首页 > 最新文献

Nber Macroeconomics Annual最新文献

英文 中文
Comment 评论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2020-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/707170
Janice C. Eberly
The paper byCovarrubias, Gutiérrez, and Philippon providesmany useful insights into the rapidly emerging literature on rising concentration in US industries. Importantly, it catalogs some important empirical shortcomings in the literature. It also provides clarity on conceptual issues that have created confusion. The paper goes on to make two types of original empirical contributions. In the first, it focuses on two categories of explanations for rising concentration: “good” and “bad.” The former is associated with technological change that increases the elasticity of substitution among goods (j, and hence greater competition) or increases firms’ accumulation of intangible capital (g, perhaps associated with network externalities and returns to scale). Bad concentration is instead associated with rising barriers to entry, k. The authors argue that the data tend to favor good concentration earlier in their data sample—through 2000. Thereafter, there is increasing evidence of barriers to competition. The collection of evidence, while not dispositive, moves the weight of the evidence toward market power explanations, especially later in the sample. The last part of the paper takes a different tack. Instead of looking for indicators ofmarket power to explain a broad range of facts, the paper looks at combinations of explanations by industry and argues that there is merit in several of them and that the results vary by industry. I will argue that these last insights are especially helpful, as the macroeconomic data are unlikely to be captured by a single simple narrative.
covarrubias, guti rez和Philippon的论文为美国工业集中度上升的快速兴起的文献提供了许多有用的见解。重要的是,它列出了文献中一些重要的经验性缺陷。它还澄清了造成混淆的概念问题。本文接着提出了两种原创性的实证贡献。首先,它着重于两类对注意力集中的解释:“好”和“坏”。前者与技术变革有关,技术变革增加了商品之间的替代弹性(j,从而增加了竞争)或增加了企业无形资本的积累(g,可能与网络外部性和规模回报有关)。相反,较差的集中度与进入门槛的上升有关,k。作者认为,在他们的数据样本中,数据倾向于较早的集中度,直到2000年。此后,越来越多的证据表明存在竞争壁垒。证据的收集,虽然不是决定性的,但将证据的权重转移到市场力量的解释上,特别是在样本的后面。论文的最后一部分采取了不同的策略。这篇论文没有寻找市场力量的指标来解释广泛的事实,而是研究了行业解释的组合,并认为其中一些解释是有价值的,结果因行业而异。我认为,最后这些见解尤其有用,因为宏观经济数据不太可能被一种简单的叙述所捕捉。
{"title":"Comment","authors":"Janice C. Eberly","doi":"10.1086/707170","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/707170","url":null,"abstract":"The paper byCovarrubias, Gutiérrez, and Philippon providesmany useful insights into the rapidly emerging literature on rising concentration in US industries. Importantly, it catalogs some important empirical shortcomings in the literature. It also provides clarity on conceptual issues that have created confusion. The paper goes on to make two types of original empirical contributions. In the first, it focuses on two categories of explanations for rising concentration: “good” and “bad.” The former is associated with technological change that increases the elasticity of substitution among goods (j, and hence greater competition) or increases firms’ accumulation of intangible capital (g, perhaps associated with network externalities and returns to scale). Bad concentration is instead associated with rising barriers to entry, k. The authors argue that the data tend to favor good concentration earlier in their data sample—through 2000. Thereafter, there is increasing evidence of barriers to competition. The collection of evidence, while not dispositive, moves the weight of the evidence toward market power explanations, especially later in the sample. The last part of the paper takes a different tack. Instead of looking for indicators ofmarket power to explain a broad range of facts, the paper looks at combinations of explanations by industry and argues that there is merit in several of them and that the results vary by industry. I will argue that these last insights are especially helpful, as the macroeconomic data are unlikely to be captured by a single simple narrative.","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"34 1","pages":"47 - 54"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2020-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/707170","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"60709639","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Editorial 编辑
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2020-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/707168
M. Eichenbaum, Erik Hurst, J. Parker
The NBER’s thirty-fourth Annual Conference on Macroeconomics brought together leading scholars to present, discuss, and debate six research papers on central issues in contemporary macroeconomics. In addition, James Stock, former chief economist and director of research at the International Monetary Fund, delivered a thought-provoking afterdinner talk on the economics of climate change. Video recordings of the presentations of the papers and the after-dinner talk are all accessible on the web page of the NBER Annual Conference on Macroeconomics (https:// www.nber.org/macroannualconference2019/macroannual2019.html). These videos,whichmake the content of the conferencemorewidely accessible, are a useful complement to this volume. This conference volume contains edited versions of the six papers presented at the conference, each followed by two written comments by leading scholars and a summary discussion of the debates that followed each paper. The volume also contains a paper, “Climate Change, Climate Policy, and Economic Growth,” by James Stock, based on his dinner talk. The paper provides an extremely useful introduction to the topic of climate change and climate change policy formacroeconomists. The paper makes four key points. First, simple time-series regression models confirm that essentially all the warming over the past 140 years is due to human activity. Second, policy has a crucial role toplay ifwe are to succeed in decarbonizing the economy. Third, current policies will not succeed in decarbonizing the economy in time to prevent severe damage from climate change. Fourth, the politics, as opposed to the economics, of Pigouvian carbon pricing do notwork. This suggests the importance of considering other policies, especially those that drive low-carbon technical innovation. There was no discussant for the paper because of its origin as a dinner talk. We are grateful to James Stock for taking the time to write up his comments on this vitally important topic.
美国国家经济研究局第三十四届宏观经济学年会汇集了顶尖学者,就当代宏观经济学的核心问题发表、讨论和辩论了六篇研究论文。此外,国际货币基金组织(imf)前首席经济学家兼研究部主任詹姆斯•斯托克(James Stock)在餐后就气候变化经济学问题发表了发人深省的演讲。论文演讲和饭后谈话的录像都可以在美国国家经济研究局宏观经济学年会的网页上(https:// www.nber.org/macroannualconference2019/macroannual2019.html)获得。这些录像使会议的内容更容易获得,是对本卷的有益补充。本会议卷包含在会议上发表的六篇论文的编辑版本,每篇论文后面都有两位主要学者的书面评论和每篇论文之后辩论的总结讨论。该卷还包括詹姆斯·斯托克的一篇论文《气候变化、气候政策和经济增长》,该论文是根据他的晚餐谈话撰写的。本文为宏观经济学家提供了关于气候变化和气候变化政策的非常有用的介绍。本文提出了四个关键点。首先,简单的时间序列回归模型证实,过去140年的所有变暖基本上都是由人类活动造成的。其次,如果我们要成功实现经济脱碳,政策将发挥至关重要的作用。第三,目前的政策无法及时成功地使经济脱碳,以防止气候变化造成的严重损害。第四,与经济学相反,庇古碳定价理论在政治上行不通。这表明考虑其他政策的重要性,尤其是那些推动低碳技术创新的政策。这篇论文没有讨论者,因为它起源于晚宴上的谈话。我们感谢詹姆斯·斯托克花时间就这个至关重要的话题写下他的评论。
{"title":"Editorial","authors":"M. Eichenbaum, Erik Hurst, J. Parker","doi":"10.1086/707168","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/707168","url":null,"abstract":"The NBER’s thirty-fourth Annual Conference on Macroeconomics brought together leading scholars to present, discuss, and debate six research papers on central issues in contemporary macroeconomics. In addition, James Stock, former chief economist and director of research at the International Monetary Fund, delivered a thought-provoking afterdinner talk on the economics of climate change. Video recordings of the presentations of the papers and the after-dinner talk are all accessible on the web page of the NBER Annual Conference on Macroeconomics (https:// www.nber.org/macroannualconference2019/macroannual2019.html). These videos,whichmake the content of the conferencemorewidely accessible, are a useful complement to this volume. This conference volume contains edited versions of the six papers presented at the conference, each followed by two written comments by leading scholars and a summary discussion of the debates that followed each paper. The volume also contains a paper, “Climate Change, Climate Policy, and Economic Growth,” by James Stock, based on his dinner talk. The paper provides an extremely useful introduction to the topic of climate change and climate change policy formacroeconomists. The paper makes four key points. First, simple time-series regression models confirm that essentially all the warming over the past 140 years is due to human activity. Second, policy has a crucial role toplay ifwe are to succeed in decarbonizing the economy. Third, current policies will not succeed in decarbonizing the economy in time to prevent severe damage from climate change. Fourth, the politics, as opposed to the economics, of Pigouvian carbon pricing do notwork. This suggests the importance of considering other policies, especially those that drive low-carbon technical innovation. There was no discussant for the paper because of its origin as a dinner talk. We are grateful to James Stock for taking the time to write up his comments on this vitally important topic.","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"34 1","pages":"xi - xviii"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2020-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/707168","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"43584113","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Comment 评论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2020-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/707174
R. Blundell
Individuals without a college degree in the United States have experienced a relative decline in labor market and other opportunities. This is especially the case for lower-educated white men who entered the labor market in the early 1980s and after. These trends are not exclusive to the United States; in theUnitedKingdom and elsewhere, thosewithout a college degree have fared poorly since the early 1980s. For the United States, the raw statistics point to one of the largest declines for developed economies. There has been a fall in (relative) real earnings for the low educated, especially white men. There appears to be almost no wage progression over the working life for low-educated men and women. There is strong assortativeness by wages in marriage such that the increasing labor market participation of women has not offset the growth in earnings inequality for couple households. In addition, medical costs have risen, especially in terms of social care, and