首页 > 最新文献

Nber Macroeconomics Annual最新文献

英文 中文
Discussion 讨论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/718663
Steven A. Solomon
Steven Davis opened the discussion by questioning whether mancessions or shecessions are more socially harmful. He listed some reasons why mancessionsmaybemore harmful, including thatwomen aremore likely to be secondary earners, women have better alternative uses of time (i.e., will spend less nonwork time pursuing sleep or leisure activities), there is a larger psychic cost of male joblessness, andmale joblessness is more associated with increased crime, drug/alcohol use, and physical abuse of spouses/children. The authors responded by saying they are not making a statement on which is worse, but rather they argued that the responses of men and women to job loss are distinct, and this has macroeconomic implications. For example, differences in labor supply flexibility can have aggregate impacts. If a secondary earner (which on average ismore likely to be a woman) loses their job, the primary earner (on average the man) has nomargin for adjustment because they are alreadyworking full-time. In contrast, if a primary earner loses their job, the secondary earner has a margin to adjust and work more. Martin Eichenbaum then followed up this discussion, to ask whether the difference between male and female sensitivity should be interpreted as a market failure, and whether this pattern says anything about efficiency. The authors responded that they do not think this points to any fundamental inefficiency, but the interaction of joint labor supply with policy can certainly create some. For instance, how taxation, unemployment benefits, and retirement entitlements treat secondary versus primary earners could interact with joint labor supply decisions in a way that creates inefficiency.
史蒂文·戴维斯(Steven Davis)在讨论一开始就提出了这样一个问题:“宅邸”还是“宅邸”对社会的危害更大?他列举了一些为什么失业更有害的原因,包括女性更有可能成为第二收入者,女性有更好的时间选择(即,将花费更少的非工作时间用于睡眠或休闲活动),男性失业的心理成本更大,男性失业与犯罪增加、吸毒/酗酒以及对配偶/孩子的身体虐待更多相关。作者回应说,他们并不是在说明哪个更糟糕,而是认为男性和女性对失业的反应是不同的,这具有宏观经济意义。例如,劳动力供给灵活性的差异会产生总体影响。如果第二经济来源(一般来说更可能是女性)失去了工作,那么主要经济来源(一般来说是男性)就没有调整的余地,因为他们已经有了全职工作。相反,如果一个初级收入者失去了工作,第二个收入者有调整和更多工作的余地。Martin Eichenbaum接着进行了讨论,询问男性和女性敏感度之间的差异是否应该被解释为市场失灵,以及这种模式是否说明了效率。作者回答说,他们不认为这表明任何根本的低效率,但联合劳动力供给与政策的相互作用肯定会产生一些低效率。例如,税收、失业救济和退休津贴如何对待第二收入者和主要收入者,可能会以一种造成效率低下的方式与联合劳动力供给决策相互作用。
{"title":"Discussion","authors":"Steven A. Solomon","doi":"10.1086/718663","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/718663","url":null,"abstract":"Steven Davis opened the discussion by questioning whether mancessions or shecessions are more socially harmful. He listed some reasons why mancessionsmaybemore harmful, including thatwomen aremore likely to be secondary earners, women have better alternative uses of time (i.e., will spend less nonwork time pursuing sleep or leisure activities), there is a larger psychic cost of male joblessness, andmale joblessness is more associated with increased crime, drug/alcohol use, and physical abuse of spouses/children. The authors responded by saying they are not making a statement on which is worse, but rather they argued that the responses of men and women to job loss are distinct, and this has macroeconomic implications. For example, differences in labor supply flexibility can have aggregate impacts. If a secondary earner (which on average ismore likely to be a woman) loses their job, the primary earner (on average the man) has nomargin for adjustment because they are alreadyworking full-time. In contrast, if a primary earner loses their job, the secondary earner has a margin to adjust and work more. Martin Eichenbaum then followed up this discussion, to ask whether the difference between male and female sensitivity should be interpreted as a market failure, and whether this pattern says anything about efficiency. The authors responded that they do not think this points to any fundamental inefficiency, but the interaction of joint labor supply with policy can certainly create some. For instance, how taxation, unemployment benefits, and retirement entitlements treat secondary versus primary earners could interact with joint labor supply decisions in a way that creates inefficiency.","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"36 1","pages":"173 - 175"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2022-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"44351536","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Editorial 社论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/718586
Martin Eichenbaum, Erik Hurst
