首页 > 最新文献

Nber Macroeconomics Annual最新文献

英文 中文
Discussion 讨论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2021-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/712327
Erik Hurst followed up on a comment made by the discussant, John Haltiwanger. He posited that the increasing dispersion in revenue productivity across firms might arise because of differential shifts in the composition of the labor force based on human capital accumulation. Haltiwanger added that the source of dispersion in revenues per employee could also be the result of misallocation deriving from a learning process. The adoption of information and communications technologies across firms is a slow process, which would result in staggered revenue productivity gains across firms, he argued. The authors agreed that markup dispersion—themain source of productivity differentials according to their results—provides a good explanation, but it is not exhaustive. Other possible channels, like human capital, and the resulting misallocations are worth investigating, they said. The authors also sympathized with the discussant’s suggestion to extend their analysis to the sectoral level and to employ a nested CES production structure. They agreed that this methodologymight be useful to shed more light on the role of big firms in driving aggregate productivity growth. The discussion ended with a brief question by Haltiwanger on the surge of IPOs in the 1990s. He askedwhether the authors had researched their role in contributing to subsequent growth. The authors answered that they did not perform the exercise but that their framework could be employed for answering the question.
Erik Hurst跟进了讨论者John Haltiwanger的评论。他认为,企业之间收入生产率的日益分散可能是由于基于人力资本积累的劳动力组成的差异变化。Haltiwanger补充道,每位员工收入分散的来源也可能是学习过程中分配不当的结果。他认为,企业间采用信息和通信技术是一个缓慢的过程,这将导致企业间收入和生产力的交错增长。作者们一致认为,根据他们的研究结果,标记分散是生产力差异的主要来源,这提供了一个很好的解释,但并不是详尽无遗的。他们表示,其他可能的渠道,如人力资本,以及由此产生的分配不当值得调查。作者还赞同讨论者的建议,将他们的分析扩展到部门层面,并采用嵌套的消费电子产品生产结构。他们一致认为,这种方法可能有助于进一步阐明大公司在推动总生产力增长方面的作用。讨论结束时,Haltiwanger就20世纪90年代IPO的激增提出了一个简短的问题。他询问作者是否研究了他们在促进后续成长中的作用。作者回答说,他们没有进行练习,但他们的框架可以用来回答这个问题。
{"title":"Discussion","authors":"","doi":"10.1086/712327","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/712327","url":null,"abstract":"Erik Hurst followed up on a comment made by the discussant, John Haltiwanger. He posited that the increasing dispersion in revenue productivity across firms might arise because of differential shifts in the composition of the labor force based on human capital accumulation. Haltiwanger added that the source of dispersion in revenues per employee could also be the result of misallocation deriving from a learning process. The adoption of information and communications technologies across firms is a slow process, which would result in staggered revenue productivity gains across firms, he argued. The authors agreed that markup dispersion—themain source of productivity differentials according to their results—provides a good explanation, but it is not exhaustive. Other possible channels, like human capital, and the resulting misallocations are worth investigating, they said. The authors also sympathized with the discussant’s suggestion to extend their analysis to the sectoral level and to employ a nested CES production structure. They agreed that this methodologymight be useful to shed more light on the role of big firms in driving aggregate productivity growth. The discussion ended with a brief question by Haltiwanger on the surge of IPOs in the 1990s. He askedwhether the authors had researched their role in contributing to subsequent growth. The authors answered that they did not perform the exercise but that their framework could be employed for answering the question.","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"35 1","pages":"308 - 308"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2021-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"42702249","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Comment 评论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2021-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/712333
Owen M. Zidar
Hubmer, Krusell, and Smith use a heterogeneous agent model to quantify the sources ofwealth inequality in the United States since 1960. They find that the substantial decline of US tax progressivity is a key driver of wealth inequality in the United States. Two other keymodel features are (1) allowing for heterogeneous returns and (2) portfolio heterogeneity. My comments focus on the threemain determinants thatHubmer et al. emphasize, which I agree are quite important, and then discuss a few other drivers ofwealth inequality that strikeme asfirst order andworthy of more analysis and discussion in future work.
Hubmer、Krusell和Smith使用异质代理模型来量化自1960年以来美国健康不平等的来源。他们发现,美国税收累进性的大幅下降是美国财富不平等的关键驱动因素。另外两个关键模型特征是(1)允许异质回报和(2)投资组合异质性。我的评论集中在Hubmer等人强调的三个主要决定因素上,我同意这三个决定因素非常重要,然后讨论了健康不平等的其他一些驱动因素,这些驱动因素被列为第一级,值得在未来的工作中进行更多的分析和讨论。
{"title":"Comment","authors":"Owen M. Zidar","doi":"10.1086/712333","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/712333","url":null,"abstract":"Hubmer, Krusell, and Smith use a heterogeneous agent model to quantify the sources ofwealth inequality in the United States since 1960. They find that the substantial decline of US tax progressivity is a key driver of wealth inequality in the United States. Two other keymodel features are (1) allowing for heterogeneous returns and (2) portfolio heterogeneity. My comments focus on the threemain determinants thatHubmer et al. emphasize, which I agree are quite important, and then discuss a few other drivers ofwealth inequality that strikeme asfirst order andworthy of more analysis and discussion in future work.","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"35 1","pages":"456 - 467"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2021-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/712333","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"41939637","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The Glass Ceiling and the Paper Floor: Changing Gender Composition of Top Earners since the 1980s 玻璃天花板和纸地板:20世纪80年代以来收入最高者性别构成的变化
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2021-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/712328
Fatih Guvenen, Greg Kaplan, Jae Song
Since the late 1970s, the US earnings distribution has experienced profound changes. Among these changes, two of the most well-known are the increasing share of total earnings that accrues to top earners (i.e., individuals in the top 1% or top 0.1% of the earnings distribution) and the continued relative absence of women from this top-earning group. This latter phenomenon is commonly referred to as the glass ceiling, the emergence of which has spurred both debate over the appropriate policy response as well as active research into its primary causes. However, progress on both fronts has been hampered by the scarcity of empirical evidence from nationally representative data on the gender structure at the top of the earnings distribution. Our goal in this paper is to provide this necessary empirical evidence on the glass ceiling, using newer and better data than have been previously available. In doing so, we also revisit several important questions about top earners of both genders: the dynamics of their earnings, their industry composition, their age and cohort composition, and the evolution of earnings for lifetime top earners. Our interest in top earners is motivated by their disproportionately large influence on the aggregate economy. This influence operates through at least three channels. First, top earners are crucial economic actors. In the United States, individuals in the top 1% of the income distribution earn approximately 15% of aggregate before-tax income and pay about 40% of individual income taxes—more than one and a half times the amount paid by the bottom 90 percentiles—and 50% of all corporate income tax. Because this group includes virtually all high-level managers
自上世纪70年代末以来,美国的收入分配经历了深刻的变化。在这些变化中,最著名的两个变化是高收入者(即收入分布中前1%或前0.1%的个人)在总收入中所占的份额不断增加,以及女性在这个收入最高的群体中继续相对缺席。后一种现象通常被称为玻璃天花板,它的出现既引发了对适当政策反应的辩论,也引发了对其主要原因的积极研究。然而,由于缺乏关于收入分配顶层性别结构的具有全国代表性的数据的经验证据,这两个方面的进展都受到了阻碍。我们在本文中的目标是使用比以前可用的更新和更好的数据,为玻璃天花板提供必要的经验证据。在此过程中,我们还回顾了关于男女高收入者的几个重要问题:他们的收入动态、行业构成、年龄和群体构成,以及终身高收入者的收入演变。我们对高收入者的兴趣,源于他们对整体经济不成比例的巨大影响。这种影响至少通过三个渠道发挥作用。首先,高收入者是至关重要的经济参与者。在美国,收入分配最高的1%的个人收入约占税前总收入的15%,缴纳约40%的个人所得税——是收入最低的90%的人缴纳的税款的1.5倍多——以及所有企业所得税的50%。因为这个群体几乎包括了所有的高层管理人员
{"title":"The Glass Ceiling and the Paper Floor: Changing Gender Composition of Top Earners since the 1980s","authors":"Fatih Guvenen, Greg Kaplan, Jae Song","doi":"10.1086/712328","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/712328","url":null,"abstract":"Since the late 1970s, the US earnings distribution has experienced profound changes. Among these changes, two of the most well-known are the increasing share of total earnings that accrues to top earners (i.e., individuals in the top 1% or top 0.1% of the earnings distribution) and the continued relative absence of women from this top-earning group. This latter phenomenon is commonly referred to as the glass ceiling, the emergence of which has spurred both debate over the appropriate policy response as well as active research into its primary causes. However, progress on both fronts has been hampered by the scarcity of empirical evidence from nationally representative data on the gender structure at the top of the earnings distribution. Our goal in this paper is to provide this necessary empirical evidence on the glass ceiling, using newer and better data than have been previously available. In doing so, we also revisit several important questions about top earners of both genders: the dynamics of their earnings, their industry composition, their age and cohort composition, and the evolution of earnings for lifetime top earners. Our interest in top earners is motivated by their disproportionately large influence on the aggregate economy. This influence operates through at least three channels. First, top earners are crucial economic actors. In the United States, individuals in the top 1% of the income distribution earn approximately 15% of aggregate before-tax income and pay about 40% of individual income taxes—more than one and a half times the amount paid by the bottom 90 percentiles—and 50% of all corporate income tax. Because this group includes virtually all high-level managers","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"35 1","pages":"309 - 373"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2021-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/712328","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"46511088","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 8
Sources of US Wealth Inequality: Past, Present, and Future 美国财富不平等的根源:过去、现在和未来
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2021-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/712332
Joachim Hubmer, Per Krusell, Anthony A. Smith
The distribution of wealth in most countries for which there is reliable data is strikingly uneven. There is also recent work suggesting that the wealth distribution has undergone significant movements over time, most recently with a large upward swing in dispersion in several AngloSaxon countries (Piketty 2014; Saez and Zucman 2016). For example, according to the estimates in Saez and Zucman (2016) for the United States, the share of overall wealth held by the top 1% has increased from around 25% in 1980 to more than 40% today; for the top 0.1% it has increased from less than 10% tomore than 20% over the same time period. The observed developments have generated strong reactions across the political spectrum. In his 2014 book Capital in the Twenty-First Century, Piketty is obviously motivated by the growing inequality in itself, but he also suggests that further increases in wealth concentration may lead to both economic and democratic instability. Conservatives in the United States have expressed worries as well: Is the American dream really still alive, or might it be that a large fraction of the population simply will no longer be able to productively contribute to society? Given, for example, that parental wealth and well-being are important determinants of children’s human capital accumulation, these are legitimate concerns regardless of one’s political views. These concerns, moreover, have stimulated the proposal and discussion of a number of possible changes in policy. The primary aim of the present paper is, instead of focusing on policy changes, to understand the determinants of the observed movements in wealth inequality. This aim is basic but well-motivated in light of the
在大多数有可靠数据的国家,财富的分配是极不平衡的。最近也有研究表明,随着时间的推移,财富分配经历了显著的变化,最近在几个盎格鲁-撒克逊国家,财富分布出现了大幅上升(Piketty 2014;Saez and Zucman 2016)。例如,根据Saez和Zucman(2016)对美国的估计,最富有的1%的人持有的总财富份额从1980年的25%左右增加到今天的40%以上;对于收入最高的0.1%的人来说,这一比例在同一时期从不到10%上升到20%以上。观察到的事态发展在整个政治领域引起了强烈反应。在2014年出版的《21世纪资本论》(Capital In the Twenty-First Century)一书中,皮凯蒂显然是受到日益加剧的不平等本身的推动,但他也指出,财富集中度的进一步提高可能会导致经济和民主的不稳定。美国的保守派也表达了担忧:美国梦真的还活着吗?还是说,很大一部分人口将不再能够为社会做出有成效的贡献?例如,鉴于父母的财富和幸福是儿童人力资本积累的重要决定因素,无论一个人的政治观点如何,这些都是合理的担忧。此外,这些关切刺激了关于若干可能的政策变化的建议和讨论。本文的主要目的不是关注政策变化,而是了解观察到的财富不平等运动的决定因素。这个目标是基本的,但很有动机的
{"title":"Sources of US Wealth Inequality: Past, Present, and Future","authors":"Joachim Hubmer, Per Krusell, Anthony A. Smith","doi":"10.1086/712332","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/712332","url":null,"abstract":"The distribution of wealth in most countries for which there is reliable data is strikingly uneven. There is also recent work suggesting that the wealth distribution has undergone significant movements over time, most recently with a large upward swing in dispersion in several AngloSaxon countries (Piketty 2014; Saez and Zucman 2016). For example, according to the estimates in Saez and Zucman (2016) for the United States, the share of overall wealth held by the top 1% has increased from around 25% in 1980 to more than 40% today; for the top 0.1% it has increased from less than 10% tomore than 20% over the same time period. The observed developments have generated strong reactions across the political spectrum. In his 2014 book Capital in the Twenty-First Century, Piketty is obviously motivated by the growing inequality in itself, but he also suggests that further increases in wealth concentration may lead to both economic and democratic instability. Conservatives in the United States have expressed worries as well: Is the American dream really still alive, or might it be that a large fraction of the population simply will no longer be able to productively contribute to society? Given, for example, that parental wealth and well-being are important determinants of children’s human capital accumulation, these are legitimate concerns regardless of one’s political views. These concerns, moreover, have stimulated the proposal and discussion of a number of possible changes in policy. The primary aim of the present paper is, instead of focusing on policy changes, to understand the determinants of the observed movements in wealth inequality. This aim is basic but well-motivated in light of the","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"35 1","pages":"391 - 455"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2021-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/712332","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"41671187","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 40
Discussion 讨论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2021-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/712320
J. Haltiwanger
John Haltiwanger opened the discussion by bringing attention to the dataused in thepaper. The analysis useddata fromtheNational Establishment Time Series (NETS). The authors argued that the NETS is a reliable source because it aligns on several dimensions with another data set, the County Business Patterns (CBP). However, Haltiwanger argued that NETS overstates employment because of imputations. Further, NETS sales data are not reliable, as documented by Barnatchez, Crane, and Decker (“An Assessment of the National Establishment Times Series [NETS] Database,” Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2017 [2017]: 110). The authors recognized that there are imputations in NETS. However, they emphasized that their findings are validated by several robustness checks. In addition, they noted that similar results hold when using a different data set, the Longitudinal Business Database (LBD). The next comments were related to the suitability of the HerfindahlHirschman Index (HHI) as ameasure ofmarket power at different levels of geographic aggregation. Jeffrey Campbell pointed out that the HHI is not a reliable measure of market power for large cities, where there are many firms in themarket and there is substantial variation across neighborhoods. He encouraged the authors to repeat their analysis for small towns. The authors responded that they replicated their results for different measures of concentration and that their findings are robust regardless of the measure considered. Erik Hurst questioned why the authors decided to start the analysis at the smallest area of aggregation, the ZIP-code level, as opposed to a larger area of aggregation, such as the county level. Seconding Campbell’s remark, the authors responded that themeasurement ofmarket power ismore reliable for smaller geographical
约翰·哈尔蒂万格(John Haltiwanger)在开始讨论时,将注意力放在了论文中使用的数据上。该分析使用了国家机构时间序列(NETS)的数据。作者认为,NETS是一个可靠的来源,因为它在几个维度上与另一个数据集,即县商业模式(CBP)相一致。然而,Haltiwanger认为,NETS夸大就业是因为估算。此外,正如Barnatchez、Crane和Decker所记录的那样,NETS的销售数据并不可靠(“对国家机构时代系列[NETS]数据库的评估”,2017年【2017】金融和经济讨论系列:110)。作者认识到NETS中存在着一些指责。然而,他们强调,他们的发现通过几次稳健性检查得到了验证。此外,他们指出,当使用不同的数据集纵向业务数据库(LBD)时,也会出现类似的结果。接下来的评论与赫芬达尔-赫希曼指数(HHI)作为衡量不同地理聚合水平下市场力量的合适性有关。Jeffrey Campbell指出,对于大城市来说,HHI并不是衡量市场力量的可靠指标,因为大城市的市场上有很多公司,而且各个社区的差异很大。他鼓励作者重复他们对小城镇的分析。作者回应说,他们复制了不同浓度测量的结果,无论考虑何种测量,他们的发现都是稳健的。Erik Hurst质疑为什么作者决定在最小的聚集区域(邮政编码级别)开始分析,而不是在更大的聚集区域,如县级别。根据坎贝尔的评论,作者们回应说,市场力量的测量对于较小的地理区域来说更可靠
{"title":"Discussion","authors":"J. Haltiwanger","doi":"10.1086/712320","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/712320","url":null,"abstract":"John Haltiwanger opened the discussion by bringing attention to the dataused in thepaper. The analysis useddata fromtheNational Establishment Time Series (NETS). The authors argued that the NETS is a reliable source because it aligns on several dimensions with another data set, the County Business Patterns (CBP). However, Haltiwanger argued that NETS overstates employment because of imputations. Further, NETS sales data are not reliable, as documented by Barnatchez, Crane, and Decker (“An Assessment of the National Establishment Times Series [NETS] Database,” Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2017 [2017]: 110). The authors recognized that there are imputations in NETS. However, they emphasized that their findings are validated by several robustness checks. In addition, they noted that similar results hold when using a different data set, the Longitudinal Business Database (LBD). The next comments were related to the suitability of the HerfindahlHirschman Index (HHI) as ameasure ofmarket power at different levels of geographic aggregation. Jeffrey Campbell pointed out that the HHI is not a reliable measure of market power for large cities, where there are many firms in themarket and there is substantial variation across neighborhoods. He encouraged the authors to repeat their analysis for small towns. The authors responded that they replicated their results for different measures of concentration and that their findings are robust regardless of the measure considered. Erik Hurst questioned why the authors decided to start the analysis at the smallest area of aggregation, the ZIP-code level, as opposed to a larger area of aggregation, such as the county level. Seconding Campbell’s remark, the authors responded that themeasurement ofmarket power ismore reliable for smaller geographical","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"35 1","pages":"173 - 174"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2021-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/712320","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"47521869","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Discussion 讨论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2021-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/712316
Valmik Prabhu, Haozhi Qi
Following up on Ricardo Reis’s discussion, Martin Eichenbaum asked a question on disagreement in models with heterogeneous beliefs, which sparked a general discussion on the topic. In practice, disagreement between agents seems to be very persistent. He asked whether the authors’ model and the modification suggested by the discussant were consistent with this observation.Alp Simsek secondedEichenbaum’s comment, pointing out that most models with dispersed information, including the authors’, have the implication that if an individualwere to elicit other agents’ expectations, shewould account for this new information. In otherwords, if average beliefs were part of the current information set, individuals would update their own beliefs in response. This does not seem to be supported by the data, he claimed. Simsek’s own empirical analysis of the Blue Chip Financial Forecasts in Ricardo Caballero and Alp Simsek (“Monetary Policy with OpinionatedMarkets” [Working Paper no. 27313, NBER, Cambridge, MA, 2020]) finds evidence in support of confident disagreement: past individual forecasts are abetter predictor for future individual forecasts than past consensus forecasts. This fact seems to indicate that forecasters have dogmatic beliefs and do not consider the other agents to have useful informationwhen forming expectations for the future. It is important to take this into account for understanding how agents respond to new information, he claimed. The authors answered to the remarks on the role of disagreement among agents arguing that it does not have material consequences for the implications of their theory. There are two arguments that support this conclusion. First, the actual level of information precision is irrelevant for shaping aggregate outcomes. It is the perceived level of precision
继Ricardo Reis的讨论之后,Martin Eichenbaum提出了一个关于具有异质信念的模型中的分歧的问题,这引发了对该主题的一般性讨论。在实践中,代理人之间的分歧似乎一直存在。他询问作者的模型和讨论者建议的修改是否与这一观察结果一致。Alp Simsek赞同Eichenbaum的评论,指出大多数信息分散的模型,包括作者的模型,都意味着如果一个人想引起其他代理人的期望,她会解释这些新信息。换句话说,如果平均信念是当前信息集的一部分,个体会更新自己的信念作为回应。他声称,这似乎没有得到数据的支持。Simsek在Ricardo Caballero和Alp Simsek(“OpinionatedMarkets的货币政策”[工作文件编号27313,NBER,Cambridge,MA,2020])中对蓝筹股金融预测的实证分析发现了支持自信分歧的证据:过去的个人预测比过去的一致预测更能预测未来的个人预测。这一事实似乎表明,预测者有着教条主义的信念,在对未来形成预期时,并不认为其他主体拥有有用的信息。他声称,重要的是要考虑到这一点,以了解特工对新信息的反应。作者回答了关于代理人之间分歧的作用的评论,认为这对他们理论的含义没有实质性后果。有两个论点支持这一结论。首先,信息精度的实际水平与形成总体结果无关。它是感知到的精度水平
{"title":"Discussion","authors":"Valmik Prabhu, Haozhi Qi","doi":"10.1086/712316","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/712316","url":null,"abstract":"Following up on Ricardo Reis’s discussion, Martin Eichenbaum asked a question on disagreement in models with heterogeneous beliefs, which sparked a general discussion on the topic. In practice, disagreement between agents seems to be very persistent. He asked whether the authors’ model and the modification suggested by the discussant were consistent with this observation.Alp Simsek secondedEichenbaum’s comment, pointing out that most models with dispersed information, including the authors’, have the implication that if an individualwere to elicit other agents’ expectations, shewould account for this new information. In otherwords, if average beliefs were part of the current information set, individuals would update their own beliefs in response. This does not seem to be supported by the data, he claimed. