首页 > 最新文献

Nber Macroeconomics Annual最新文献

英文 中文
Comment 评论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2023-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/723588
L. Tesar
During the COVIDpandemic, governments undertook large fiscal interventions—initially to support households and firms during mandated shutdowns and then, as the need for social distancing abated, to revive economic activity. Beginning in early 2020, the US government passed a sequence of bills to provide COVID support, totaling some $5.8 trillion and increasing the federal debt to gross domestic product (GDP) ratio from 107% in 2019 to 136% in 2021. Governments in Europe similarly enacted an ambitious set of fiscal policies, including an expansion of social safety nets, loan guarantees to firms to protect workers and jobs, and expanded flexibility in national and local debt limits. Over the same 2019– 21 period, euro area government debt increased from 84% to 96% of GDP (International Monetary Fund, n.d.). The debt figures for the euro area as a whole mask large differences across Europe, as the countries hardest hit by the pandemic (such as Spain and Italy) saw debt increases comparable to that of the United States. Relative to the United States, European governments tended to provide more above-the-line support such as loan guarantees, whereas US fiscal interventions relied more heavily on direct transfer payments to individuals. The focus ofAggarwal et al. is the transmission of these unprecedented, COVID-related fiscal expenditures across the set of advanced economies. The paper argues that debt-financed transfers during COVID resulted in predictable changes in the current account that persist over time. Countries that made larger-than-average transfers tended to run current account surpluses, whereas those below the average ran deficits. In the
在2019冠状病毒病大流行期间,各国政府采取了大规模财政干预措施,最初是为了在强制停工期间支持家庭和企业,然后随着保持社交距离的需求减弱,恢复经济活动。从2020年初开始,美国政府通过了一系列法案,提供COVID支持,总额约为5.8万亿美元,并将联邦债务与国内生产总值(GDP)的比率从2019年的107%提高到2021年的136%。欧洲各国政府同样制定了一套雄心勃勃的财政政策,包括扩大社会安全网,为企业提供贷款担保以保护工人和就业,以及扩大国家和地方债务限额的灵活性。在2019年至2021年的同一时期,欧元区政府债务从GDP的84%增加到96%(国际货币基金组织,n.d)。整个欧元区的债务数据掩盖了欧洲各国之间的巨大差异,因为受疫情影响最严重的国家(如西班牙和意大利)的债务增幅与美国相当。相对于美国,欧洲政府倾向于提供更多的线下支持,如贷款担保,而美国的财政干预更多地依赖于对个人的直接转移支付。aggarwal等人的重点是这些前所未有的、与新冠病毒相关的财政支出在发达经济体中的传导。本文认为,COVID期间的债务融资转移导致了经常账户的可预测变化,这种变化会持续一段时间。高于平均水平的国家往往有经常账户盈余,而低于平均水平的国家则有经常账户赤字。在
{"title":"Comment","authors":"L. Tesar","doi":"10.1086/723588","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/723588","url":null,"abstract":"During the COVIDpandemic, governments undertook large fiscal interventions—initially to support households and firms during mandated shutdowns and then, as the need for social distancing abated, to revive economic activity. Beginning in early 2020, the US government passed a sequence of bills to provide COVID support, totaling some $5.8 trillion and increasing the federal debt to gross domestic product (GDP) ratio from 107% in 2019 to 136% in 2021. Governments in Europe similarly enacted an ambitious set of fiscal policies, including an expansion of social safety nets, loan guarantees to firms to protect workers and jobs, and expanded flexibility in national and local debt limits. Over the same 2019– 21 period, euro area government debt increased from 84% to 96% of GDP (International Monetary Fund, n.d.). The debt figures for the euro area as a whole mask large differences across Europe, as the countries hardest hit by the pandemic (such as Spain and Italy) saw debt increases comparable to that of the United States. Relative to the United States, European governments tended to provide more above-the-line support such as loan guarantees, whereas US fiscal interventions relied more heavily on direct transfer payments to individuals. The focus ofAggarwal et al. is the transmission of these unprecedented, COVID-related fiscal expenditures across the set of advanced economies. The paper argues that debt-financed transfers during COVID resulted in predictable changes in the current account that persist over time. Countries that made larger-than-average transfers tended to run current account surpluses, whereas those below the average ran deficits. In the","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"37 1","pages":"423 - 431"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2023-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"43270345","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Intramolecular ligation method (iLIME) for pre-miRNA quantification and sequencing. 用于前 miRNA 定量和测序的分子内连接法(iLIME)。
IF 4.2 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-07-01 Epub Date: 2022-04-29 DOI: 10.1261/rna.079101.122
Minh Ngoc Le, Cong Truc Le, Tuan Anh Nguyen

Hairpin-containing pre-miRNAs, produced from pri-miRNAs, are precursors of miRNAs (microRNAs) that play essential roles in gene expression and various human diseases. Current qPCR-based methods used to quantify pre-miRNAs are not effective to discriminate between pre-miRNAs and their parental pri-miRNAs. Here, we developed the intramolecular ligation method (iLIME) to quantify and sequence pre-miRNAs specifically. This method utilizes T4 RNA ligase 1 to convert pre-miRNAs into circularized RNAs, allowing us to design PCR primers to quantify pre-miRNAs, but not their parental pri-miRNAs. In addition, the iLIME also enables us to sequence the ends of pre-miRNAs using next-generation sequencing. Therefore, this method offers a simple and effective way to quantify and sequence pre-miRNAs, so it will be highly beneficial for investigating pre-miRNAs when addressing research questions and medical applications.

由 pri-miRNA 生成的含发夹的 pre-miRNA 是 miRNA(microRNA)的前体,在基因表达和各种人类疾病中发挥着重要作用。目前用于量化 pre-miRNAs 的 qPCR 方法不能有效区分 pre-miRNAs 及其亲本 pri-miRNAs。在此,我们开发了分子内连接法(iLIME)来对 pre-miRNA 进行定量和测序。这种方法利用 T4 RNA 连接酶 1 将 pre-miRNA 转化为环化 RNA,使我们能够设计 PCR 引物来定量 pre-miRNA,而不是其亲本 pri-miRNA。此外,iLIME 还能让我们利用新一代测序技术对 pre-miRNA 的末端进行测序。因此,这种方法为 pre-miRNA 的定量和测序提供了一种简单而有效的途径,对研究问题和医学应用中的 pre-miRNA 调查大有裨益。
{"title":"Intramolecular ligation method (iLIME) for pre-miRNA quantification and sequencing.","authors":"Minh Ngoc Le, Cong Truc Le, Tuan Anh Nguyen","doi":"10.1261/rna.079101.122","DOIUrl":"10.1261/rna.079101.122","url":null,"abstract":"<p><p>Hairpin-containing pre-miRNAs, produced from pri-miRNAs, are precursors of miRNAs (microRNAs) that play essential roles in gene expression and various human diseases. Current qPCR-based methods used to quantify pre-miRNAs are not effective to discriminate between pre-miRNAs and their parental pri-miRNAs. Here, we developed the intramolecular ligation method (iLIME) to quantify and sequence pre-miRNAs specifically. This method utilizes T4 RNA ligase 1 to convert pre-miRNAs into circularized RNAs, allowing us to design PCR primers to quantify pre-miRNAs, but not their parental pri-miRNAs. In addition, the iLIME also enables us to sequence the ends of pre-miRNAs using next-generation sequencing. Therefore, this method offers a simple and effective way to quantify and sequence pre-miRNAs, so it will be highly beneficial for investigating pre-miRNAs when addressing research questions and medical applications.</p>","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"5 1","pages":"1028-1038"},"PeriodicalIF":4.2,"publicationDate":"2022-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC9202589/pdf/","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"83260254","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
A Reassessment of Monetary Policy Surprises and High-Frequency Identification 货币政策意外和高频识别的再评估
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-04-01 DOI: 10.1086/723574
M. Bauer, Eric T. Swanson
High-frequency changes in interest rates around FOMC announcements are an important tool for identifying the effects of monetary policy on asset prices and the macroeconomy. However, some recent studies have questioned both the exogeneity and the relevance of these monetary policy surprises as instruments, especially for estimating the macroeconomic effects of monetary policy shocks. For example, monetary policy surprises are correlated with macroeconomic and financial data that is publicly available prior to the FOMC announcement. We address these concerns in two ways: First, we expand the set of monetary policy announcements to include speeches by the Fed Chair, which essentially doubles the number and importance of announcements in our dataset. Second, we explain the predictability of the monetary policy surprises in terms of the “Fed response to news” channel of Bauer and Swanson (2021) and account for it by orthogonalizing the surprises with respect to macroeconomic and financial data. Our subsequent reassessment of the effects of monetary policy yields two key results: First, estimates of the high-frequency effects on financial markets are largely unchanged. Second, estimates of the macroeconomic effects of monetary policy are substantially larger and more significant than what most previous empirical studies have found.