The NBER’s 36th Annual Conference on Macroeconomics brought together leading scholars to present, discuss, and debate five research papers on central issues in contemporary macroeconomics. In addition, we included a panel discussion on the cost associated with expanding the size of government debt. Raghu Rajan moderated the panel, which included CarmenReinhart, RichardReis, andLarry Summers. Given the pandemic, the conference took place via Zoom. Video recordings of the presentations of the papers and the panel discussion are accessible on the web page of the NBER Annual Conference on Macroeconomics. These videos make a useful complement to this volume andmake the conference’s content more widely accessible. This conference volume contains edited versions of the five papers presented at the conference, each followed by two written discussions by leading scholars and a summary of the debates that followed each paper. How the labor market evolves during a recession and its subsequent recovery is a key question inmacroeconomics. During a recession,many workers are displaced from their employers. Over time, these workers are absorbed back into the labor force. So at the onset of a recession, the unemployment rate rises sharply, whereas the unemployment rate falls slowly during the recovery. In their paper “Why Has the US Economy Recovered So Consistently from Every Recession in the Past 70 Years?” Robert Hall and Marianna Kudlyak explore the underpinnings of unemployment dynamics across recessions. Hall and Kudlyak start their paper by documenting a set of
NBER第36届宏观经济学年会汇集了顶尖学者,就当代宏观经济学的核心问题发表了五篇研究论文,进行了讨论和辩论。此外,我们还就扩大政府债务规模的相关成本进行了小组讨论。拉古·拉詹主持了包括卡门林哈特、里查德·赖斯和拉里·萨默斯在内的小组讨论。鉴于疫情,会议通过Zoom举行。论文介绍和小组讨论的录像可在国家经济研究所宏观经济年会的网页上查阅。这些视频是对本卷的有益补充,使会议内容更容易获得。本会议卷包含了在会议上发表的五篇论文的编辑版本,每篇论文都有两篇由知名学者撰写的书面讨论,以及每篇论文之后的辩论摘要。劳动力市场在经济衰退期间如何演变及其随后的复苏是宏观经济学中的一个关键问题。在经济衰退期间,许多工人被雇主解雇。随着时间的推移,这些工人被重新吸收到劳动力队伍中。因此,在经济衰退开始时,失业率急剧上升,而在复苏期间,失业率下降缓慢。Robert Hall和Marianna Kudlyak在他们的论文《为什么美国经济在过去70年的每一次衰退中都如此稳定地复苏?》中探讨了衰退中失业动态的基础。Hall和Kudlyak通过记录一组
{"title":"Editorial","authors":"Martin Eichenbaum, Erik Hurst","doi":"10.1086/718586","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/718586","url":null,"abstract":"The NBER’s 36th Annual Conference on Macroeconomics brought together leading scholars to present, discuss, and debate five research papers on central issues in contemporary macroeconomics. In addition, we included a panel discussion on the cost associated with expanding the size of government debt. Raghu Rajan moderated the panel, which included CarmenReinhart, RichardReis, andLarry Summers. Given the pandemic, the conference took place via Zoom. Video recordings of the presentations of the papers and the panel discussion are accessible on the web page of the NBER Annual Conference on Macroeconomics. These videos make a useful complement to this volume andmake the conference’s content more widely accessible. This conference volume contains edited versions of the five papers presented at the conference, each followed by two written discussions by leading scholars and a summary of the debates that followed each paper. How the labor market evolves during a recession and its subsequent recovery is a key question inmacroeconomics. During a recession,many workers are displaced from their employers. Over time, these workers are absorbed back into the labor force. So at the onset of a recession, the unemployment rate rises sharply, whereas the unemployment rate falls slowly during the recovery. In their paper “Why Has the US Economy Recovered So Consistently from Every Recession in the Past 70 Years?” Robert Hall and Marianna Kudlyak explore the underpinnings of unemployment dynamics across recessions. Hall and Kudlyak start their paper by documenting a set of","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"36 1","pages":"xi - xvii"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2022-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"46577509","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Comment 评论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/718656
Ayşegül Şahi̇n
Hall and Kudlyak start with the observation that in the typical US business cycle recovery, unemployment declines slowly but reliably from a high point at the end of a business cycle contraction. They show that the direct effect of job loss at the onset of the recession cannot account for the persistently high unemployment rate during the recovery. The recession’s effects on the labor market go beyond the job losses that mark the beginning of recessions.Hall andKudlyak then exploremodelswhere there is feedback from high unemployment to the forces driving job creation. These mechanisms include higher recruiting costs early in the recovery, congestion in recruitment, externalities from recruitment selection, lower matching efficiency, impaired profitability of new matches, and persistently higher separation rates. These models imply that the recovery of aggregate unemployment is slower than the rate at which individual unemployed workers find new jobs. The paper tackles an interesting and eternal topic. Understanding how the labormarket recovers from recessionary shocks and howfirms recruit and search for workers helps us in shaping policy response to recessionary shocks. This comment reviews and interprets Hall and Kudlyak’s findings and suggests new directions of research.