perhaps most surprisingly, mortality has risen. Motivated by these trends, the authors specify a life-cycle model that includes marriage and divorce, human capital accumulation, medical expenditures, and changing life expectancy. They use data from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics and the Health and Retirement Survey to construct a sample of white, non-college-educated Americans. Sample moments are then used to estimate the model. Counterfactual simulations are then used to ask: What if the 1940s cohort of non-college-educated white Americans had experienced the wages, the medical expenses, and the mortality of the 1960s cohort? The “what if” is for labor market participation, hours, savings, and welfare. In this discussion, I first examine the trends in outcomes for these different groups over this period in the United States. I then briefly run
在美国,没有大学学位的人在劳动力市场和其他机会上经历了相对的下降。对于在20世纪80年代初及之后进入劳动力市场的受教育程度较低的白人男性来说,情况尤其如此。这些趋势并不是美国独有的;自20世纪80年代初以来,在英国和其他地方,没有大学学位的人的生活就很糟糕。对美国来说,原始统计数据显示,它是发达经济体中下降幅度最大的国家之一。受教育程度低的人,尤其是白人男性的(相对)实际收入有所下降。对于受教育程度较低的男性和女性来说,在整个职业生涯中,工资似乎几乎没有增长。婚姻中的工资具有很强的选择性,因此,女性劳动力市场参与度的增加并没有抵消夫妻家庭收入不平等的增长。此外,医疗费用上升,特别是在社会护理方面,也许最令人惊讶的是,死亡率上升了。在这些趋势的推动下,作者指定了一个生命周期模型,其中包括婚姻和离婚、人力资本积累、医疗支出和预期寿命的变化。他们使用收入动态小组研究和健康与退休调查的数据来构建一个没有受过大学教育的美国白人样本。然后使用样本矩来估计模型。然后用反事实模拟来问:如果20世纪40年代那批没有受过大学教育的美国白人经历了20世纪60年代那批人的工资、医疗费用和死亡率,情况会怎样?“如果”指的是劳动力市场参与度、工作时间、储蓄和福利。在这次讨论中,我首先考察了这一时期美国这些不同群体的结果趋势。然后我简短地跑一下
{"title":"Comment","authors":"R. Blundell","doi":"10.1086/707174","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/707174","url":null,"abstract":"Individuals without a college degree in the United States have experienced a relative decline in labor market and other opportunities. This is especially the case for lower-educated white men who entered the labor market in the early 1980s and after. These trends are not exclusive to the United States; in theUnitedKingdom and elsewhere, thosewithout a college degree have fared poorly since the early 1980s. For the United States, the raw statistics point to one of the largest declines for developed economies. There has been a fall in (relative) real earnings for the low educated, especially white men. There appears to be almost no wage progression over the working life for low-educated men and women. There is strong assortativeness by wages in marriage such that the increasing labor market participation of women has not offset the growth in earnings inequality for couple households. In addition, medical costs have risen, especially in terms of social care, and perhaps most surprisingly, mortality has risen. Motivated by these trends, the authors specify a life-cycle model that includes marriage and divorce, human capital accumulation, medical expenditures, and changing life expectancy. They use data from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics and the Health and Retirement Survey to construct a sample of white, non-college-educated Americans. Sample moments are then used to estimate the model. Counterfactual simulations are then used to ask: What if the 1940s cohort of non-college-educated white Americans had experienced the wages, the medical expenses, and the mortality of the 1960s cohort? The “what if” is for labor market participation, hours, savings, and welfare. In this discussion, I first examine the trends in outcomes for these different groups over this period in the United States. I then briefly run","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"34 1","pages":"116 - 126"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2020-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/707174","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"44169425","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Discussion 讨论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2020-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/718657
U. Strunz
This chapter discusses the empirical results, adds additional results, and compares derived insights to other scientific conclusions from the domain of behavioral economics. The first subchapter sums up understandings of agent behavior by the results of the various hypotheses, and includes further results from statistical analyses.