FOMC公告前后利率的高频变化是识别货币政策对资产价格和宏观经济影响的重要工具。然而,最近的一些研究对这些货币政策意外作为工具的外生性和相关性提出了质疑,特别是在估计货币政策冲击的宏观经济影响方面。例如,货币政策的意外与联邦公开市场委员会宣布之前公开的宏观经济和金融数据相关。我们通过两种方式解决这些问题:首先,我们扩大了货币政策公告的集合,包括美联储主席的讲话,这基本上使我们数据集中公告的数量和重要性增加了一倍。其次,我们根据Bauer和Swanson(2021)的“美联储对新闻的反应”渠道解释了货币政策意外的可预测性,并通过将意外与宏观经济和金融数据正交来解释它。我们随后对货币政策影响的重新评估得出了两个关键结论:首先,对金融市场高频效应的估计基本上没有变化。其次,对货币政策宏观经济影响的估计,比以往大多数实证研究发现的要大得多,意义也更重大。
{"title":"A Reassessment of Monetary Policy Surprises and High-Frequency Identification","authors":"M. Bauer, Eric T. Swanson","doi":"10.1086/723574","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/723574","url":null,"abstract":"High-frequency changes in interest rates around FOMC announcements are an important tool for identifying the effects of monetary policy on asset prices and the macroeconomy. However, some recent studies have questioned both the exogeneity and the relevance of these monetary policy surprises as instruments, especially for estimating the macroeconomic effects of monetary policy shocks. For example, monetary policy surprises are correlated with macroeconomic and financial data that is publicly available prior to the FOMC announcement. We address these concerns in two ways: First, we expand the set of monetary policy announcements to include speeches by the Fed Chair, which essentially doubles the number and importance of announcements in our dataset. Second, we explain the predictability of the monetary policy surprises in terms of the “Fed response to news” channel of Bauer and Swanson (2021) and account for it by orthogonalizing the surprises with respect to macroeconomic and financial data. Our subsequent reassessment of the effects of monetary policy yields two key results: First, estimates of the high-frequency effects on financial markets are largely unchanged. Second, estimates of the macroeconomic effects of monetary policy are substantially larger and more significant than what most previous empirical studies have found.","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"37 1","pages":"87 - 155"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2022-04-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"48865276","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 58
Stubborn Beliefs in Search Equilibrium 搜索均衡中的顽固信念
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-04-01 DOI: 10.1086/723582
G. Menzio
I study a search equilibrium model of the labor market in which workers have stubborn beliefs about their labor market prospects, i.e. beliefs about their probability of (cid:133)nding a job and the wage they will earn that do not respond to aggregate (cid:135)uctuations in fundamentals. I show that, when workers have stubborn beliefs, the response of the wage bargained by a (cid:133)rm and a worker to aggregate shocks is dampened. As a result, the response of labor market tightness, job-(cid:133)nding probability, unemployment and vacancies to aggregate (cid:135)uctuations is ampli(cid:133)ed. I show that stubborn beliefs generate cyclical ine¢ ciencies in the labor market that can be corrected with countercyclical employment subsidies. I (cid:133)nd that the response of the labor market to negative shocks is the same even if only a small fraction of workers has stubborn beliefs. In contrast, if the fraction of workers with stubborn beliefs is small, the response of the labor market to positive shocks is approximately the same as under rational expectations.
我研究了一个劳动力市场的搜索均衡模型,在该模型中,工人对他们的劳动力市场前景有着顽固的信念,即对他们找到工作的概率(cid:133)和他们将获得的工资的信念,这些信念对基本面上的总(cid:135)波动没有反应。我表明,当工人有顽固的信念时,(cid:133)rm和工人讨价还价的工资对总体冲击的反应会减弱。因此,劳动力市场紧缩、就业(cid:133)概率、失业率和职位空缺对总(cid:135)产出的反应是扩大的。我表明,顽固的信念会在劳动力市场中产生周期性的不确定性,这种不确定性可以通过反周期的就业补贴来纠正。我(cid:133)认为,即使只有一小部分工人有顽固的信念,劳动力市场对负面冲击的反应也是一样的。相比之下,如果有顽固信念的工人比例很小,那么劳动力市场对积极冲击的反应与理性预期下的反应大致相同。
{"title":"Stubborn Beliefs in Search Equilibrium","authors":"G. Menzio","doi":"10.1086/723582","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/723582","url":null,"abstract":"I study a search equilibrium model of the labor market in which workers have stubborn beliefs about their labor market prospects, i.e. beliefs about their probability of (cid:133)nding a job and the wage they will earn that do not respond to aggregate (cid:135)uctuations in fundamentals. I show that, when workers have stubborn beliefs, the response of the wage bargained by a (cid:133)rm and a worker to aggregate shocks is dampened. As a result, the response of labor market tightness, job-(cid:133)nding probability, unemployment and vacancies to aggregate (cid:135)uctuations is ampli(cid:133)ed. I show that stubborn beliefs generate cyclical ine¢ ciencies in the labor market that can be corrected with countercyclical employment subsidies. I (cid:133)nd that the response of the labor market to negative shocks is the same even if only a small fraction of workers has stubborn beliefs. In contrast, if the fraction of workers with stubborn beliefs is small, the response of the labor market to positive shocks is approximately the same as under rational expectations.","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"37 1","pages":"239 - 297"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2022-04-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"47868430","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Comment 评论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/718670
Per Krusell
The authors develop a climate-economy framework whose main purpose is to illustrate the importance of taking “the unknown” seriously in this area. More precisely, the paper considers risk, model ambiguity, and model misspecification. The focus is on the decision problem of a plannerwhose preferences embody uncertainty aversion. That is, amarket outcome is not considered. The key contribution of the paper is to propose a framework—that is, methods useful for addressing this kind of issue—and then to apply it to three examples. None of the examples can be viewed as full-fledged, quantitative settings, so it is difficult to draw concrete policy conclusions from them. At the same time, they illustrate possible magnitudes that could arise. Overall it is an impressive paper. My commentswill be organized into three sections: Iwill discuss the broad motivation for focusing on uncertainty, I will comment on the specific modeling approach, and I will make concluding remarks.
作者制定了一个气候经济框架,其主要目的是说明在这一领域认真对待“未知”的重要性。更准确地说,本文考虑了风险、模型模糊性和模型错误指定。重点研究了偏好体现不确定性厌恶的规划者的决策问题。也就是说,没有考虑苦杏仁的结果。本文的主要贡献是提出了一个框架——也就是说,有助于解决这类问题的方法——然后将其应用于三个例子。没有一个例子可以被视为全面的、定量的背景,因此很难从中得出具体的政策结论。同时,它们说明了可能出现的幅度。总的来说,这是一篇令人印象深刻的论文。我的评论将分为三个部分:我将讨论关注不确定性的广泛动机,我将评论具体的建模方法,我将发表结论性意见。
{"title":"Comment","authors":"Per Krusell","doi":"10.1086/718670","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/718670","url":null,"abstract":"The authors develop a climate-economy framework whose main purpose is to illustrate the importance of taking “the unknown” seriously in this area. More precisely, the paper considers risk, model ambiguity, and model misspecification. The focus is on the decision problem of a plannerwhose preferences embody uncertainty aversion. That is, amarket outcome is not considered. The key contribution of the paper is to propose a framework—that is, methods useful for addressing this kind of issue—and then to apply it to three examples. None of the examples can be viewed as full-fledged, quantitative settings, so it is difficult to draw concrete policy conclusions from them. At the same time, they illustrate possible magnitudes that could arise. Overall it is an impressive paper. My commentswill be organized into three sections: Iwill discuss the broad motivation for focusing on uncertainty, I will comment on the specific modeling approach, and I will make concluding remarks.","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"36 1","pages":"329 - 334"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2022-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"46512205","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Comment 评论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/718669
M. Reguant
Barnett, Brock, and Hansen build a theoretical and quantitative framework to incorporate concepts of uncertainty and ambiguity aversion to climate policy modeling. Their primary focus is on building a tractable dynamic model that includes uncertainty about carbon dynamics, temperature dynamics, and damage functions in a parsimonious way. Their model features state-of-the-art tools in asset pricing with a continuoustimemodel, emphasizing specific processes of uncertainty, such as regime changes (jump processes) and misspecified Brownian increments. This model extends the authors’ previous work (Barnett, Brock, and Hansen 2020). Climate carbon and temperature dynamics follow scientific inputs that combine various climatemodels (Joos et al. 2013). The static economic game is simple, focused on investment and consumption choices over time. There are no explicit prices. The use of emissions in production, which are costly from a climate-change perspective, largely determines the shadow price of consumption. The paper presented by Barnett et al. is a serious attempt at modeling uncertainty from a mathematical point of view. A comprehensive treatment of uncertainty surrounding climate change, such as the one proposed in this paper, seems warranted. I agree that there are significant uncertainties to be studied, particularly regarding the ability of humanity to adapt and mitigate the change (policy and economic uncertainty) as well as surrounding the possibility of major tipping points (Cai et al. 2015; Lemoine and Traeger 2016). Indeed, the authors find that uncertainty
Barnett、Brock和Hansen建立了一个理论和定量框架,将不确定性和模糊性厌恶概念纳入气候政策建模。他们的主要重点是建立一个易于处理的动态模型,其中包括碳动力学、温度动力学和损伤函数的不确定性。他们的模型采用了最先进的资产定价工具和连续模型,强调了不确定性的具体过程,如制度变化(跳跃过程)和错误指定的布朗增量。该模型扩展了作者之前的工作(Barnett, Brock, and Hansen 2020)。气候碳和温度动态遵循结合各种气候模型的科学输入(Joos et al. 2013)。静态经济博弈很简单,关注的是一段时间内的投资和消费选择。没有明确的价格。从气候变化的角度来看,在生产中使用排放物的成本很高,这在很大程度上决定了消费的影子价格。Barnett等人提出的论文是从数学角度对不确定性建模的认真尝试。对围绕气候变化的不确定性的综合处理,如本文中提出的,似乎是有必要的。我同意有很大的不确定性需要研究,特别是关于人类适应和减缓变化的能力(政策和经济的不确定性),以及围绕主要临界点的可能性(Cai et al. 2015;Lemoine and Traeger 2016)。事实上,作者发现了这种不确定性
{"title":"Comment","authors":"M. Reguant","doi":"10.1086/718669","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/718669","url":null,"abstract":"Barnett, Brock, and Hansen build a theoretical and quantitative framework to incorporate concepts of uncertainty and ambiguity aversion to climate policy modeling. Their primary focus is on building a tractable dynamic model that includes uncertainty about carbon dynamics, temperature dynamics, and damage functions in a parsimonious way. Their model features state-of-the-art tools in asset pricing with a continuoustimemodel, emphasizing specific processes of uncertainty, such as regime changes (jump processes) and misspecified Brownian increments. This model extends the authors’ previous work (Barnett, Brock, and Hansen 2020). Climate carbon and temperature dynamics follow scientific inputs that combine various climatemodels (Joos et al. 2013). The static economic game is simple, focused on investment and consumption choices over time. There are no explicit prices. The use of emissions in production, which are costly from a climate-change perspective, largely determines the shadow price of consumption. The paper presented by Barnett et al. is a serious attempt at modeling uncertainty from a mathematical point of view. A comprehensive treatment of uncertainty surrounding climate change, such as the one proposed in this paper, seems warranted. I agree that there are significant uncertainties to be studied, particularly regarding the ability of humanity to adapt and mitigate the change (policy and economic uncertainty) as well as surrounding the possibility of major tipping points (Cai et al. 2015; Lemoine and Traeger 2016). Indeed, the authors find that uncertainty","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"36 1","pages":"321 - 328"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2022-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"47061556","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Discussion 讨论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/718671
D. Acemoglu
Daron Acemoglu opened the discussion by recognizing the importance of the topic. Then, in agreement with the discussants, he argued for a number of potentially fruitful extensions of the model. First, he expressed the desirability ofwidening the scope of the analysis to include issues such as irreversibility and tipping points. He added that it would be useful to jointly analyze emissions and mitigation actions, which are themselves uncertain or subject to uncertain learning. In the presence of uncertainty, it might be optimal to be conservative in emissions butmore experimental in mitigation policies such as investment in renewable energy and carbon sequestration. This is because the latter act as insurancemechanisms. Mar Reguant expressed concern that in the current model, dire scenarios can be avoided by losing only 20% of utility, and this seems infeasible. Lars Hansen agreed that he and his collaborators look forward to pushing the analysis in the ways mentioned and in other directions, while preserving tractability. The point of this paper is to argue for taking a broader approach to uncertainty than is typical in this and other literatures and to show that this can be quantitatively important. In regard to tipping points in particular, Hansen added that the introduction of a probabilistic structure on tipping points opens up new research challenges by pushing beyondpure riskmodels to amore nuanced approach that recognizes the limited knowledge of the timing and magnitude of such events. The discussion then centered around the issue of discounting. James Stock pointed out that implementing a stochastic approach to discounting under uncertainty is a complex procedure that requires information on outcomes of covariances and consumption paths, which might
Daron Acemoglu在开始讨论时承认了这个话题的重要性。然后,在与讨论者的意见一致的情况下,他主张对该模式进行一些可能富有成效的扩展。首先,他表示希望确定分析的范围,包括不可逆转性和临界点等问题。他补充说,联合分析排放和缓解行动将是有益的,因为这些行动本身是不确定的或需要进行不确定的学习。在存在不确定性的情况下,最好在排放方面保持保守,但在可再生能源投资和碳封存等缓解政策方面更具实验性。这是因为后者起到了保险机制的作用。Mar Reguant表示担心,在目前的模型中,只损失20%的效用就可以避免可怕的情况,这似乎是不可行的。Lars Hansen同意,他和他的合作者期待着以上述方式和其他方向推动分析,同时保持易处理性。本文的目的是主张对不确定性采取比这篇文献和其他文献中典型的更广泛的方法,并表明这在数量上是重要的。特别是关于临界点,Hansen补充道,引入临界点的概率结构,通过将超越纯粹的风险模型推向一种更微妙的方法,从而开启了新的研究挑战,这种方法认识到对此类事件的时间和规模的有限知识。当时的讨论集中在折扣问题上。James Stock指出,在不确定性下实施随机贴现方法是一个复杂的过程,需要关于协变量和消费路径的结果的信息,这可能
{"title":"Discussion","authors":"D. Acemoglu","doi":"10.1086/718671","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/718671","url":null,"abstract":"Daron Acemoglu opened the discussion by recognizing the importance of the topic. Then, in agreement with the discussants, he argued for a number of potentially fruitful extensions of the model. First, he expressed the desirability ofwidening the scope of the analysis to include issues such as irreversibility and tipping points. He added that it would be useful to jointly analyze emissions and mitigation actions, which are themselves uncertain or subject to uncertain learning. In the presence of uncertainty, it might be optimal to be conservative in emissions butmore experimental in mitigation policies such as investment in renewable energy and carbon sequestration. This is because the latter act as insurancemechanisms. Mar Reguant expressed concern that in the current model, dire scenarios can be avoided by losing only 20% of utility, and this seems infeasible. Lars Hansen agreed that he and his collaborators look forward to pushing the analysis in the ways mentioned and in other directions, while preserving tractability. The point of this paper is to argue for taking a broader approach to uncertainty than is typical in this and other literatures and to show that this can be quantitatively important. In regard to tipping points in particular, Hansen added that the introduction of a probabilistic structure on tipping points opens up new research challenges by pushing beyondpure riskmodels to amore nuanced approach that recognizes the limited knowledge of the timing and magnitude of such events. The discussion then centered around the issue of discounting. James Stock pointed out that implementing a stochastic approach to discounting under uncertainty is a complex procedure that requires information on outcomes of covariances and consumption paths, which might","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"36 1","pages":"335 - 336"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2022-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"45825036","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Comment 评论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/718655
R. Shimer
In this provocative paper, Hall and Kudlyak show that during a typical recession in the United States from 1949 to 2019, a short-lived burst of job loss explains much of the rapid increase in the unemployment rate. During the subsequent expansion, unemployment declines comparatively slowly and steadily, primarily due to a sharp and persistent decline in the job finding rate, both for the initial group of job losers and for other workers who became unemployed only later in the business cycle. Hall and Kudlyak argue that the elevated jobless rate for the latter group is evidence that unemployment is “contagious” or “infectious.” For the most part, I will not take issue with their facts, although I will make the (well-known) observation that the 2020 pandemic recession and subsequent expansion featured the fastest increase in unemployment on record, followed by the fastest decrease on record. Although this recession was different in many ways from past ones, the fact that unemployment fell so quickly during the early stages of this expansionmay be useful for diagnosing why unemployment declined so slowly during prior expansions. I will focusmy attention on the claim that unemployment is contagious or infectious. Hall and Kudlyak are very clear about what they mean by this: “We consider negative feedback from high unemployment to the job finding rate as a key mechanism behind the slow unemployment recoveries.” The function g(u) in equation (14) exemplifies this logic. SectionVIII of their paper sketches a number of endogenousmechanisms that cangenerate such feedback. Iwill not try to critique each—or indeed any—
在这篇颇具争议的论文中,霍尔和库德利亚克指出,在1949年至2019年美国典型的经济衰退期间,短暂的失业爆发在很大程度上解释了失业率的快速上升。在随后的经济扩张期间,失业率相对缓慢而稳定地下降,这主要是由于求职率急剧而持续的下降,无论是对最初的失业群体,还是对在经济周期后期才失业的其他工人。霍尔和库德利亚克认为,后一类人失业率的上升证明失业具有“传染性”或“传染性”。在很大程度上,我不会对他们的事实提出异议,尽管我将提出(众所周知的)观察,即2020年的大流行经济衰退和随后的扩张是有记录以来失业率增长最快的一次,随后是有记录以来失业率下降最快的一次。尽管这次经济衰退在许多方面与以往有所不同,但在经济扩张的早期阶段失业率下降得如此之快,这一事实可能有助于诊断为什么在之前的经济扩张期间失业率下降得如此之慢。我将重点关注失业具有传染性或传染性的说法。霍尔和库德利亚克非常清楚他们的意思:“我们认为,高失业率对求职率的负面反馈是失业率缓慢复苏背后的一个关键机制。”方程(14)中的函数g(u)说明了这种逻辑。他们论文的第八节概述了产生这种反馈的一些内在机制。我不会试图批判每一个,或者任何一个
{"title":"Comment","authors":"R. Shimer","doi":"10.1086/718655","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/718655","url":null,"abstract":"In this provocative paper, Hall and Kudlyak show that during a typical recession in the United States from 1949 to 2019, a short-lived burst of job loss explains much of the rapid increase in the unemployment rate. During the subsequent expansion, unemployment declines comparatively slowly and steadily, primarily due to a sharp and persistent decline in the job finding rate, both for the initial group of job losers and for other workers who became unemployed only later in the business cycle. Hall and Kudlyak argue that the elevated jobless rate for the latter group is evidence that unemployment is “contagious” or “infectious.” For the most part, I will not take issue with their facts, although I will make the (well-known) observation that the 2020 pandemic recession and subsequent expansion featured the fastest increase in unemployment on record, followed by the fastest decrease on record. Although this recession was different in many ways from past ones, the fact that unemployment fell so quickly during the early stages of this expansionmay be useful for diagnosing why unemployment declined so slowly during prior expansions. I will focusmy attention on the claim that unemployment is contagious or infectious. Hall and Kudlyak are very clear about what they mean by this: “We consider negative feedback from high unemployment to the job finding rate as a key mechanism behind the slow unemployment recoveries.” The function g(u) in equation (14) exemplifies this logic. SectionVIII of their paper sketches a number of endogenousmechanisms that cangenerate such feedback. Iwill not try to critique each—or indeed any—","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"36 1","pages":"56 - 67"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2022-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"48057167","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Comment 评论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/718665
Nir Jaimovich
In recent years, various Organisation for Economic Co-operation andDevelopment (OECD) countries have implemented reforms targeting work incentives directed at older workers. So understanding how such reforms affect the labor market is crucial. I see this interesting and important paper by Richard Rogerson and JohannaWalleniusas as a first step in an exciting new research agenda. In this paper, the authors investigate the link between the labor market policy reforms targeting older workers and these workers’ employment rates. The paper presents an extremely useful synthesis that brings together findings from different countries, and it suggests an important avenue for further research. The paper contains numerous insights, and below I discuss the main argument. First, the authors document that the employment rate of men aged 55–64 has displayed aU-shaped pattern over the last 4 decades. Interestingly (and somewhat surprisingly), this pattern is common across many advanced economies, hinting that a common explanation could be responsible for it. At the same time, the reversal’s magnitude varies across countries. The explanation the authors put forth is based on three steps. First, the authors argue for the importance of “institutions” that gave rise to provisions that favored a reduction in employment rate of this older age group inmany countries in the 1970s and 1980s. Second, they suggest there was a mean-reverting aggregate shock that led to a recovery in the employment
近年来,经济合作与发展组织(OECD)的各个国家都实施了针对老年工人的工作激励措施的改革。因此,了解这些改革对劳动力市场的影响至关重要。我认为Richard Rogerson和Johanna Walleniusas的这篇有趣而重要的论文是令人兴奋的新研究议程的第一步。在本文中,作者调查了针对老年工人的劳动力市场政策改革与这些工人的就业率之间的联系。这篇论文汇集了来自不同国家的研究结果,提供了一个非常有用的综合,并为进一步研究提供了一条重要途径。这篇论文包含了许多见解,下面我将讨论主要论点。首先,作者记录了55-64岁男性的就业率在过去40年中呈U型模式。有趣的是(也有点令人惊讶),这种模式在许多发达经济体中很常见,这暗示着一种共同的解释可能是造成这种情况的原因。与此同时,这种逆转的程度因国家而异。作者提出的解释基于三个步骤。首先,作者认为“制度”的重要性,这些制度在20世纪70年代和80年代产生了有利于降低许多国家这一老年群体就业率的条款。其次,他们认为存在一种均值回归的总体冲击,导致就业复苏
{"title":"Comment","authors":"Nir Jaimovich","doi":"10.1086/718665","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/718665","url":null,"abstract":"In recent years, various Organisation for Economic Co-operation andDevelopment (OECD) countries have implemented reforms targeting work incentives directed at older workers. So understanding how such reforms affect the labor market is crucial. I see this interesting and important paper by Richard Rogerson and JohannaWalleniusas as a first step in an exciting new research agenda. In this paper, the authors investigate the link between the labor market policy reforms targeting older workers and these workers’ employment rates. The paper presents an extremely useful synthesis that brings together findings from different countries, and it suggests an important avenue for further research. The paper contains numerous insights, and below I discuss the main argument. First, the authors document that the employment rate of men aged 55–64 has displayed aU-shaped pattern over the last 4 decades. Interestingly (and somewhat surprisingly), this pattern is common across many advanced economies, hinting that a common explanation could be responsible for it. At the same time, the reversal’s magnitude varies across countries. The explanation the authors put forth is based on three steps. First, the authors argue for the importance of “institutions” that gave rise to provisions that favored a reduction in employment rate of this older age group inmany countries in the 1970s and 1980s. Second, they suggest there was a mean-reverting aggregate shock that led to a recovery in the employment","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"36 1","pages":"217 - 233"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2022-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"47171026","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Comment 评论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/718673