Hall和Kudlyak首先观察到,在典型的美国商业周期复苏中,失业率从商业周期收缩结束时的高点缓慢但可靠地下降。他们表明,经济衰退开始时失业的直接影响无法解释经济复苏期间失业率居高不下的原因。经济衰退对劳动力市场的影响不仅仅是标志着经济衰退开始的失业。Hall和Kudlyak随后探讨了高失业率对创造就业的力量的反馈。这些机制包括复苏初期招聘成本较高、招聘拥堵、招聘选择的外部性、匹配效率较低、新匹配的盈利能力受损以及离职率持续较高。这些模型表明,总失业率的恢复速度慢于个别失业工人找到新工作的速度。这篇论文涉及一个有趣而又永恒的话题。了解劳动力市场如何从衰退冲击中复苏,以及企业如何招聘和寻找工人,有助于我们制定应对衰退冲击的政策。这篇评论回顾并解释了Hall和Kudlyak的发现,并提出了新的研究方向。
{"title":"Comment","authors":"Ayşegül Şahi̇n","doi":"10.1086/718656","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/718656","url":null,"abstract":"Hall and Kudlyak start with the observation that in the typical US business cycle recovery, unemployment declines slowly but reliably from a high point at the end of a business cycle contraction. They show that the direct effect of job loss at the onset of the recession cannot account for the persistently high unemployment rate during the recovery. The recession’s effects on the labor market go beyond the job losses that mark the beginning of recessions.Hall andKudlyak then exploremodelswhere there is feedback from high unemployment to the forces driving job creation. These mechanisms include higher recruiting costs early in the recovery, congestion in recruitment, externalities from recruitment selection, lower matching efficiency, impaired profitability of new matches, and persistently higher separation rates. These models imply that the recovery of aggregate unemployment is slower than the rate at which individual unemployed workers find new jobs. The paper tackles an interesting and eternal topic. Understanding how the labormarket recovers from recessionary shocks and howfirms recruit and search for workers helps us in shaping policy response to recessionary shocks. This comment reviews and interprets Hall and Kudlyak’s findings and suggests new directions of research.","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"36 1","pages":"68 - 79"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2022-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"49051007","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Comment 评论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/718674
D. Acemoglu, Carlos Molina
The contribution by Kremer, Willis, and You revisit cross-country convergence patterns over the past 6 decades. They provide evidence that the lack of convergence that applied early in the sample has now been replaced by modest convergence. They also argue this relationship is driven by convergence in various determinants of economic growth across countries and a flattening of the relationship between these determinants and growth. Although the patterns documented by the authors are intriguing, our reanalysis finds that these results are driven by the lack of country fixed effects controlling for unobserved determinants of gross domestic product per capita across countries. We show theoretically and empirically that failure to include country fixed effects will create a bias in convergence coefficients toward zero and this bias can be time varying, even when the underlying country-level parameters are stable. These results are relevant not just for the current paper but also for the convergence literature more generally. Our reanalysis finds no evidence of major changes in patterns of convergence and, more importantly, no flattening of the relationship between institutional variables and economic growth. Focusing on democracy, we show that this variable’s impact continues to be precisely estimated and if anything a little larger than at the beginning of the sample.
克雷默、威利斯和你的贡献回顾了过去60年的跨国趋同模式。他们提供的证据表明,在样本早期应用的缺乏收敛性现在已经被适度收敛所取代。他们还认为,这种关系是由各国经济增长的各种决定因素趋同以及这些决定因素与增长之间的关系趋于平缓所驱动的。尽管作者记录的模式很有趣,但我们的重新分析发现,这些结果是由于缺乏控制各国人均国内生产总值未观察到的决定因素的国家固定效应所驱动的。我们从理论上和经验上表明,不包括国家固定效应将导致收敛系数趋于零的偏差,并且这种偏差可能随时间变化,即使在潜在的国家层面参数稳定时也是如此。这些结果不仅与当前的论文有关,而且与更普遍的收敛文献有关。我们的重新分析没有发现趋同模式发生重大变化的证据,更重要的是,制度变量与经济增长之间的关系没有趋于平缓。以民主为重点,我们表明,这个变量的影响继续被精确地估计,如果有的话,比样本开始时更大一点。
{"title":"Comment","authors":"D. Acemoglu, Carlos Molina","doi":"10.1086/718674","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/718674","url":null,"abstract":"The contribution by Kremer, Willis, and You revisit cross-country convergence patterns over the past 6 decades. They provide evidence that the lack of convergence that applied early in the sample has now been replaced by modest convergence. They also argue this relationship is driven by convergence in various determinants of economic growth across countries and a flattening of the relationship between these determinants and growth. Although the patterns documented by the authors are intriguing, our reanalysis finds that these results are driven by the lack of country fixed effects controlling for unobserved determinants of gross domestic product per capita across countries. We show theoretically and empirically that failure to include country fixed effects will create a bias in convergence coefficients toward zero and this bias can be time varying, even when the underlying country-level parameters are stable. These results are relevant not just for the current paper but also for the convergence literature more generally. Our reanalysis finds no evidence of major changes in patterns of convergence and, more importantly, no flattening of the relationship between institutional variables and economic growth. Focusing on democracy, we show that this variable’s impact continues to be precisely estimated and if anything a little larger than at the beginning of the sample.","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"36 1","pages":"425 - 442"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2022-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"47104565","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Converging to Convergence 收敛到收敛
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2021-11-01 DOI: 10.1086/718672
M. Kremer, Jack Willis, Yang You
Empirical tests in the 1990s found little evidence of poor countries catching up with rich unconditional convergence - since the 1960s, and divergence over longer periods. This stylized fact spurred several developments in growth theory, including AK models, poverty trap models, and the concept of convergence conditional on determinants of steady-state income. We revisit these findings, using the subsequent 25 years as an out-of-sample test, and document a trend towards unconditional convergence since 1990 and convergence since 2000, driven by both faster catch-up growth and slower growth of the frontier. During the same period, many of the correlates of growth - human capital, policies, institutions, and culture - also converged substantially and moved in the direction associated with higher income. Were these changes related? Using the omitted variable bias formula, we decompose the gap between unconditional and conditional convergence as the product of two cross-sectional slopes. First, correlate-income slopes, which remained largely stable since 1990. Second, growth-correlate slopes controlling for income - the coefficients of growth regressions - which remained stable for fundamentals of the Solow model (investment rate, population growth, and human capital) but which flattened substantially for other correlates, leading unconditional convergence to converge towards conditional convergence.
20世纪90年代的经验测试发现,几乎没有证据表明,自20世纪60年代以来,贫穷国家赶上了富裕国家的无条件趋同和长期分化。这一程式化的事实刺激了增长理论的几项发展,包括AK模型、贫困陷阱模型和以稳定收入决定因素为条件的趋同概念。我们使用随后的25年作为样本外测试,重新审视了这些发现,并记录了自1990年以来无条件趋同和自2000年以来趋同的趋势,这是由更快的追赶增长和更慢的前沿增长驱动的。在同一时期,许多与增长相关的因素——人力资本、政策、制度和文化——也大幅趋同,并朝着与更高收入相关的方向发展。这些变化是否相关?使用省略的变量偏差公式,我们将无条件收敛和条件收敛之间的差距分解为两个横截面斜率的乘积。首先,相关收入斜率,自1990年以来基本保持稳定。其次,控制收入的增长相关斜率(增长回归系数)在索洛模型的基本面(投资率、人口增长和人力资本)中保持稳定,但在其他相关方面基本持平,导致无条件收敛向条件收敛。
{"title":"Converging to Convergence","authors":"M. Kremer, Jack Willis, Yang You","doi":"10.1086/718672","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/718672","url":null,"abstract":"Empirical tests in the 1990s found little evidence of poor countries catching up with rich unconditional convergence - since the 1960s, and divergence over longer periods. This stylized fact spurred several developments in growth theory, including AK models, poverty trap models, and the concept of convergence conditional on determinants of steady-state income. We revisit these findings, using the subsequent 25 years as an out-of-sample test, and document a trend towards unconditional convergence since 1990 and convergence since 2000, driven by both faster catch-up growth and slower growth of the frontier. During the same period, many of the correlates of growth - human capital, policies, institutions, and culture - also converged substantially and moved in the direction associated with higher income. Were these changes related? Using the omitted variable bias formula, we decompose the gap between unconditional and conditional convergence as the product of two cross-sectional slopes. First, correlate-income slopes, which remained largely stable since 1990. Second, growth-correlate slopes controlling for income - the coefficients of growth regressions - which remained stable for fundamentals of the Solow model (investment rate, population growth, and human capital) but which flattened substantially for other correlates, leading unconditional convergence to converge towards conditional convergence.","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"36 1","pages":"337 - 412"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2021-11-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"48192759","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 8
