The Guidelines’ treatment of market definition is likely to lead to underenforcement because they define markets too broadly. Finally, the Guidelines could have made better use of recent retrospective studies—many of which would have provided further support for the substantive positions that the Guidelines take.</p>","PeriodicalId":47454,"journal":{"name":"Review of Industrial Organization","volume":"22 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2024-05-18","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141060119","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Mergers in Declining Industry 衰退行业的兼并
IF 1.1 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-05-18 DOI: 10.1007/s11151-024-09966-w
Tirza Angerhofer

Declining industries are characterized by prolonged declines in demand and excess capacity. Mergers of firms in declining industries often lead to rationalization of capacity, which makes production more efficient and makes firms better off. This benefit, however, may not be merger-specific, since capacity could be rationalized via firm exit. But the exit process itself may lead to inefficiencies, such as delays and inefficient ordering of exit (i.e., low-cost capital exits before high cost capital), which could warrant a merger. Increased market power of the combined firm, however, may lead to higher prices for consumers, which would be anticompetitive. This article considers the procompetitive efficiencies and anticompetitive consequences of mergers in declining industries and will discuss how the Agencies may evaluate these mergers.

衰退产业的特点是需求长期下降和产能过剩。衰退产业中企业的兼并往往会导致产能合理化,从而提高生产效率,改善企业状况。然而,这种好处可能不是兼并特有的,因为产能可以通过企业退出实现合理化。但退出过程本身可能导致效率低下,如退出延迟和退出顺序效率低下(即低成本资本先于高成本资本退出),这就需要合并。然而,合并后企业市场力量的增强可能会导致消费者支付更高的价格,这将是反竞争的。本文探讨了衰退行业兼并的竞争效率和反竞争后果,并将讨论各机构如何评估这些兼并。
{"title":"Mergers in Declining Industry","authors":"Tirza Angerhofer","doi":"10.1007/s11151-024-09966-w","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-024-09966-w","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Declining industries are characterized by prolonged declines in demand and excess capacity. Mergers of firms in declining industries often lead to rationalization of capacity, which makes production more efficient and makes firms better off. This benefit, however, may not be merger-specific, since capacity could be rationalized via firm exit. But the exit process itself may lead to inefficiencies, such as delays and inefficient ordering of exit (i.e., low-cost capital exits before high cost capital), which could warrant a merger. Increased market power of the combined firm, however, may lead to higher prices for consumers, which would be anticompetitive. This article considers the procompetitive efficiencies and anticompetitive consequences of mergers in declining industries and will discuss how the Agencies may evaluate these mergers.</p>","PeriodicalId":47454,"journal":{"name":"Review of Industrial Organization","volume":"22 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2024-05-18","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"141060102","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The 2023 Merger Guidelines and The Role of Economics 2023 年合并指南与经济学的作用
IF 1.1 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-05-03 DOI: 10.1007/s11151-024-09957-x
Michael A. Salinger

Relying heavily on legal analysis, the 2023 Merger Guidelines argue for a fundamental shift in antitrust enforcement that places more emphasis on protecting competitors and less on protecting the beneficiaries of competition. It is up to courts, not economists, to ascertain whether this interpretation of antitrust law is correct. But economists can and should analyze the likely economic effects. Evidence that antitrust enforcement has permitted some markets to be overly concentrated justifies the tightening of horizontal merger enforcement that is signaled by these guidelines. Evaluating the elimination of double marginalization from vertical mergers as a part of an efficiency defense rather than as a primary economic effect reflects a fundamental misunderstanding of the economics of vertical mergers. At a minimum, these guidelines will further damage the reputation of the DOJ and FTC among competition policy enforcers in other countries. A potentially more serious cost will be if foreign competition authorities use these guidelines to justify enforcing their own laws to protect inefficient domestic firms against foreign competition.

2023 年合并指南》在很大程度上依赖于法律分析,主张从根本上转变反垄断执法,更加重视保护竞争者,减少对竞争受益者的保护。这种对反垄断法的解释是否正确,应由法院而非经济学家来确定。但经济学家可以而且应该分析可能产生的经济影响。有证据表明,反垄断执法允许某些市场过度集中,这就证明了这些指导方针所显示的横向兼并执法收紧的合理性。将消除纵向兼并的双重边缘化作为效率辩护的一部分,而不是作为主要的经济效应进行评估,反映了对纵向兼并经济学的根本误解。至少,这些指南会进一步损害司法部和联邦贸易委员会在其他国家竞争政策执行者中的声誉。如果外国竞争管理机构利用这些指南来证明其执行本国法律的正当性,以保护效率低下的国内企业免受外国竞争的影响,则可能会付出更严重的代价。
{"title":"The 2023 Merger Guidelines and The Role of Economics","authors":"Michael A. Salinger","doi":"10.1007/s11151-024-09957-x","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-024-09957-x","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Relying heavily on legal analysis, the 2023 Merger Guidelines argue for a fundamental shift in antitrust enforcement that places more emphasis on protecting competitors and less on protecting the beneficiaries of competition. It is up to courts, not economists, to ascertain whether this interpretation of antitrust law is correct. But economists can and should analyze the likely economic effects. Evidence that antitrust enforcement has permitted some markets to be overly concentrated justifies the tightening of horizontal merger enforcement that is signaled by these guidelines. Evaluating the elimination of double marginalization from vertical mergers as a part of an efficiency defense rather than as a primary economic effect reflects a fundamental misunderstanding of the economics of vertical mergers. At a minimum, these guidelines will further damage the reputation of the DOJ and FTC among competition policy enforcers in other countries. A potentially more serious cost will be if foreign competition authorities use these guidelines to justify enforcing their own laws to protect inefficient domestic firms against foreign competition.</p>","PeriodicalId":47454,"journal":{"name":"Review of Industrial Organization","volume":"2013 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2024-05-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"140886237","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Marker Systems in Leniency Policies 宽大政策中的标记系统
IF 1.1 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-05-02 DOI: 10.1007/s11151-024-09955-z
Konstantinos Charistos

Leniency Programs (LPs) reward cartel-participating firms that come forward with evidence that can be used as proof of the illegal conduct in which they have participated. The marker system allows a leniency applicant to reserve its position in the reporting queue before the names of the eligible applicants are announced. We show that markers can reduce the destabilizing effect of LPs: When cartels are established either with or without a marker system, self-reporting and cartel disruption are less likely with markers, as compared to without markers. In addition, the introduction of markers in LPs may further the sustainability of collusion.

宽大处理方案(LPs)奖励那些提供证据证明其所参与的非法行为的卡特尔参与企业。标记系统允许宽大处理申请人在符合条件的申请人名单公布前保留其在报告队列中的位置。我们的研究表明,标记可以降低 LP 的不稳定效应:无论是有还是没有标记系统的卡特尔,有标记系统的卡特尔与无标记系统的卡特尔相比,自我报告和卡特尔破坏的可能性都更小。此外,在LP中引入标记可能会促进合谋的可持续性。
{"title":"Marker Systems in Leniency Policies","authors":"Konstantinos Charistos","doi":"10.1007/s11151-024-09955-z","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-024-09955-z","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Leniency Programs (LPs) reward cartel-participating firms that come forward with evidence that can be used as proof of the illegal conduct in which they have participated. The marker system allows a leniency applicant to reserve its position in the reporting queue before the names of the eligible applicants are announced. We show that markers can reduce the destabilizing effect of LPs: When cartels are established either with or without a marker system, self-reporting and cartel disruption are less likely with markers, as compared to without markers. In addition, the introduction of markers in LPs may further the sustainability of collusion.</p>","PeriodicalId":47454,"journal":{"name":"Review of Industrial Organization","volume":"11 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2024-05-02","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"140834361","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The 2023 Merger Guidelines: A Post-Chicago and Neo-Brandeisian Integration 2023 年合并指南》:后芝加哥与新勃兰登堡式整合
IF 1.1 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-04-09 DOI: 10.1007/s11151-024-09959-9
Steven C. Salop

This article is designed to explicate the somewhat misunderstood analysis in the 2023 Merger Guidelines (MGs) and situate the MGs in the context of the legal as well as economic environment in which they operate. The MGs refine economic analyses in previous MGs, renew emphasis on certain competitive concerns and approaches, and add several emerging new competitive issues. They also integrate certain goals of post-Chicago and Neo-Brandeisian approaches to merger analysis. The MGs integrate the economic analysis into the traditional legal structure of the “prima facie” and “rebuttal” evidentiary stages and place greater weight on avoiding false negatives over false positives in various places, which is a principal element in both post-Chicago and Neo-Brandeisian approaches. An important theme that runs through the 2023 MGs is that competitive effects analysis should not be limited to static competitive effects analysis of the immediate unilateral or coordinated price effects of a merger. They stress that the analysis should also account for the dynamic effects that result from the change in market structure that follows from the merger as well as the changes in the incentives of the firms. As in the seminal Spence-Dixit models, the entrant would rationally anticipate that the lower marginal costs of the merged firm could produce more intense post-entry price competition and a higher likelihood that the entry would be unprofitable. Thus, higher barriers to entry or expansion may result, which means that the merged firm’s rebuttal burden of production under the sliding scale should be increased accordingly under the decision theory risk analysis that places greater weight on avoiding false negatives.

本文旨在解释《2023 年企业合并指南》(MGs)中有些被误解的分析,并将 MGs 置于其所处的法律和经济环境中。指导原则》完善了以往《指导原则》中的经济分析,重新强调了某些竞争问题和方法,并增加了几个新出现的竞争问题。它们还整合了后芝加哥和新勃兰登堡合并分析方法的某些目标。合并指南》将经济分析纳入了 "表面证据 "和 "反驳 "证据阶段的传统法律结构中,并在不同地方更加重视避免假否定而不是假肯定,这是后芝加哥和新勃兰登堡方法的主要内容。贯穿 2023 年《指导原则》的一个重要主题是,竞争影响分析不应局限于对兼并的直接单边或协调价格影响的静态竞争影响分析。他们强调,分析还应考虑兼并后市场结构的变化以及企业激励机制的变化所产生的动态效应。正如斯彭斯-迪克西特(Spence-Dixit)的开创性模型一样,进入者会理性地预期,合并后的企业边际成本较低,进入后的价格竞争会更加激烈,进入后无利可图的可能性会更大。因此,进入或扩张可能会面临更高的壁垒,这意味着在决策理论风险分析中,被兼并企业在滑动量表下的反驳举证责任应相应增加,因为决策理论更重视避免假否定。
{"title":"The 2023 Merger Guidelines: A Post-Chicago and Neo-Brandeisian Integration","authors":"Steven C. Salop","doi":"10.1007/s11151-024-09959-9","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-024-09959-9","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This article is designed to explicate the somewhat misunderstood analysis in the 2023 Merger Guidelines (MGs) and situate the MGs in the context of the legal as well as economic environment in which they operate. The MGs refine economic analyses in previous MGs, renew emphasis on certain competitive concerns and approaches, and add several emerging new competitive issues. They also integrate certain goals of post-Chicago and Neo-Brandeisian approaches to merger analysis. The MGs integrate the economic analysis into the traditional legal structure of the “prima facie” and “rebuttal” evidentiary stages and place greater weight on avoiding false negatives over false positives in various places, which is a principal element in both post-Chicago and Neo-Brandeisian approaches. An important theme that runs through the 2023 MGs is that competitive effects analysis should not be limited to static competitive effects analysis of the immediate unilateral or coordinated price effects of a merger. They stress that the analysis should also account for the dynamic effects that result from the change in market structure that follows from the merger as well as the changes in the incentives of the firms. As in the seminal Spence-Dixit models, the entrant would rationally anticipate that the lower marginal costs of the merged firm could produce more intense post-entry price competition and a higher likelihood that the entry would be unprofitable. Thus, higher barriers to entry or expansion may result, which means that the merged firm’s rebuttal burden of production under the sliding scale should be increased accordingly under the decision theory risk analysis that places greater weight on avoiding false negatives.</p>","PeriodicalId":47454,"journal":{"name":"Review of Industrial Organization","volume":"71 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2024-04-09","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"140576041","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Evolution of the Merger Guidelines: Is This Fox Too Clever by Half? 合并指南的演变:这只狐狸是不是太聪明了?
IF 1.1 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-04-06 DOI: 10.1007/s11151-024-09956-y
Carl Shapiro

The 2023 Merger Guidelines make some notable improvements over the 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines. They give greater emphasis to the idea that predicting the competitive effects of a proposed merger is inherently difficult and that to block a merger the government need only show a risk that the merger may substantially lessen competition – not that it will do so. They also give greater emphasis to dynamic competition and innovation – especially with regard to acquisitions of potential entrants – and they add useful material on multi-sided platforms. However, the treatment of market definition in the 2023 Merger Guidelines may weaken horizontal merger enforcement by demoting the role of the “hypothetical monopolist test,” which is used to define markets for the purpose of measuring market shares, and by removing extensive material from prior guidelines that explained why market shares measured in narrower markets tend to be more informative than market shares measured in broader markets. The 2023 Merger Guidelines lower the market concentration thresholds that trigger a presumption by the antitrust enforcement agencies that a merger may substantially lessen competition, but the enforcement data suggest that change will have little effect in practice. The 2023 Merger Guidelines also may lead to less effective deterrence of harmful mergers because they are not well targeted at the mergers that are most likely to substantially lessen competition. One cannot prioritize everything.

与 2010 年《横向兼并指南》相比,《2023 年兼并指南》有了一些显著改进。它们更加强调预测拟议兼并的竞争影响本质上是困难的,要阻止兼并,政府只需证明兼并可能大幅削弱竞争的风险,而不是兼并一定会削弱竞争。它们还更加强调动态竞争和创新--尤其是关于潜在进入者的收购--并增加了关于多方平台的有用材料。然而,《2023 年兼并指南》对市场定义的处理可能会削弱横向兼并的执法力度,因为《2023 年兼并指南》贬低了 "假定垄断者测试 "的作用,而 "假定垄断者测试 "是用来定义市场以衡量市场份额的,《2023 年兼并指南》还删除了以前指南中的大量材料,这些材料解释了为什么在较窄市场中衡量的市场份额往往比在较宽市场中衡量的市场份额更有参考价值。2023 年《兼并指南》降低了市场集中度门槛,反垄断执法机构可据此推定兼并可能大幅削弱竞争,但执法数据表明,这一变化在实践中影响不大。2023 年《兼并指南》还可能导致对有害兼并的威慑效果大打折扣,因为它没有很好地针对最有可能大幅削弱竞争的兼并。我们不能把所有事情都放在首位。
{"title":"Evolution of the Merger Guidelines: Is This Fox Too Clever by Half?","authors":"Carl Shapiro","doi":"10.1007/s11151-024-09956-y","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-024-09956-y","url":null,"abstract":"<p>The 2023 Merger Guidelines make some notable improvements over the 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines. They give greater emphasis to the idea that predicting the competitive effects of a proposed merger is inherently difficult and that to block a merger the government need only show a risk that the merger may substantially lessen competition – not that it will do so. They also give greater emphasis to dynamic competition and innovation – especially with regard to acquisitions of potential entrants – and they add useful material on multi-sided platforms. However, the treatment of market definition in the 2023 Merger Guidelines may weaken horizontal merger enforcement by demoting the role of the “hypothetical monopolist test,” which is used to define markets for the purpose of measuring market shares, and by removing extensive material from prior guidelines that explained why market shares measured in narrower markets tend to be more informative than market shares measured in broader markets. The 2023 Merger Guidelines lower the market concentration thresholds that trigger a presumption by the antitrust enforcement agencies that a merger may substantially lessen competition, but the enforcement data suggest that change will have little effect in practice. The 2023 Merger Guidelines also may lead to less effective deterrence of harmful mergers because they are not well targeted at the mergers that are most likely to substantially lessen competition. One cannot prioritize everything.</p>","PeriodicalId":47454,"journal":{"name":"Review of Industrial Organization","volume":"6 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2024-04-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"140576245","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Customer Recognition and Mobile Geo-Targeting 客户识别和移动地理定位
IF 1.1 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-04-04 DOI: 10.1007/s11151-024-09952-2
Irina Baye, Philip Hanspach, Tim Reiz, Geza Sapi

We consider competing mobile marketers that complement geo-targeting with behavior-based pricing and send personalized offers to customers. Firms observe consumers’ locations and can infer their (heterogeneous) responsiveness to discounts from purchase histories. The overall profit effect of behavioral targeting is driven by firms’ discount factor and consumers’ transport cost and can be neutral, positive, or negative. We are the first to show that the profitability of behavioral data may depend on firms’ time preferences. We derive conditions for when firms prefer more rather than less behavioral targeting.

我们考虑了相互竞争的移动营销公司,这些公司通过基于行为的定价对地理定位进行补充,并向客户发送个性化的优惠信息。企业可以观察到消费者的位置,并从购买历史记录中推断出他们对折扣的(异质性)反应。行为定位的总体利润效应由企业的折扣系数和消费者的运输成本决定,可以是中性的、积极的或消极的。我们首次证明,行为数据的盈利能力可能取决于企业的时间偏好。我们推导出了企业倾向于更多而非更少的行为定位的条件。
{"title":"Customer Recognition and Mobile Geo-Targeting","authors":"Irina Baye, Philip Hanspach, Tim Reiz, Geza Sapi","doi":"10.1007/s11151-024-09952-2","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-024-09952-2","url":null,"abstract":"<p>We consider competing mobile marketers that complement geo-targeting with behavior-based pricing and send personalized offers to customers. Firms observe consumers’ locations and can infer their (heterogeneous) responsiveness to discounts from purchase histories. The overall profit effect of behavioral targeting is driven by firms’ discount factor and consumers’ transport cost and can be neutral, positive, or negative. We are the first to show that the profitability of behavioral data may depend on firms’ time preferences. We derive conditions for when firms prefer more rather than less behavioral targeting.</p>","PeriodicalId":47454,"journal":{"name":"Review of Industrial Organization","volume":"89 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2024-04-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"140576011","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The Auction of Contracts by Consumer Groups and the Effect on Market Power 消费者团体拍卖合同及其对市场力量的影响
IF 1.1 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2024-04-03 DOI: 10.1007/s11151-024-09943-3
Pablo Serra

This article discusses the auctioning of financial contracts by aggregations of consumers who aim to reduce the spot price of a concentrated industry’s product; this is a frequent arrangement in electricity markets. The contracts' underlying asset is the product; the auctions' bidding variable is the strike price; and the bidders are the producers. Using a three-stage complete-information game, we show that when all consumers belong to some group, in the subgame perfect Nash equilibrium, each group fully hedges its consumption, and total output reaches its efficient level. Otherwise, each group over-hedges its consumption, and total production is below the efficiency level.

本文讨论的是消费者集合体拍卖金融合约的情况,这些消费者的目的是降低集中行业产品的现货价格;这是电力市场中经常出现的一种安排。合约的基础资产是产品;拍卖的投标变量是执行价格;投标人是生产商。通过三阶段完全信息博弈,我们证明了当所有消费者都属于某个群体时,在子博弈完全纳什均衡中,每个群体都会完全对冲其消费,总产出达到有效水平。否则,每个群体过度对冲其消费,总产量低于效率水平。
{"title":"The Auction of Contracts by Consumer Groups and the Effect on Market Power","authors":"Pablo Serra","doi":"10.1007/s11151-024-09943-3","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-024-09943-3","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This article discusses the auctioning of financial contracts by aggregations of consumers who aim to reduce the spot price of a concentrated industry’s product; this is a frequent arrangement in electricity markets. The contracts' underlying asset is the product; the auctions' bidding variable is the strike price; and the bidders are the producers. Using a three-stage complete-information game, we show that when all consumers belong to some group, in the subgame perfect Nash equilibrium, each group fully hedges its consumption, and total output reaches its efficient level. Otherwise, each group over-hedges its consumption, and total production is below the efficiency level.</p>","PeriodicalId":47454,"journal":{"name":"Review of Industrial Organization","volume":"42 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2024-04-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"140576009","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Review of Industrial Organization
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1