R. Pande, Nils Enevoldsen
Neoclassical growth theory posits that countries with access to identical technologies should converge to a common income level. However, an important literature, exemplified by Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1992), tested this prediction using cross-country data from 1960 to 1990 and instead found conditional convergence. That is, poor countries converged in growth to rich countries only after conditioning on policies, institutions, and other country-specific factors such as human capital. “Converging to Convergence” extends the underlying data series up to 2015, reestimates cross-country growth regressions, and documents a striking change. Since the mid-1980s, there has been a trend toward unconditional convergence culminating in absolute convergence since 2000 (roughly 1% per annum). The paper examines convergence in correlates of growth, andfinds that enhanced Solow fundamentals (s, n, h), short-run correlates (political and financial institutions, fiscal policy), and culture all show b-convergence. This evidence, the authors suggest, is supportive of “institutional homogenization” contributing to absolute convergence: short-run growth coefficients diminished because convergence of “development-favored” policies outpaced that of income. Importantly, the same is not true of Solow fundamentals. The paper is based on an impressive collation of data sets and careful standardization of conditioning variables. Using the original empirical specification developed in Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1992), it documents
新古典增长理论认为,能够获得相同技术的国家应该达到共同的收入水平。然而,以Barro和Sala-i-Martin(1992)为例的一篇重要文献,使用1960年至1990年的跨国数据对这一预测进行了测试,并发现了条件收敛性。也就是说,只有在政策、制度和其他特定于国家的因素(如人力资本)的影响下,贫穷国家的增长才会向富裕国家趋同。“收敛到收敛”将基础数据系列扩展到2015年,重新估计跨国增长回归,并记录了一个惊人的变化。自20世纪80年代中期以来,出现了无条件趋同的趋势,自2000年以来达到了绝对趋同(每年约1%)。本文考察了增长相关因素的趋同,发现索洛基本面(s,n,h)增强、短期相关因素(政治和金融机构、财政政策)和文化都表现出b-趋同。作者认为,这一证据支持“制度同质化”有助于绝对趋同:短期增长系数下降是因为“有利于发展”的政策的趋同超过了收入的趋同。重要的是,索洛的基本面并非如此。这篇论文是基于对数据集的令人印象深刻的整理和对条件变量的仔细标准化。使用Barro和Sala-i-Martin(1992)中开发的原始经验规范,它记录了
{"title":"Comment","authors":"R. Pande, Nils Enevoldsen","doi":"10.1086/718673","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/718673","url":null,"abstract":"Neoclassical growth theory posits that countries with access to identical technologies should converge to a common income level. However, an important literature, exemplified by Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1992), tested this prediction using cross-country data from 1960 to 1990 and instead found conditional convergence. That is, poor countries converged in growth to rich countries only after conditioning on policies, institutions, and other country-specific factors such as human capital. “Converging to Convergence” extends the underlying data series up to 2015, reestimates cross-country growth regressions, and documents a striking change. Since the mid-1980s, there has been a trend toward unconditional convergence culminating in absolute convergence since 2000 (roughly 1% per annum). The paper examines convergence in correlates of growth, andfinds that enhanced Solow fundamentals (s, n, h), short-run correlates (political and financial institutions, fiscal policy), and culture all show b-convergence. This evidence, the authors suggest, is supportive of “institutional homogenization” contributing to absolute convergence: short-run growth coefficients diminished because convergence of “development-favored” policies outpaced that of income. Importantly, the same is not true of Solow fundamentals. The paper is based on an impressive collation of data sets and careful standardization of conditioning variables. Using the original empirical specification developed in Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1992), it documents","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"36 1","pages":"413 - 424"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2022-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"42108048","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
期刊
Nber Macroeconomics Annual
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1