Climate Change Uncertainty Spillover in the Macroeconomy 气候变化不确定性对宏观经济的影响
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2021-07-01 DOI: 10.1086/718668
Michael B. Barnett, W. Brock, L. Hansen
The design and conduct of climate change policy necessarily confronts uncertainty along multiple fronts. We explore the consequences of ambiguity over various sources and configurations of models that impact how economic opportunities could be damaged in the future. We appeal to decision theory under risk, model ambiguity and misspecification concerns to provide an economically motivated approach to uncertainty quantification. We show how this approach reduces the many facets of uncertainty into a low dimensional characterization that depends on the uncertainty aversion of a decision-maker or fictitious social planner. In our computations, we take inventory of three alternative channels of uncertainty and provide a novel way to assess them. These include i) carbon dynamics that capture how carbon emissions impact atmospheric carbon in future time periods; ii) temperature dynamics that depict how atmospheric carbon alters temperature in future time periods; iii) damage functions that quantify how temperature changes diminish economic opportunities. We appeal to geoscientific modeling to quantify the first two channels. We show how these uncertainty sources interact for a social planner looking to design a prudent approach to the social pricing of carbon emissions.
气候变化政策的设计和实施必然面临多方面的不确定性。我们探讨了影响未来经济机会如何受损的各种来源和模型配置的模糊性的后果。我们呼吁决策理论在风险,模型模糊和错误规范的关注,提供一个经济动机的方法来不确定性量化。我们展示了这种方法如何将不确定性的许多方面减少到一个低维度的特征,这取决于决策者或虚构的社会规划者对不确定性的厌恶。在我们的计算中,我们盘点了三种可选的不确定性渠道,并提供了一种评估它们的新方法。这些包括i)碳动力学,捕捉碳排放如何影响未来时间段的大气碳;Ii)描述未来时期大气碳如何改变温度的温度动力学;Iii)量化温度变化如何减少经济机会的损害函数。我们呼吁地球科学建模来量化前两个渠道。我们展示了这些不确定性来源如何相互作用,为社会规划者寻求设计一个谨慎的碳排放社会定价方法。
{"title":"Climate Change Uncertainty Spillover in the Macroeconomy","authors":"Michael B. Barnett, W. Brock, L. Hansen","doi":"10.1086/718668","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/718668","url":null,"abstract":"The design and conduct of climate change policy necessarily confronts uncertainty along multiple fronts. We explore the consequences of ambiguity over various sources and configurations of models that impact how economic opportunities could be damaged in the future. We appeal to decision theory under risk, model ambiguity and misspecification concerns to provide an economically motivated approach to uncertainty quantification. We show how this approach reduces the many facets of uncertainty into a low dimensional characterization that depends on the uncertainty aversion of a decision-maker or fictitious social planner. In our computations, we take inventory of three alternative channels of uncertainty and provide a novel way to assess them. These include i) carbon dynamics that capture how carbon emissions impact atmospheric carbon in future time periods; ii) temperature dynamics that depict how atmospheric carbon alters temperature in future time periods; iii) damage functions that quantify how temperature changes diminish economic opportunities. We appeal to geoscientific modeling to quantify the first two channels. We show how these uncertainty sources interact for a social planner looking to design a prudent approach to the social pricing of carbon emissions.","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"36 1","pages":"253 - 320"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2021-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"46249709","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 23
Shocks, Institutions, and Secular Changes in Employment of Older Individuals 老年人就业的冲击、制度和世俗变化
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2021-06-01 DOI: 10.1086/718664
Richard Rogerson, Johanna Wallenius
Employment rates of males aged 55-64 have changed dramatically in the OECD over the last 5 decades. The average employment rate decreased by more than 15 percentage points between the mid-1970s and the mid-1990s, only to increase by roughly the same amount subsequently. One proposed explanation in the literature is that spousal non-working times are complements and that older males are working longer as a result of secular increases in labor supply of older females. In the first part of this paper we present evidence against this explanation. We then offer a new narrative to understand the employment rate changes for older individuals. We argue that the dramatic U-shaped pattern for older male employment rates should be understood as reflecting a mean reverting low frequency shock to labor market opportunities for all workers in combination with temporary country specific policy responses that incentivized older individuals to withdraw from market work.
在过去的50年里,经合组织国家中55-64岁男性的就业率发生了巨大的变化。从上世纪70年代中期到90年代中期,平均就业率下降了15个百分点以上,但随后又以大致相同的幅度上升。文献中提出的一种解释是,配偶的非工作时间是一种补充,老年男性的工作时间更长是老年女性劳动力供应长期增加的结果。在本文的第一部分,我们提出了反对这种解释的证据。然后,我们提供了一种新的叙事来理解老年人的就业率变化。我们认为,老年男性就业率的戏剧性u型模式应被理解为反映了对所有工人的劳动力市场机会的平均恢复低频率冲击,以及激励老年人退出市场工作的临时国家具体政策反应。
{"title":"Shocks, Institutions, and Secular Changes in Employment of Older Individuals","authors":"Richard Rogerson, Johanna Wallenius","doi":"10.1086/718664","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/718664","url":null,"abstract":"Employment rates of males aged 55-64 have changed dramatically in the OECD over the last 5 decades. The average employment rate decreased by more than 15 percentage points between the mid-1970s and the mid-1990s, only to increase by roughly the same amount subsequently. One proposed explanation in the literature is that spousal non-working times are complements and that older males are working longer as a result of secular increases in labor supply of older females. In the first part of this paper we present evidence against this explanation. We then offer a new narrative to understand the employment rate changes for older individuals. We argue that the dramatic U-shaped pattern for older male employment rates should be understood as reflecting a mean reverting low frequency shock to labor market opportunities for all workers in combination with temporary country specific policy responses that incentivized older individuals to withdraw from market work.","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"36 1","pages":"177 - 216"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2021-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"48622958","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
From Mancession to Shecession: Women’s Employment in Regular and Pandemic Recessions 从男性衰退到女性衰退:定期衰退和大范围衰退中的妇女就业
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2021-04-01 DOI: 10.1086/718660
T. Alon, Sena Coskun, Matthias Doepke, David Koll, M. Tertilt
We examine the impact of the global recession triggered by the Covid-19 pandemic on women's versus men's employment. Whereas recent recessions in advanced economies usually had a disproportionate impact on men's employment, giving rise to the moniker "mancessions," we show that the pandemic recession of 2020 was a "shecession" in most countries with larger employment declines among women. We examine the causes behind this pattern using micro data from several national labor force surveys, and show that both the composition of women's employment across industries and occupations as well as increased childcare needs during closures of schools and daycare centers made important contributions. While many countries exhibit similar patterns, we also emphasize how policy choices such as furloughing policies and the extent of school closures shape the pandemic's impact on the labor market. Another notable finding is the central role of telecommuting: gender gaps in the employment impact of the pandemic arise almost entirely among workers who are unable to work from home. Nevertheless, among telecommuters a different kind of gender gap arises: women working from home during the pandemic spent more work time also doing childcare and experienced greater productivity reductions than men. We discuss what our findings imply for gender equality in a post-pandemic labor market that will likely continue to be characterized by pervasive telecommuting.
我们研究了新冠肺炎疫情引发的全球经济衰退对女性和男性就业的影响。尽管发达经济体最近的衰退通常对男性就业产生了不成比例的影响,从而产生了“男性衰退”的绰号,但我们表明,2020年的疫情衰退在大多数女性就业下降幅度较大的国家都是“衰退”。我们使用几项全国劳动力调查的微观数据研究了这种模式背后的原因,并表明,不同行业和职业的女性就业构成,以及学校和日托中心关闭期间儿童保育需求的增加,都做出了重要贡献。虽然许多国家都表现出类似的模式,但我们也强调休假政策和学校关闭程度等政策选择如何影响疫情对劳动力市场的影响。另一个值得注意的发现是远程办公的核心作用:在疫情的就业影响中,性别差距几乎完全出现在无法在家工作的工人中。然而,在远程办公者中,出现了一种不同的性别差距:在疫情期间,在家工作的女性比男性花更多的工作时间照顾孩子,生产力下降幅度更大。我们讨论了我们的发现对疫情后劳动力市场的性别平等意味着什么,这个市场可能会继续以普遍的远程办公为特征。
{"title":"From Mancession to Shecession: Women’s Employment in Regular and Pandemic Recessions","authors":"T. Alon, Sena Coskun, Matthias Doepke, David Koll, M. Tertilt","doi":"10.1086/718660","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/718660","url":null,"abstract":"We examine the impact of the global recession triggered by the Covid-19 pandemic on women's versus men's employment. Whereas recent recessions in advanced economies usually had a disproportionate impact on men's employment, giving rise to the moniker \"mancessions,\" we show that the pandemic recession of 2020 was a \"shecession\" in most countries with larger employment declines among women. We examine the causes behind this pattern using micro data from several national labor force surveys, and show that both the composition of women's employment across industries and occupations as well as increased childcare needs