首页 > 最新文献

Nber Macroeconomics Annual最新文献

英文 中文
Comment 评论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2021-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/712318
J. Eeckhout
There is a rapidly growing recent literature that analyzes the rise of market power over the last 4 decades in the United States and in many other economies. The study of market power is, of course, not new and is arguably as old as the study of economics itself. But the renewed interest is its scope, particularly the role for macroeconomics. Much of the recent literature focuses on measuring market power throughout the economy and on its quantitative macroeconomic implications. Many macroeconomic models from monetary economics, over trade and urban economics, to labor have predictions that hinge on the degree of market power that firms have. Themonetary transmissionmechanism in theNewKeynesianmodels, for example, crucially depends onmarkups and the extent to which the market power of firms is pervasive throughout the economy. The challenge, therefore, is to find appropriate ways to measure market power for a representative sample of the universe of firms in the economy. The paper by Esteban Rossi-Hansberg, Pierre Sarte, andNico Trachter draws attention to an important and hitherto understudied issue in this literature, the dichotomy between national and local measures of concentration. The main idea is that the degree of concentration of firms at the national level is very different than what it is at a local level, be it the state, the metropolitan area, or the ZIP code. They find a baffling fact: all measures of local concentration show a declining trend, whereas measures of national concentration show an increasing trend. This is an important observation and I sympathizewith the premise of investigating market power at different levels of aggregation and for different subeconomies of the macro economy. After all, to understand the macro economywe need to understand the micro origins. The paper
最近有越来越多的文献分析了过去40年来美国和许多其他经济体市场力量的崛起。当然,对市场力量的研究并不新鲜,可以说与经济学本身一样古老。但人们重新关注的是它的范围,尤其是宏观经济学的作用。最近的许多文献都集中在衡量整个经济中的市场力量及其对宏观经济的量化影响上。从货币经济学、贸易和城市经济学到劳动力,许多宏观经济模型的预测都取决于企业的市场力量程度。例如,新凯恩斯主义模型中的单一传导机制在很大程度上取决于标记和企业的市场力量在整个经济中的普遍程度。因此,挑战在于找到适当的方法来衡量经济中企业界的代表性样本的市场力量。Esteban Rossi Hansberg、Pierre Sarte和Nico Trachter的论文引起了人们对这篇文献中一个迄今为止研究不足的重要问题的关注,即国家和地方集中措施之间的二分法。主要观点是,国家层面的企业集中程度与地方层面的企业非常不同,无论是州、大都市地区还是邮政编码。他们发现了一个令人困惑的事实:所有地方集中度指标都呈下降趋势,而全国集中度指标则呈上升趋势。这是一个重要的观察结果,我赞同调查宏观经济中不同聚合水平和不同子经济的市场力量的前提。毕竟,要了解宏观经济,就需要了解微观起源。该论文
{"title":"Comment","authors":"J. Eeckhout","doi":"10.1086/712318","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/712318","url":null,"abstract":"There is a rapidly growing recent literature that analyzes the rise of market power over the last 4 decades in the United States and in many other economies. The study of market power is, of course, not new and is arguably as old as the study of economics itself. But the renewed interest is its scope, particularly the role for macroeconomics. Much of the recent literature focuses on measuring market power throughout the economy and on its quantitative macroeconomic implications. Many macroeconomic models from monetary economics, over trade and urban economics, to labor have predictions that hinge on the degree of market power that firms have. Themonetary transmissionmechanism in theNewKeynesianmodels, for example, crucially depends onmarkups and the extent to which the market power of firms is pervasive throughout the economy. The challenge, therefore, is to find appropriate ways to measure market power for a representative sample of the universe of firms in the economy. The paper by Esteban Rossi-Hansberg, Pierre Sarte, andNico Trachter draws attention to an important and hitherto understudied issue in this literature, the dichotomy between national and local measures of concentration. The main idea is that the degree of concentration of firms at the national level is very different than what it is at a local level, be it the state, the metropolitan area, or the ZIP code. They find a baffling fact: all measures of local concentration show a declining trend, whereas measures of national concentration show an increasing trend. This is an important observation and I sympathizewith the premise of investigating market power at different levels of aggregation and for different subeconomies of the macro economy. After all, to understand the macro economywe need to understand the micro origins. The paper","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"35 1","pages":"151 - 166"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2021-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"49258601","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Discussion 讨论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2021-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/712324
Greg Kaplan opened the discussion by inquiring about the goal of the estimation and the nature of the counterfactual exercises carried out in the paper. He expressed concern that the exercises that study the response of households to changes in prices are treating an equilibrium object—namely, house prices—as a parameter. AlisdairMcKay responded that individual households treat house prices as exogenous. Thus, it is appropriate to treat house prices as a parameter in a partial equilibrium setting and study how sensitive household decisions are to that parameter. As a following step, it is then possible to aggregate housing decisions. He agreed that a real-world counterpart of this exercise is not immediate because it would consider an average of different housing parameters across individuals. Kaplan agreed on the scope of the exercise in the context of the model, but he pointed out that we need to believe that the assumptions made in the model also hold in the real world. He also emphasized the importance of clearly stating the relevant real-world counterfactual at the core of the analysis that is being carried out. Jón Steinsson argued that it was important to distinguish clearly between two separate objects. The first is what is measured in the data, which is clearly defined by the empirical specification. The second is the interpretation of the measured object. A theoretical model can provide an interpretation for the object measured in the data. He highlighted that housing is not exogenous in the model presented in the paper, yet it corresponds to the object observed in the data. Adam Guren further pointed out that the home price shock is similar to a foreign demand shock and that the effect of such a shock on consumption is instrumental to correctly calibrating the housing wealth effect in a general equilibrium model.
格雷格·卡普兰(Greg Kaplan)首先询问了评估的目标和论文中进行的反事实练习的性质。他表示担心,研究家庭对价格变化的反应的练习将均衡对象——即房价——视为一个参数。AlisdairMcKay回应称,个别家庭将房价视为外生因素。因此,将房价视为部分均衡环境中的一个参数,并研究家庭决策对该参数的敏感程度是合适的。作为下一步,可以汇总住房决策。他同意,在现实世界中,这项工作并不是立即进行的,因为它将考虑个人不同住房参数的平均值。Kaplan同意该模型中的演习范围,但他指出,我们需要相信模型中的假设在现实世界中也适用。他还强调了在正在进行的分析的核心明确说明相关现实世界反事实的重要性。Jón Steinson认为,明确区分两个不同的物体很重要。第一个是数据中所测量的内容,这是由经验规范明确定义的。二是对被测对象的解释。理论模型可以为数据中测量的对象提供解释。他强调,在论文中提出的模型中,住房不是外生的,但它与数据中观察到的对象相对应。Adam Guren进一步指出,房价冲击类似于外国需求冲击,这种冲击对消费的影响有助于在一般均衡模型中正确校准住房财富效应。
{"title":"Discussion","authors":"","doi":"10.1086/712324","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/712324","url":null,"abstract":"Greg Kaplan opened the discussion by inquiring about the goal of the estimation and the nature of the counterfactual exercises carried out in the paper. He expressed concern that the exercises that study the response of households to changes in prices are treating an equilibrium object—namely, house prices—as a parameter. AlisdairMcKay responded that individual households treat house prices as exogenous. Thus, it is appropriate to treat house prices as a parameter in a partial equilibrium setting and study how sensitive household decisions are to that parameter. As a following step, it is then possible to aggregate housing decisions. He agreed that a real-world counterpart of this exercise is not immediate because it would consider an average of different housing parameters across individuals. Kaplan agreed on the scope of the exercise in the context of the model, but he pointed out that we need to believe that the assumptions made in the model also hold in the real world. He also emphasized the importance of clearly stating the relevant real-world counterfactual at the core of the analysis that is being carried out. Jón Steinsson argued that it was important to distinguish clearly between two separate objects. The first is what is measured in the data, which is clearly defined by the empirical specification. The second is the interpretation of the measured object. A theoretical model can provide an interpretation for the object measured in the data. He highlighted that housing is not exogenous in the model presented in the paper, yet it corresponds to the object observed in the data. Adam Guren further pointed out that the home price shock is similar to a foreign demand shock and that the effect of such a shock on consumption is instrumental to correctly calibrating the housing wealth effect in a general equilibrium model.","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"35 1","pages":"242 - 244"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2021-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/712324","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"47341663","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Editorial 编辑
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2021-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/712310
M. Eichenbaum, Erik Hurst
The NBER’s 35th Annual Conference on Macroeconomics brought together leading scholars to present, discuss, and debate six research papers on central issues in contemporary macroeconomics. In addition, Jeremy Stein, former governor of the Federal Reserve, led a thoughtprovoking discussion on whether the financial system is safer now than it was prior to the Great Recession. Given the pandemic, the conference took place via Zoom. Video recordings of the presentations of the papers and the after-dinner talk are all accessible on the web page of the NBER AnnualConference onMacroeconomics. These videosmake auseful complement to this volumeandmake the content of the conferencemorewidely accessible. This conference volume contains edited versions of the six papers presented at the conference. With one exception, each paper is followed by two written discussions by leading scholars and a summary of the debates that followed each paper. In the exception, there is only one written discussion. In their paper “Imperfect Macroeconomic Expectations: Evidence and Theory,” George-Marios Angeletos, Zhen Huo, and Karthik Sastry tackle a central question in macroeconomics: How should we model people’s expectations? For many years the answer to this question was widely viewed among mainstream macroeconomists as a settled issue. The answer was that people have rational expectations and common knowledge about the state of the economy. That consensus shattered under theweight of a large literature testing rational expectations, based in part on survey-based data. But what should we replace our simple benchmark model of expectations with? The paper by Angeletos et al.
美国国家经济研究局第35届宏观经济学年会汇集了顶尖学者,就当代宏观经济学的核心问题发表、讨论和辩论了六篇研究论文。此外,美联储(fed)前行长杰里米•斯坦(Jeremy Stein)就当前金融体系是否比大衰退(Great Recession)前更安全展开了一场发人深省的讨论。鉴于疫情,会议通过Zoom举行。在NBER宏观经济学年会的网页上,可以看到论文展示和餐后谈话的录像。这些视频是对本卷的有益补充,使会议的内容更容易获得。本会议卷载有在会议上发表的六篇论文的编辑版本。除了一个例外,每篇论文之后都有两篇由主要学者撰写的书面讨论,以及每篇论文之后的辩论摘要。在例外情况下,只有一次书面讨论。在他们的论文《不完美的宏观经济预期:证据与理论》中,乔治-马里奥斯·安格莱托斯、霍真和卡蒂克·萨斯特里解决了宏观经济学中的一个核心问题:我们应该如何为人们的预期建模?多年来,主流宏观经济学家普遍认为这个问题的答案是一个已解决的问题。答案是,人们对经济状况有理性预期和常识。在检验理性预期的大量文献(部分基于调查数据)的重压下,这种共识被打破了。但是,我们应该用什么来取代我们简单的期望基准模型呢?Angeletos等人的论文。
{"title":"Editorial","authors":"M. Eichenbaum, Erik Hurst","doi":"10.1086/712310","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/712310","url":null,"abstract":"The NBER’s 35th Annual Conference on Macroeconomics brought together leading scholars to present, discuss, and debate six research papers on central issues in contemporary macroeconomics. In addition, Jeremy Stein, former governor of the Federal Reserve, led a thoughtprovoking discussion on whether the financial system is safer now than it was prior to the Great Recession. Given the pandemic, the conference took place via Zoom. Video recordings of the presentations of the papers and the after-dinner talk are all accessible on the web page of the NBER AnnualConference onMacroeconomics. These videosmake auseful complement to this volumeandmake the content of the conferencemorewidely accessible. This conference volume contains edited versions of the six papers presented at the conference. With one exception, each paper is followed by two written discussions by leading scholars and a summary of the debates that followed each paper. In the exception, there is only one written discussion. In their paper “Imperfect Macroeconomic Expectations: Evidence and Theory,” George-Marios Angeletos, Zhen Huo, and Karthik Sastry tackle a central question in macroeconomics: How should we model people’s expectations? For many years the answer to this question was widely viewed among mainstream macroeconomists as a settled issue. The answer was that people have rational expectations and common knowledge about the state of the economy. That consensus shattered under theweight of a large literature testing rational expectations, based in part on survey-based data. But what should we replace our simple benchmark model of expectations with? The paper by Angeletos et al.","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"35 1","pages":"xi - xvii"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2021-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/712310","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"42054725","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Comment 评论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2021-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/712330
Raquel Fernández
This is a nice paper that uses data from the US Social Security Administration (SSA) to provide empirical evidence on gender differences in earnings. It focuses on differences in gender representation at the top 0.1% and the next 0.9% of the earnings distribution. It examines the persistence of an individual’s presence in these top percentiles, how age and industry composition matter, and gives some feel for life-cycle dynamics, all the while contrasting the presence of women versus men. The authors have access to a 10% representative sample of individual earnings histories from the SSA (constructed by selecting all individuals with the same last digit of a transformation of the social security number). This is a panel data set spanning 32 years: 1981–2012. There is basic demographic information available: age, sex, race, type of work (farm/ nonfarm, employment/self-employment), and earnings. The latter consists of wages and salaries, bonuses, and exercised stock options as reported in Box 1 on a W-2 form. For most of their analysis, they select from the 10% sample all individuals who in that year are between 25 and 60 years old and whose annual earnings exceed a minimum threshold (equivalent to 13 weeks, full-time, at one-half minimum wage). Among the advantages of a panel set are that one can, for example, study earnings over a number of years to smooth out temporary fluctuations, ask questions about persistence, and examine measures of lifetime income. What this data set sacrifices, however, is any rich information about other characteristics of these individuals such as their education, marital status and children, spousal attributes, and occupation other than that captured by broad industry categories. This makes it virtually
这是一篇不错的论文,它使用了美国社会保障局(SSA)的数据,为收入的性别差异提供了实证证据。它关注的是收入分配中前0.1%和后0.9%的性别代表差异。它考察了一个人在前百分位数的持续存在,年龄和行业构成的影响,并给出了一些生命周期动态的感觉,同时对比了女性和男性的存在。作者可以从SSA获得10%的个人收入历史代表性样本(通过选择所有具有相同社会安全号码转换后的最后一位数字的个人来构建)。这是一个32年的面板数据集:1981-2012。有基本的人口统计信息:年龄、性别、种族、工作类型(农场/非农、就业/自营职业)和收入。后者包括工资和薪金,奖金和行使股票期权,在W-2表格的框1中报告。在他们的大部分分析中,他们从10%的样本中选择了所有在那一年年龄在25岁到60岁之间,年收入超过最低门槛(相当于13周的全职工作,最低工资的一半)的个人。面板集的优点之一是,例如,人们可以研究多年的收入,以消除暂时的波动,询问有关持久性的问题,并检查终身收入的衡量标准。然而,这个数据集所牺牲的是这些个人的其他特征的丰富信息,如他们的教育、婚姻状况和子女、配偶属性和职业,而不是广泛的行业类别所捕获的信息。这让它变得很虚拟
{"title":"Comment","authors":"Raquel Fernández","doi":"10.1086/712330","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/712330","url":null,"abstract":"This is a nice paper that uses data from the US Social Security Administration (SSA) to provide empirical evidence on gender differences in earnings. It focuses on differences in gender representation at the top 0.1% and the next 0.9% of the earnings distribution. It examines the persistence of an individual’s presence in these top percentiles, how age and industry composition matter, and gives some feel for life-cycle dynamics, all the while contrasting the presence of women versus men. The authors have access to a 10% representative sample of individual earnings histories from the SSA (constructed by selecting all individuals with the same last digit of a transformation of the social security number). This is a panel data set spanning 32 years: 1981–2012. There is basic demographic information available: age, sex, race, type of work (farm/ nonfarm, employment/self-employment), and earnings. The latter consists of wages and salaries, bonuses, and exercised stock options as reported in Box 1 on a W-2 form. For most of their analysis, they select from the 10% sample all individuals who in that year are between 25 and 60 years old and whose annual earnings exceed a minimum threshold (equivalent to 13 weeks, full-time, at one-half minimum wage). Among the advantages of a panel set are that one can, for example, study earnings over a number of years to smooth out temporary fluctuations, ask questions about persistence, and examine measures of lifetime income. What this data set sacrifices, however, is any rich information about other characteristics of these individuals such as their education, marital status and children, spousal attributes, and occupation other than that captured by broad industry categories. This makes it virtually","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"35 1","pages":"381 - 387"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2021-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"42181466","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Comment 评论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2021-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/712314
Jessica A. Wachter
The authors build a quantitative framework, broad enough to nest different types of ideas proposed in behavioral macroeconomics, to help make sense of the survey evidence on expectations. The goal is not so much to understand survey evidence for its own sake, though that might be interesting. Nor is it to decide between a class of competing models, all of which work fairly well. Rather, the goal is to inform future directions for research in a field that at the moment seems a bit lost in a “wilderness.” In the end, using their approach, the authors are able to say that theweight of the evidence favors some types of models rather than others. The focus on survey evidence comes at a time of uncertainty about future directions inmacroeconomics.Many, including some of the authors in prior work, have noted serious failings with benchmark models. These failings have a solution, perhaps, within a different class of models, ones that do not impose rational expectations. But rational expectations are a powerful disciplining device, and this broader class seems impossibly large. The literature has, for several years, recognized the potential of survey evidence to itself be a disciplining device, filling some of the role that rational expectations used to, and do still, play. Barberis et al. (2015), for example, argue for using survey evidence to decide between competing models in financial economics. In macroeconomics, Coibion and Gorodnichenko (2015) argue that one need not have a model to interpret survey evidence: a positive sign in regressions of forecast errors on forecast revisions is
作者建立了一个量化框架,它足够广泛,可以容纳行为宏观经济学中提出的不同类型的观点,以帮助理解有关预期的调查证据。我们的目标并不是为了理解调查证据本身,尽管这可能很有趣。它也不是要在一类相互竞争的模型之间做出选择,这些模型都运行得相当好。相反,它的目标是为这个目前似乎有点迷失在“荒野”中的领域的研究指明未来的方向。最后,使用他们的方法,作者可以说,证据的权重倾向于某些类型的模型,而不是其他模型。对调查证据的关注出现在宏观经济学未来方向不确定的时期。许多人,包括之前工作中的一些作者,都指出了基准模型的严重缺陷。或许,在另一类不强加理性预期的模型中,这些缺陷有一个解决方案。但理性预期是一种强有力的约束手段,而这个更广泛的阶层似乎大得不可思议。多年来,文献已经认识到调查证据本身的潜力是一种约束手段,填补了理性预期过去和现在仍然在发挥的一些作用。例如,Barberis等人(2015)主张使用调查证据来决定金融经济学中相互竞争的模型。在宏观经济学中,Coibion和Gorodnichenko(2015)认为,人们不需要一个模型来解释调查证据:预测误差对预测修正的回归的积极迹象是
{"title":"Comment","authors":"Jessica A. Wachter","doi":"10.1086/712314","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/712314","url":null,"abstract":"The authors build a quantitative framework, broad enough to nest different types of ideas proposed in behavioral macroeconomics, to help make sense of the survey evidence on expectations. The goal is not so much to understand survey evidence for its own sake, though that might be interesting. Nor is it to decide between a class of competing models, all of which work fairly well. Rather, the goal is to inform future directions for research in a field that at the moment seems a bit lost in a “wilderness.” In the end, using their approach, the authors are able to say that theweight of the evidence favors some types of models rather than others. The focus on survey evidence comes at a time of uncertainty about future directions