本章讨论了实证结果,增加了额外的结果,并将衍生的见解与行为经济学领域的其他科学结论进行了比较。第一章通过各种假设的结果总结了对代理人行为的理解,并包括统计分析的进一步结果。
{"title":"Discussion","authors":"U. Strunz","doi":"10.1086/718657","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/718657","url":null,"abstract":"This chapter discusses the empirical results, adds additional results, and compares derived insights to other scientific conclusions from the domain of behavioral economics. The first subchapter sums up understandings of agent behavior by the results of the various hypotheses, and includes further results from statistical analyses.","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"36 1","pages":"80 - 81"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2020-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"46610808","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Comment 评论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2020-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/707178
B. Bernanke
In 2008, for the first time since the Great Depression, the Federal Reserve encountered the zero lower bound (ZLB) on the nominal interest rate. The Fed’s target rate, the overnight federal funds rate, fell effectively to zero in the fall as the central bank’s emergency lending programs rapidly increased the supply of bank reserves. Then at its December 2008 meeting, the FederalOpenMarketCommittee (FOMC), the Fed’smonetary policymaking body, formally set the target range for the funds rate at 0 to 25 basis points—effectively zero. With the economy in free fall and little scope for additional rate cuts, the FOMC then turned to nonstandard policy tools, including forward guidance (communication about the likely or intended forward path of the policy rate) and large-scale asset purchases, also known as quantitative easing. Both tools were used actively during the Great Recession and the subsequent recovery. Did the nonstandard tools work? The current consensus of central bankers and economists is that forward guidance and asset purchases eased financial conditions and supported the economy, with fewer adverse side effects than many predicted. Accordingly, these policies appear to have become permanent components of the monetary tool kit, both in the United States and abroad. However, the prevailing view also holds that the overall response of monetary policy was effectively constrained by the ZLB; that is, although nonstandard policies evidentlymitigated the downturn, their use did not fully compensate for the inability of the Fed to cut short-term rates significantly further. This view, and the concern that in a world of low neutral interest rates future encounters with the ZLB may be frequent, has led the Fed and other central banks to actively consider new tools and new policy frameworks for dealing with the ZLB constraint. In contrast to this prevailing view, however, a small literature has adduced indirect evidence to argue that the Fed’s response to the Great
2008年,自大萧条以来,美联储首次遭遇名义利率零下限(ZLB)。美联储的目标利率,即隔夜联邦基金利率,在去年秋天实际上降至零,因为美联储的紧急贷款计划迅速增加了银行准备金的供应。然后在2008年12月的会议上,联邦公开市场委员会(FOMC),美联储的货币政策制定机构,正式将基金利率的目标范围设定在0到25个基点之间——实际上是零。随着经济自由落体,进一步降息的空间很小,联邦公开市场委员会随后转向非标准政策工具,包括前瞻性指导(关于政策利率可能或预期的未来路径的沟通)和大规模资产购买,也被称为量化宽松。在大衰退和随后的复苏期间,这两种工具都被积极使用。非标准工具工作吗?央行官员和经济学家目前的共识是,前瞻指引和资产购买措施缓解了金融状况,支持了经济,副作用比许多人预期的要少。因此,无论是在美国还是在其他国家,这些政策似乎都已成为货币工具的永久组成部分。然而,主流观点也认为,货币政策的总体反应受到ZLB的有效约束;也就是说,尽管非标准政策明显缓解了经济衰退,但它们的使用并不能完全弥补美联储无法进一步大幅削减短期利率的缺陷。这一观点,以及对在低中性利率世界中未来可能频繁遇到ZLB的担忧,导致美联储和其他央行积极考虑处理ZLB约束的新工具和新政策框架。然而,与这种普遍观点相反,一小部分文献引用了间接证据,认为美联储对大萧条的反应
{"title":"Comment","authors":"B. Bernanke","doi":"10.1086/707178","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/707178","url":null,"abstract":"In 2008, for the first time since the Great Depression, the Federal Reserve encountered the zero lower bound (ZLB) on the nominal interest rate. The Fed’s target rate, the overnight federal funds rate, fell effectively to zero in the fall as the central bank’s emergency lending programs rapidly increased the supply of bank reserves. Then at its December 2008 meeting, the FederalOpenMarketCommittee (FOMC), the Fed’smonetary policymaking body, formally set the target range for the funds rate at 0 to 25 basis points—effectively zero. With the economy in free fall and little scope for additional rate cuts, the FOMC then turned to nonstandard policy tools, including forward guidance (communication about the likely or intended forward path of the policy rate) and large-scale asset purchases, also known as quantitative easing. Both tools were used actively during the Great Recession and the subsequent recovery. Did the nonstandard tools work? The current consensus of central bankers and economists is that forward guidance and asset purchases eased financial conditions and supported the economy, with fewer adverse side effects than many predicted. Accordingly, these policies appear to have become permanent components of the monetary tool kit, both in the United States and abroad. However, the prevailing view also holds that the overall response of monetary policy was effectively constrained by the ZLB; that is, although nonstandard policies evidentlymitigated the downturn, their use did not fully compensate for the inability of the Fed to cut short-term rates significantly further. This view, and the concern that in a world of low neutral interest rates future encounters with the ZLB may be frequent, has led the Fed and other central banks to actively consider new tools and new policy frameworks for dealing with the ZLB constraint. In contrast to this prevailing view, however, a small literature has adduced indirect evidence to argue that the Fed’s response to the Great","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"34 1","pages":"171 - 181"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2020-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/707178","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"42971193","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Copyright 版权
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2020-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/709005
{"title":"Copyright","authors":"","doi":"10.1086/709005","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/709005","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"1 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2020-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/709005","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"43210704","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Comment 评论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2020-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/707183
M. Rognlie
Recently, I had a dream where I was trying to explain supply and demand to an audience of intransigent economists.How could I say that demand curves sloped downward, they asked, when for so many goods, a simple plot of quantity demanded against price showed the opposite? How could these curves be useful concepts when, even by the most generous account, their parameters shifted from year to year? I knew the answers. The incorrect slope of demand was no surprise; a plot of quantities against prices would reveal the demand curve only if the variation was caused by supply shocks. And yes, supply and demand didmove around from year to year, but this did not invalidate the concepts. If I am selling oil, I can predict that a sudden decline in supply (embargo) will increase the price, I can predict that a new source of supply (fracking) will decrease the price, and I can predict that a decline in demand (fuel efficiency) will decrease the price. All of this is useful information. The dream audience was unmoved. But upon waking up, I was relieved to find myself in a world where economists are not so silly. We understand that supply and demand is a useful framework, even if there is an identification problem and even if there is no consensus on the parameters for a particular market. In fact, we persist even in the face of more profound theoretical complications, like imperfect competition or increasing returns. Then I started reading commentary on the Phillips curve and economists started seeming awfully silly again. Somehow, a weak reducedform relationship in the aggregate data has led many people to deny the Phillips curve as a structural relationship. In the face of this criticism, McLeay and Tenreyro’s paper is a vitally important rejoinder.
最近,我做了一个梦,试图向一群顽固的经济学家解释供求关系。他们问道,当这么多商品的需求量与价格的简单关系图显示出相反的情况时,我怎么能说需求曲线向下倾斜呢?即使是最慷慨的解释,当这些曲线的参数逐年变化时,它们怎么会是有用的概念?我知道答案。需求的不正确斜率并不奇怪;只有当需求曲线的变化是由供应冲击引起时,数量与价格的关系图才能揭示需求曲线。是的,供应和需求确实逐年变化,但这并没有使这些概念失效。如果我在卖石油,我可以预测供应的突然下降(禁运)会使价格上涨,我可以预见新的供应来源(水力压裂)会使油价下跌,我可以预言需求的下降(燃油效率)会使物价下跌。所有这些都是有用的信息。梦中的观众不为所动。但醒来后,我发现自己身处一个经济学家并不那么愚蠢的世界,这让我松了一口气。我们知道,即使存在识别问题,即使对特定市场的参数没有达成共识,供需也是一个有用的框架。事实上,即使面对更深刻的理论复杂性,比如不完全竞争或不断增加的回报,我们也会坚持下去。然后我开始阅读关于菲利普斯曲线的评论,经济学家们又开始显得非常愚蠢。不知何故,聚合数据中的弱归约形式关系导致许多人否认菲利普斯曲线是一种结构关系。面对这种批评,McLeay和Tenreyro的论文是至关重要的反驳。
{"title":"Comment","authors":"M. Rognlie","doi":"10.1086/707183","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/707183","url":null,"abstract":"Recently, I had a dream where I was trying to explain supply and demand to an audience of intransigent economists.How could I say that demand curves sloped downward, they asked, when for so many goods, a simple plot of quantity demanded against price showed the opposite? How could these curves be useful concepts when, even by the most generous account, their parameters shifted from year to year? I knew the answers. The incorrect slope of demand was no surprise; a plot of quantities against prices would reveal the demand curve only if the variation was caused by supply shocks. And yes, supply and demand didmove around from year to year, but this did not invalidate the concepts. If I am selling oil, I can predict that a sudden decline in supply (embargo) will increase the price, I can predict that a new source of supply (fracking) will decrease the price, and I can predict that a decline in demand (fuel efficiency) will decrease the price. All of this is useful information. The dream audience was unmoved. But upon waking up, I was relieved to find myself in a world where economists are not so silly. We understand that supply and demand is a useful framework, even if there is an identification problem and even if there is no consensus on the parameters for a particular market. In fact, we persist even in the face of more profound theoretical complications, like imperfect competition or increasing returns. Then I started reading commentary on the Phillips curve and economists started seeming awfully silly again. Somehow, a weak reducedform relationship in the aggregate data has led many people to deny the Phillips curve as a structural relationship. In the face of this criticism, McLeay and Tenreyro’s paper is a vitally important rejoinder.","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"34 1","pages":"267 - 279"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2020-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/707183","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"46376775","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Comment 评论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2020-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/707190
M. Obstfeld
December 18, 2018,marked the fortieth anniversary of the Third Plenary Session of the Eleventh Central Committee of the Chinese Communist Party (CCP), at which Deng Xiaoping launched China on its remarkable recent trajectory of economic growth. By giving greater play over time to market forces, Deng’s reform and opening initiative spurred rapid income convergence. But it did so while preserving the CCP’s political monopoly. As figure 1 shows, China’s real gross domestic product (GDP) growth (insofar as the official data are accurate) has been high on average although anything but smooth. Moreover, it has declined markedly since the last year of double-digit growth in 2010 and even more so since the heady precrisis peak. China’s politics have not evolved monotonically either. The year 2019 marked the thirtieth anniversary of the Tiananmen protests, sparked by the (vain) hope that China’s economic evolution would encourage a commensurate political evolution. Chinese politics—and, I argue, economics— have only regressed under the more authoritarian rule of President Xiaoping Xi. In this paper, Chong-en Bai, Chang-Tai Hsieh, and Zheng Song likewise link China’s falling growth rate over the past decade to political factors, but I emphasize a set of factors different from the one that they highlight. What mechanism linking politics to growth do the authors emphasize? In his speech commemorating the fortieth anniversary of Deng’s reforms, President Xi stated that “we will resolutely reform what should and can be reformed, and make no change where there should not and cannot be any reform.” An alternative title for this paper could have been “Chinese Cronyism: Can It Be Changed? Should It Be Changed?” The authors’mainmessage is that cronyism is deeply ingrained inChina’smode
2018年12月18日是中国共产党第十一届中央委员会第三次全体会议四十周年,邓小平在会上推动了中国最近显著的经济增长轨迹。随着时间的推移,邓的改革开放举措进一步发挥了市场力量,促进了收入的快速趋同。但它这样做的同时保持了中共的政治垄断地位。如图1所示,中国的实际国内生产总值(GDP)增长(在官方数据准确的范围内)平均很高,尽管绝非平稳。此外,自2010年上一年两位数的增长以来,它已经显著下降,自令人兴奋的危机前高峰以来更是如此。中国的政治发展也并非单调乏味。2019年是天安门抗议活动30周年,人们(徒劳地)希望中国的经济发展会鼓励相应的政治发展。我认为,在Xi主席更加专制的统治下,中国的政治——以及经济——只会倒退。在这篇文章中,庄恩白、张泰谢和郑松同样将中国过去十年的增长率下降与政治因素联系起来,但我强调的是一系列不同于他们所强调的因素。作者强调了将政治与增长联系起来的机制是什么?Xi主席在纪念邓改革四十周年的讲话中说:“该改革的、能改革的坚决改革,不该改革的和不能改革的坚决不改。这篇论文的另一个标题可能是“中国的任人唯亲:它可以改变吗?它应该改变吗?”作者的主要信息是任人唯贤在中国的模式中根深蒂固
{"title":"Comment","authors":"M. Obstfeld","doi":"10.1086/707190","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/707190","url":null,"abstract":"December 18, 2018,marked the fortieth anniversary of the Third Plenary Session of the Eleventh Central Committee of the Chinese Communist Party (CCP), at which Deng Xiaoping launched China on its remarkable recent trajectory of economic growth. By giving greater play over time to market forces, Deng’s reform and opening initiative spurred rapid income convergence. But it did so while preserving the CCP’s political monopoly. As figure 1 shows, China’s real gross domestic product (GDP) growth (insofar as the official data are accurate) has been high on average although anything but smooth. Moreover, it has declined markedly since the last year of double-digit growth in 2010 and even more so since the heady precrisis peak. China’s politics have not evolved monotonically either. The year 2019 marked the thirtieth anniversary of the Tiananmen protests, sparked by the (vain) hope that China’s economic evolution would encourage a commensurate political evolution. Chinese politics—and, I argue, economics— have only regressed under the more authoritarian rule of President Xiaoping Xi. In this paper, Chong-en Bai, Chang-Tai Hsieh, and Zheng Song likewise link China’s falling growth rate over the past decade to political factors, but I emphasize a set of factors different from the one that they highlight. What mechanism linking politics to growth do the authors emphasize? In his speech commemorating the fortieth anniversary of Deng’s reforms, President Xi stated that “we will resolutely reform what should and can be reformed, and make no change where there should not and cannot be any reform.” An alternative title for this paper could have been “Chinese Cronyism: Can It Be Changed? Should It Be Changed?” The authors’mainmessage is that cronyism is deeply ingrained inChina’smode","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"34 1","pages":"380 - 388"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2020-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/707190","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"49009707","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Climate Change, Climate Policy, and Economic Growth 气候变化、气候政策和经济增长
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2020-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/707193
J. Stock
The topics of climate change and climate change policy encompass a complex mixture of the natural sciences, economics, and a mass of institutional, legal, and technical details. This complexity and multidisciplinary nature make it difficult for thoughtful citizens to reach their own conclusions on the topic and for potentially interested economists to know where to start. This essay aims to provide a point of entry formacroeconomists interested in climate change and climate change policy but with no special knowledge of the field. I therefore start at the beginning, with some basic background on climate change, presented through the eyes of an econometrician. I then turn to climate policy in the United States. That discussion points to a large number of researchable open questions that macroeconomists are particularly well suited to tackle. Let me summarize my four main points. First, although a healthy dose of skepticism is always in order (as academics it is in our DNA), simple and transparent time series regression models familiar to macroeconomists provide independent verification of some key conclusions from climate science models and in particular confirm that essentially all the warming over the past 140 years is because of human activity, that is, is anthropogenic. Figure 1 shows time series data on annual global mean temperature since 1860, when reliable instrumental records start. As seen in the figure, the global mean temperature has increased by approximately 1 degree Celsius, compared with its 1870–90 average value. This increase in temperatures drives a wide range of changes in climate, including droughts, more hot days, and more intense rainfalls and storms, all of which vary regionally. Because climate science uses large, opaque calibrated models of the climate system, there is room for confusion among legitimately skeptical outsiders about just howmuch of the global warming observed since the industrial revolution results from human
气候变化和气候变化政策的主题包含了自然科学、经济学和大量制度、法律和技术细节的复杂混合。这种复杂性和多学科性质使得有思想的公民很难在这个话题上得出自己的结论,而潜在感兴趣的经济学家也不知道从哪里开始。本文旨在为对气候变化和气候变化政策感兴趣但对该领域没有专门知识的宏观经济学家提供一个切入点。因此,我将以计量经济学家的视角,从气候变化的一些基本背景入手。然后我转向美国的气候政策。这种讨论指出了大量可研究的开放性问题,宏观经济学家特别适合解决这些问题。让我总结一下我的四个主要观点。首先,尽管保持一定程度的怀疑是必要的(就像学术界对我们的DNA一样),宏观经济学家熟悉的简单透明的时间序列回归模型为气候科学模型的一些关键结论提供了独立的验证,特别是确认了过去140年里所有的变暖基本上都是由人类活动造成的,也就是说,是人为的。图1显示了自1860年开始有可靠仪器记录以来全球年平均气温的时间序列数据。如图所示,与1870 - 1990年的平均值相比,全球平均温度上升了约1摄氏度。气温的升高导致了广泛的气候变化,包括干旱、更热的天气以及更强的降雨和风暴,所有这些都因地区而异。由于气候科学使用的是大型、不透明的气候系统校准模型,因此,对于工业革命以来观测到的全球变暖有多少是人类活动造成的,持合理怀疑态度的局外人有可能产生困惑
{"title":"Climate Change, Climate Policy, and Economic Growth","authors":"J. Stock","doi":"10.1086/707193","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/707193","url":null,"abstract":"The topics of climate change and climate change policy encompass a complex mixture of the natural sciences, economics, and a mass of institutional, legal, and technical details. This complexity and multidisciplinary nature make it difficult for thoughtful citizens to reach their own conclusions on the topic and for potentially interested economists to know where to start. This essay aims to provide a point of entry formacroeconomists interested in climate change and climate change policy but with no special knowledge of the field. I therefore start at the beginning, with some basic background on climate change, presented through the eyes of an econometrician. I then turn to climate policy in the United States. That discussion points to a large number of researchable open questions that macroeconomists are particularly well suited to tackle. Let me summarize my four main points. First, although a healthy dose of skepticism is always in order (as academics it is in our DNA), simple and transparent time series regression models familiar to macroeconomists provide independent verification of some key conclusions from climate science models and in particular confirm that essentially all the warming over the past 140 years is because of human activity, that is, is anthropogenic. Figure 1 shows time series data on annual global mean temperature since 1860, when reliable instrumental records start. As seen in the figure, the global mean temperature has increased by approximately 1 degree Celsius, compared with its 1870–90 average value. This increase in temperatures drives a wide range of changes in climate, including droughts, more hot days, and more intense rainfalls and storms, all of which vary regionally. Because climate science uses large, opaque calibrated models of the climate system, there is room for confusion among legitimately skeptical outsiders about just howmuch of the global warming observed since the industrial revolution results from human","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"34 1","pages":"399 - 419"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2020-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/707193","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"45137359","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 17
Discussion 讨论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2020-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/707176
DaronAcemoglu contextualized the authors’ paper as part of an ongoing debate about the origins of intercohort trends in labor market outcomes. He argued that differences across education groups have been studied extensively,whereas differences across cohorts are less understood.He contrasted two views on the subject. According to the first one, which he labeled the “early labor view,” intercohort trends stem from differences in protections and unionization across cohorts. The second view, which Acemoglu labeled the “Card-Lemieux (2001) view” (David Card and Thomas Lemieux [“Can Falling Supply Explain the Rising Return to College for Younger Men? A Cohort-Based Analysis,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 116, no. 2 (2001): 705–46]), imputes these trends to differences in educational attainments across cohorts. Acemoglu downplayed the importance of the first view. He suggested instead that a decrease in the relative supply of educated workers across cohorts is the most plausible explanation for the rise in the skill premium observed in the data. He noted that college graduation rates rose steadily for cohorts born before 1950, but educational attainments stagnated or even declined afterward. Acemoglu argued that the literature still does not have a good understanding of the source of this structural break. The authors agreed that the decline in educational achievements across cohorts is striking, especially because the skill premium rose over the relevant period. They would not speculate about the reasons underlying this trend but suggested that skill-biased technical changes might also have played a role for the rising skill premium. Valerie Ramey followedupon the subject andoffered a tentative explanation for the decline in educational achievements across cohorts. She highlighted the role of expectations for investment in human capital. She noted that the 1960s cohort (studied in the paper) turned 18 in the late 1970s, when the college premiumwas low and strong unions guaranteed
DaronAcemoglu将作者的论文作为正在进行的关于劳动力市场结果的队列间趋势起源的辩论的一部分。他认为,不同教育群体之间的差异已经得到了广泛的研究,而不同群体之间的差异却鲜为人知。他对比了对这个问题的两种看法。根据第一种观点(他称之为“早期劳工观”),群体间的趋势源于群体间在保护和工会化方面的差异。第二种观点,阿西莫格鲁称之为“卡-勒米厄(2001)观点”(大卫·卡德和托马斯·勒米厄在《供给下降能否解释年轻男性返校率上升?》《基于群体的分析》,《经济学季刊》第116期。[2](2001): 705-46]),将这些趋势归咎于不同群体的受教育程度差异。阿西莫格鲁淡化了第一种观点的重要性。相反,他认为,对于数据中观察到的技能溢价上升,最合理的解释是,在各个群体中,受过教育的工人的相对供应减少。他指出,1950年以前出生的人的大学毕业率稳步上升,但之后的受教育程度停滞不前,甚至有所下降。阿西莫格鲁认为,文献仍然没有很好地理解这种结构断裂的来源。研究报告的作者们一致认为,在同一群体中,教育成就的下降是惊人的,尤其是因为技能优势在相关时期有所上升。他们不愿推测这一趋势背后的原因,但表示偏向于技能的技术变革可能也对技能溢价的上升起了作用。瓦莱丽·雷米(Valerie Ramey)继续研究了这个问题,并对不同年龄段的人在教育成就上的下降给出了一个尝试性的解释。她强调了对人力资本投资的预期的作用。她指出,上世纪60年代出生的人(在论文中被研究过)在上世纪70年代末年满18岁,当时大学学费很低,工会也很强大
{"title":"Discussion","authors":"","doi":"10.1086/707176","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/707176","url":null,"abstract":"DaronAcemoglu contextualized the authors’ paper as part of an ongoing debate about the origins of intercohort trends in labor market outcomes. He argued that differences across education groups have been studied extensively,whereas differences across cohorts are less understood.He contrasted two views on the subject. According to the first one, which he labeled the “early labor view,” intercohort trends stem from differences in protections and unionization across cohorts. The second view, which Acemoglu labeled the “Card-Lemieux (2001) view” (David Card and Thomas Lemieux [“Can Falling Supply Explain the Rising Return to College for Younger Men? A Cohort-Based Analysis,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 116, no. 2 (2001): 705–46]), imputes these trends to differences in educational attainments across cohorts. Acemoglu downplayed the importance of the first view. He suggested instead that a decrease in the relative supply of educated workers across cohorts is the most plausible explanation for the rise in the skill premium observed in the data. He noted that college graduation rates rose steadily for cohorts born before 1950, but educational attainments stagnated or even declined afterward. Acemoglu argued that the literature still does not have a good understanding of the source of this structural break. The authors agreed that the decline in educational achievements across cohorts is striking, especially because the skill premium rose over the relevant period. They would not speculate about the reasons underlying this trend but suggested that skill-biased technical changes might also have played a role for the rising skill premium. Valerie Ramey followedupon the subject andoffered a tentative explanation for the decline in educational achievements across cohorts. She highlighted the role of expectations for investment in human capital. She noted that the 1960s cohort (studied in the paper) turned 18 in the late 1970s, when the college premiumwas low and strong unions guaranteed","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"34 1","pages":"137 - 139"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2020-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/707176","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"42395876","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Nber Macroeconomics Annual
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1