during closures of schools and daycare centers made important contributions. While many countries exhibit similar patterns, we also emphasize how policy choices such as furloughing policies and the extent of school closures shape the pandemic's impact on the labor market. Another notable finding is the central role of telecommuting: gender gaps in the employment impact of the pandemic arise almost entirely among workers who are unable to work from home. Nevertheless, among telecommuters a different kind of gender gap arises: women working from home during the pandemic spent more work time also doing childcare and experienced greater productivity reductions than men. We discuss what our findings imply for gender equality in a post-pandemic labor market that will likely continue to be characterized by pervasive telecommuting.","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"36 1","pages":"83 - 151"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2021-04-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"49228195","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 128
Reparations and Persistent Racial Wealth Gaps 赔款和持续的种族贫富差距
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2021-02-01 DOI: 10.1086/723578
J. Boerma, Loukas Karabarbounis
Reparations is a policy proposal aiming to address the wealth gap between Black and White households. We provide a first formal analysis of the economics of reparations using a long-run model of heterogeneous dynasties with an occupational choice and bequests. Our innovation is to introduce endogenous dispersion of beliefs about risky returns, reflecting differences in dynasties' experiences with entrepreneurship over time. Feeding the exclusion of Black dynasties from labor and capital markets as driving force, the model quantitatively reproduces current and historical racial gaps in wealth, income, entrepreneurship, mobility, and beliefs about risky returns. We use the model to evaluate reparations and find that transfers eliminating the racial gap in average wealth today do not lead to wealth convergence in the long run. The logic is that century-long exclusions lead Black dynasties to enter into reparations with pessimistic beliefs about risky returns and to forego investment opportunities. We conclude by showing that entrepreneurial subsidies are more effective than wealth transfers in achieving racial wealth convergence in the long run.
赔偿是一项旨在解决黑人和白人家庭之间贫富差距的政策提案。我们使用具有职业选择和遗赠的异质王朝的长期模型,对赔款经济学进行了首次正式分析。我们的创新之处在于引入关于风险回报的信念的内生分散,反映了历代企业家精神经历的差异。将黑人王朝排除在劳动力和资本市场之外作为驱动力,该模型定量再现了当前和历史上在财富、收入、创业精神、流动性和对风险回报的信念方面的种族差距。我们使用该模型来评估赔偿,并发现消除当前平均财富的种族差距的转移不会导致长期的财富趋同。其逻辑是,长达一个世纪的排斥导致黑人王朝怀着对风险回报的悲观信念进行赔偿,并放弃投资机会。我们的结论是,从长远来看,在实现种族财富趋同方面,企业补贴比财富转移更有效。
{"title":"Reparations and Persistent Racial Wealth Gaps","authors":"J. Boerma, Loukas Karabarbounis","doi":"10.1086/723578","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/723578","url":null,"abstract":"Reparations is a policy proposal aiming to address the wealth gap between Black and White households. We provide a first formal analysis of the economics of reparations using a long-run model of heterogeneous dynasties with an occupational choice and bequests. Our innovation is to introduce endogenous dispersion of beliefs about risky returns, reflecting differences in dynasties' experiences with entrepreneurship over time. Feeding the exclusion of Black dynasties from labor and capital markets as driving force, the model quantitatively reproduces current and historical racial gaps in wealth, income, entrepreneurship, mobility, and beliefs about risky returns. We use the model to evaluate reparations and find that transfers eliminating the racial gap in average wealth today do not lead to wealth convergence in the long run. The logic is that century-long exclusions lead Black dynasties to enter into reparations with pessimistic beliefs about risky returns and to forego investment opportunities. We conclude by showing that entrepreneurial subsidies are more effective than wealth transfers in achieving racial wealth convergence in the long run.","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"37 1","pages":"171 - 221"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2021-02-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"44383276","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 18
Discussion 讨论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2021-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/712335
Greg Kaplan opened the general discussion with a remark about asset return heterogeneity. In the authors’ model, a sufficient degree of dispersion in asset returns guarantees a well-defined equilibriumwealth distribution. Removing asset return heterogeneity would not imply a counterfactually low degree of wealth inequality but rather a degenerate wealth distribution with a mass point at infinity, he said. The authors clarified that their model is able to generate a Pareto tail in the wealth distribution by adding capital return heterogeneity to a standard S. R. Aiyagari (“Uninsured Idiosyncratic Risk and Aggregate Saving,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 109, no. 3 [1994]: 659–84) model with labor income inequality. In their calibration, the mean asset return is below the discount rate, but introducing sufficient dispersion in asset returns allows the model to generate the Pareto tail in the wealth distribution observed in the data, they argued. The rest of the discussion focused on a single topic: the importance of modeling the tax system and measuring the effective tax rate correctly. Frederic Mishkin noted that the effective tax rate can be influenced by tax avoidance. Actual tax collection from highmarginal-income tax brackets in the 1960s and 1970s, for example, was likely impaired due to widespread avoidance, he argued. The authors agreed that accounting for tax avoidance is crucial. They emphasized that their paper employs estimates of the effective tax rate from T. Piketty and E. Saez (“How Progressive Is the US Federal Tax System?AHistorical and International Perspective,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 21, no. 1 [2007]: 3–24), which takes care of this issue. James Poterba offered two comments related to the measurement of the effective tax rate on capital income. Such estimates are typically low, Poterba argued, because of two features of the US tax system: the deferral
Greg Kaplan以一句关于资产回报异质性的话开启了一般性讨论。在作者的模型中,资产回报的充分分散程度保证了财富分配的明确平衡。他说,消除资产回报的异质性并不意味着反事实的低程度财富不平等,而是一种质量点无穷大的退化财富分布。作者澄清说,他们的模型能够通过将资本回报异质性添加到具有劳动收入不平等的标准S.R.Aiyagari(“未保险的特定风险和总储蓄”,《经济学季刊》109,第3期[1994]:659–84)模型中,在财富分配中产生帕累托尾部。他们认为,在他们的校准中,平均资产回报率低于贴现率,但在资产回报中引入足够的分散性可以使模型在数据中观察到的财富分布中产生帕累托尾部。其余的讨论集中在一个单一的主题上:税收系统建模和正确衡量有效税率的重要性。弗雷德里克·米什金指出,实际税率可能受到避税行为的影响。例如,他认为,在20世纪60年代和70年代,从高边际所得税等级征收的实际税款可能因普遍避税而受损。提交人一致认为,对避税行为进行会计核算至关重要。他们强调,他们的论文采用了T.Piketty和E.Saez对有效税率的估计(“美国联邦税收制度的进步程度如何?历史和国际视角”,《经济展望杂志》21,第1期[2007]:3-24),该文处理了这一问题。James Poterba就资本收入实际税率的衡量提出了两条意见。Poterba认为,由于美国税收制度的两个特点,这种估计通常很低:延期
{"title":"Discussion","authors":"","doi":"10.1086/712335","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/712335","url":null,"abstract":"Greg Kaplan opened the general discussion with a remark about asset return heterogeneity. In the authors’ model, a sufficient degree of dispersion in asset returns guarantees a well-defined equilibriumwealth distribution. Removing asset return heterogeneity would not imply a counterfactually low degree of wealth inequality but rather a degenerate wealth distribution with a mass point at infinity, he said. The authors clarified that their model is able to generate a Pareto tail in the wealth distribution by adding capital return heterogeneity to a standard S. R. Aiyagari (“Uninsured Idiosyncratic Risk and Aggregate Saving,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 109, no. 3 [1994]: 659–84) model with labor income inequality. In their calibration, the mean asset return is below the discount rate, but introducing sufficient dispersion in asset returns allows the model to generate the Pareto tail in the wealth distribution observed in the data, they argued. The rest of the discussion focused on a single topic: the importance of modeling the tax system and measuring the effective tax rate correctly. Frederic Mishkin noted that the effective tax rate can be influenced by tax avoidance. Actual tax collection from highmarginal-income tax brackets in the 1960s and 1970s, for example, was likely impaired due to widespread avoidance, he argued. The authors agreed that accounting for tax avoidance is crucial. They emphasized that their paper employs estimates of the effective tax rate from T. Piketty and E. Saez (“How Progressive Is the US Federal Tax System?AHistorical and International Perspective,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 21, no. 1 [2007]: 3–24), which takes care of this issue. James Poterba offered two comments related to the measurement of the effective tax rate on capital income. Such estimates are typically low, Poterba argued, because of two features of the US tax system: the deferral","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"35 1","pages":"480 - 481"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2021-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/712335","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"48297496","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Nber Macroeconomics Annual
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1