inmacroeconomics.Many, including some of the authors in prior work, have noted serious failings with benchmark models. These failings have a solution, perhaps, within a different class of models, ones that do not impose rational expectations. But rational expectations are a powerful disciplining device, and this broader class seems impossibly large. The literature has, for several years, recognized the potential of survey evidence to itself be a disciplining device, filling some of the role that rational expectations used to, and do still, play. Barberis et al. (2015), for example, argue for using survey evidence to decide between competing models in financial economics. In macroeconomics, Coibion and Gorodnichenko (2015) argue that one need not have a model to interpret survey evidence: a positive sign in regressions of forecast errors on forecast revisions is","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"35 1","pages":"87 - 98"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2021-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/712314","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"44925004","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Comment 评论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2021-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/712322
Gabriel Chodorow-reich
In this paper, Guren, McKay, Nakamura, and Steinsson (Guren et al.) advocate using regional cross-sectional empirical estimates to measure microeconomic parameters such as the marginal propensity to consume out of housing wealth. The “divide-by-multiplier”method recovers the microeconomic parameter by dividing the regional response to a shock by a “demandmultiplier” estimated separately as the regional response to a government spending shock. This method has many potential applications in regional data. (Full disclosure: in Chodorow-Reich, Nenov, and Simsek [2019] I use it to measure the stock market wealth effect on consumption.) Guren et al. provide a comprehensive yet accessible theoretical exposition and a numerical evaluation in the context of a model of housing wealth. I divide my comments into four parts. First, I provide background on literatures using regional data in macroeconomics and on demand multipliers. Second, Guren et al. apply the method to a shock to preferences for housing. This choice introduces complications because housing is both part of wealth and an expenditure item, and both construction and consumer spending may respond to changes in house prices. I illustrate the relationship using a simpler yet still fully microfounded model with pure wealth shocks. Third, I use thismodel tomakemymain critique of the paper or, more accurately, of the paper’s title. A casual reader might infer that the divide-by-multipliermethod provides the only validway to interpret regional empirical estimates. My simple model illustrates an additional property of regional effects of demand shocks, namely, that they provide a lower bound for the appropriately defined aggregate effect of the shock. I conclude by reviewing other recent approaches to interpreting
在本文中,Guren、McKay、Nakamura和Steinson(Guren等人)主张使用区域横截面经验估计来衡量微观经济参数,如住房外财富的边际消费倾向。“除以乘数”方法通过将地区对冲击的反应除以单独估计为地区对政府支出冲击的反应的“需求乘数”来恢复微观经济参数。这种方法在区域数据中有许多潜在的应用。(完全披露:在Chodorow-Reich、Nenov和Simsek[199]中,我用它来衡量股市财富对消费的影响。)Guren等人在住房财富模型的背景下提供了全面而容易获得的理论阐述和数字评估。我将我的评论分为四个部分。首先,我提供了在宏观经济学和需求乘数中使用区域数据的文献背景。其次,Guren等人将该方法应用于对住房偏好的冲击。这种选择带来了复杂性,因为住房既是财富的一部分,也是支出项目,建筑和消费者支出都可能对房价的变化做出反应。我使用一个更简单但仍然完全微观的模型来说明这种关系,该模型具有纯粹的财富冲击。第三,我用这个模型来对论文进行评论,或者更准确地说,对论文的标题进行评论。一个普通读者可能会推断,乘除法是解释区域经验估计的唯一有效方法。我的简单模型说明了需求冲击的区域效应的另一个特性,即它们为适当定义的冲击的总效应提供了下限。最后,我回顾了其他最近的口译方法
{"title":"Comment","authors":"Gabriel Chodorow-reich","doi":"10.1086/712322","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/712322","url":null,"abstract":"In this paper, Guren, McKay, Nakamura, and Steinsson (Guren et al.) advocate using regional cross-sectional empirical estimates to measure microeconomic parameters such as the marginal propensity to consume out of housing wealth. The “divide-by-multiplier”method recovers the microeconomic parameter by dividing the regional response to a shock by a “demandmultiplier” estimated separately as the regional response to a government spending shock. This method has many potential applications in regional data. (Full disclosure: in Chodorow-Reich, Nenov, and Simsek [2019] I use it to measure the stock market wealth effect on consumption.) Guren et al. provide a comprehensive yet accessible theoretical exposition and a numerical evaluation in the context of a model of housing wealth. I divide my comments into four parts. First, I provide background on literatures using regional data in macroeconomics and on demand multipliers. Second, Guren et al. apply the method to a shock to preferences for housing. This choice introduces complications because housing is both part of wealth and an expenditure item, and both construction and consumer spending may respond to changes in house prices. I illustrate the relationship using a simpler yet still fully microfounded model with pure wealth shocks. Third, I use thismodel tomakemymain critique of the paper or, more accurately, of the paper’s title. A casual reader might infer that the divide-by-multipliermethod provides the only validway to interpret regional empirical estimates. My simple model illustrates an additional property of regional effects of demand shocks, namely, that they provide a lower bound for the appropriately defined aggregate effect of the shock. I conclude by reviewing other recent approaches to interpreting","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"35 1","pages":"224 - 231"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2021-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/712322","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"43532847","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Relation of the Directors to the Work and Publications of the NBER 董事与NBER工作和出版物的关系
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2021-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/667777
{"title":"Relation of the Directors to the Work and Publications of the NBER","authors":"","doi":"10.1086/667777","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/667777","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"26 1","pages":"vii - viii"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2021-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/667777","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"42511369","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Comment 评论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2021-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/712329
Paola Sapienza
The paper by Guvenen, Kaplan, and Song provides many useful insights into the evolution of top earners’ earnings and the dynamics of the gender gap at the top of the earning distribution. The authors have access to a representative sample of 10% of individual earnings from the US Social Security Administration (SSA) between 1981 and 2012. The panel structure of the data allows them to follow individuals over time, shedding light on the persistence of top earners and addressing some of the shortcomings of the literature that uses cross-sectional data. Theyfind several interesting results. First, in 2012, the share ofwomen among the top 0.1% of earners is only 11% and among the top 1% only 18%. This gap was even larger earlier in the sample, suggesting a slow positive trend toward the reduction of the gender gap, with themajority of the gain concentrated in the 1980s and the 1990s. Second, the paper unveils a very large turnover over the life cycle among top earners, for both men andwomen, and highlights that gender improvements coincidewith a larger persistence over time ofwomen at the top of the income distribution. Although in the 1980swomenwere twice as likely asmen to drop out from the top earners, in recent years the probability of men and women of droppingout hasbecome similar. Third, industryandagevariationsprovide further insights on the dynamics of the gender gap. The authors do not find any obvious relationship between the evolution of income across industries and the mitigation of the gender gap over time, whereas the distribution of age among top earners shows significant changes, with new cohorts of women making inroads into the top 1% earlier in their lifetime than previous cohorts (this results does not hold for the top 0.1% earners).
Guvenen、Kaplan和Song的论文为高收入者的收入演变和收入分布顶端的性别差距动态提供了许多有用的见解。作者获得了1981年至2012年间美国社会保障局(SSA) 10%个人收入的代表性样本。数据的面板结构使他们能够随着时间的推移跟踪个人,揭示高收入者的持久性,并解决使用横截面数据的文献的一些缺点。他们发现了几个有趣的结果。首先,2012年,在收入最高的0.1%人群中,女性所占比例仅为11%,而在收入最高的1%人群中,女性所占比例仅为18%。在样本的早期,这一差距甚至更大,这表明性别差距的缩小是一个缓慢的积极趋势,大部分的增长集中在20世纪80年代和90年代。其次,该论文揭示了高收入者在整个生命周期中的巨大更替,无论是男性还是女性,并强调了性别的改善与女性在收入分配顶端的长期持久性相吻合。尽管在20世纪80年代,女性从高收入者行列中退出的可能性是男性的两倍,但近年来,男性和女性退出的可能性已经变得相似。第三,行业和年龄的差异为性别差距的动态提供了进一步的见解。作者没有发现各行各业的收入演变与性别差距随着时间的推移而缩小之间有任何明显的关系,而高收入者的年龄分布却发生了重大变化,新一批女性比以前的人群更早地进入了前1%的人群(这一结果并不适用于前0.1%的人群)。
{"title":"Comment","authors":"Paola Sapienza","doi":"10.1086/712329","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/712329","url":null,"abstract":"The paper by Guvenen, Kaplan, and Song provides many useful insights into the evolution of top earners’ earnings and the dynamics of the gender gap at the top of the earning distribution. The authors have access to a representative sample of 10% of individual earnings from the US Social Security Administration (SSA) between 1981 and 2012. The panel structure of the data allows them to follow individuals over time, shedding light on the persistence of top earners and addressing some of the shortcomings of the literature that uses cross-sectional data. Theyfind several interesting results. First, in 2012, the share ofwomen among the top 0.1% of earners is only 11% and among the top 1% only 18%. This gap was even larger earlier in the sample, suggesting a slow positive trend toward the reduction of the gender gap, with themajority of the gain concentrated in the 1980s and the 1990s. Second, the paper unveils a very large turnover over the life cycle among top earners, for both men andwomen, and highlights that gender improvements coincidewith a larger persistence over time ofwomen at the top of the income distribution. Although in the 1980swomenwere twice as likely asmen to drop out from the top earners, in recent years the probability of men and women of droppingout hasbecome similar. Third, industryandagevariationsprovide further insights on the dynamics of the gender gap. The authors do not find any obvious relationship between the evolution of income across industries and the mitigation of the gender gap over time, whereas the distribution of age among top earners shows significant changes, with new cohorts of women making inroads into the top 1% earlier in their lifetime than previous cohorts (this results does not hold for the top 0.1% earners).","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"35 1","pages":"374 - 380"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2021-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/712329","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"42703081","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Comment 评论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2021-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/712326
J. Haltiwanger
Understanding the determinants of innovation and productivity growth is a core open area of economics research. Although enormous progress has beenmade in theoretical models of innovation accompanied by an increasing use of firm-level data to quantify the nature of innovation and productivity, many challenges remain. A key challenge is that much of the research using firm-level data has focused on firms with observable measures of the inputs into innovation (e.g., research and development [R&D] expenditures) and direct measures of the success of innovations (e.g., patents). This approach focuses on a relativelynarrow subset offirms and sectors where such observables are relevant. Most firms do not report R&D expenditures or patents. It is implausible that only the firms with these observable measures of innovation are responsible for the observed fluctuations in productivity growth from innovation. As evidence of this, a National Academy of Sciences report (Brown et al. 2005) highlighting the limitations of R&Ddata reported that one of themost innovative firms in retail trade, Walmart, reports no R&D expenditures in its 10-K reports. This paper takes an indirect approach to identifying innovation activity that overcomes these limitations. Using an innovative growth accounting framework that is motivated by a quality laddermodel of innovation, this paper uses data on the employment growth rate distribution for the universe of private sector, nonfarm (hereafter private sector for short) establishments to quantify the contribution of creative destruction (CD), own innovation, and new varieties. The authors accomplish this important objective by using the Longitudinal Business Database (LBD) that tracks the employment dynamics, including entry and exit,firm size, andfirmage of
理解创新和生产力增长的决定因素是经济学研究的一个核心开放领域。尽管随着越来越多地使用企业层面的数据来量化创新和生产力的性质,创新的理论模型取得了巨大进展,但仍存在许多挑战。一个关键的挑战是,许多使用企业层面数据的研究都集中在对创新投入(例如,研发支出)有可观察指标和对创新成功(例如,专利)有直接指标的企业上。这种方法关注的是一个相对较低的子组的形式和扇区,这些可观测性是相关的。大多数公司不报告研发支出或专利。令人难以置信的是,只有具有这些可观察到的创新指标的公司才能对创新导致的生产率增长波动负责。作为证据,美国国家科学院的一份报告(Brown等人,2005)强调了研发数据的局限性,报告称零售业最具创新性的公司之一沃尔玛在其10-K报告中没有报告研发支出。本文采用了一种间接的方法来识别克服这些限制的创新活动。本文使用由创新质量阶梯模型驱动的创新增长会计框架,使用私营部门、非农(以下简称私营部门)机构的就业增长率分布数据来量化创造性破坏(CD)、自主创新和新品种的贡献。作者通过使用纵向商业数据库(LBD)来实现这一重要目标,该数据库跟踪就业动态,包括进入和退出、公司规模和公司年龄
{"title":"Comment","authors":"J. Haltiwanger","doi":"10.1086/712326","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/712326","url":null,"abstract":"Understanding the determinants of innovation and productivity growth is a core open area of economics research. Although enormous progress has beenmade in theoretical models of innovation accompanied by an increasing use of firm-level data to quantify the nature of innovation and productivity, many challenges remain. A key challenge is that much of the research using firm-level data has focused on firms with observable measures of the inputs into innovation (e.g., research and development [R&D] expenditures) and direct measures of the success of innovations (e.g., patents). This approach focuses on a relativelynarrow subset offirms and sectors where such observables are relevant. Most firms do not report R&D expenditures or patents. It is implausible that only the firms with these observable measures of innovation are responsible for the observed fluctuations in productivity growth from innovation. As evidence of this, a National Academy of Sciences report (Brown et al. 2005) highlighting the limitations of R&Ddata reported that one of themost innovative firms in retail trade, Walmart, reports no R&D expenditures in its 10-K reports. This paper takes an indirect approach to identifying innovation activity that overcomes these limitations. Using an innovative growth accounting framework that is motivated by a quality laddermodel of innovation, this paper uses data on the employment growth rate distribution for the universe of private sector, nonfarm (hereafter private sector for short) establishments to quantify the contribution of creative destruction (CD), own innovation, and new varieties. The authors accomplish this important objective by using the Longitudinal Business Database (LBD) that tracks the employment dynamics, including entry and exit,firm size, andfirmage of","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"35 1","pages":"296 - 307"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2021-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/712326","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"45729314","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Comment 评论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2021-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/712319
R. Hall
Authors Rossi-Hansberg, Sarte, and Trachter have delivered a focused, definitive paper, part of a broader research program on structural change in US product and labor markets. The subject of the paper is concentration. Measurement of concentration starts from the market definition. Concentration depends on the pattern of market shares within a market, defined by a product, a geographic region, and a time period. Amarket is a specification of the product, region, and time such that a hypothetical monopolist would have market power—it could elevate its price substantially abovemarginal cost. The connection to concentration is the general belief that the actual market power of the firms selling in a market depends on the number and importance of the competitors selling in that market. Themost widely usedmeasure of concentration—and the one used in this paper—is the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI), the sum of the squared market shares of the sellers in a market. This measure is sensitive to both the number of sellers and their market shares, and it is a sufficient statistic for the elevation of price over marginal cost in certain oligopoly models. However, other models, especially those involving collusion, predict substantial exercise ofmarket powerwithpricesmarked up well above marginal cost, in the face of HHI measures suggesting rather less price elevation. Some markets are national or international. The products in these markets have low transport cost across the country relative to price. A substantial body of research has found high and rising concentration in many national markets, primarily for manufactured goods. The paper confirms that finding. The paper does not pursue the key question of
作者Rossi Hansberg、Sarte和Trachter发表了一篇重点明确的论文,这是关于美国产品和劳动力市场结构变化的更广泛研究计划的一部分。这篇论文的主题是专注。集中度的衡量从市场定义开始。集中度取决于市场中的市场份额模式,由产品、地理区域和时间段定义。Amarket是一种产品、地区和时间的规范,假设的垄断者将拥有市场力量——它可以大幅提高价格,超过边际成本。与集中度的联系是,人们普遍认为,在一个市场上销售的公司的实际市场力量取决于在该市场销售的竞争对手的数量和重要性。最广泛使用的集中度指标——也是本文中使用的指标——是赫芬达尔-赫希曼指数(HHI),即市场中卖方市场份额的平方和。这一指标对卖家数量及其市场份额都很敏感,对于某些寡头垄断模型中价格高于边际成本的情况来说,这是一个足够的统计数据。然而,其他模型,尤其是那些涉及共谋的模型,预测了在HHI措施表明价格上涨幅度较小的情况下,市场权力的实质性行使,价格远高于边际成本。有些市场是国内或国际市场。相对于价格而言,这些市场上的产品在全国范围内的运输成本较低。大量研究发现,许多国家市场的集中度很高,而且越来越高,主要是制成品市场。该论文证实了这一发现。这篇论文没有探讨
{"title":"Comment","authors":"R. Hall","doi":"10.1086/712319","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/712319","url":null,"abstract":"Authors Rossi-Hansberg, Sarte, and Trachter have delivered a focused, definitive paper, part of a broader research program on structural change in US product and labor markets. The subject of the paper is concentration. Measurement of concentration starts from the market definition. Concentration depends on the pattern of market shares within a market, defined by a product, a geographic region, and a time period. Amarket is a specification of the product, region, and time such that a hypothetical monopolist would have market power—it could elevate its price substantially abovemarginal cost. The connection to concentration is the general belief that the actual market power of the firms selling in a market depends on the number and importance of the competitors selling in that market. Themost widely usedmeasure of concentration—and the one used in this paper—is the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI), the sum of the squared market shares of the sellers in a market. This measure is sensitive to both the number of sellers and their market shares, and it is a sufficient statistic for the elevation of price over marginal cost in certain oligopoly models. However, other models, especially those involving collusion, predict substantial exercise ofmarket powerwithpricesmarked up well above marginal cost, in the face of HHI measures suggesting rather less price elevation. Some markets are national or international. The products in these markets have low transport cost across the country relative to price. A substantial body of research has found high and rising concentration in many national markets, primarily for manufactured goods. The paper confirms that finding. The paper does not pursue the key question of","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"35 1","pages":"167 - 172"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2021-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/712319","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"44295694","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Nber Macroeconomics Annual
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1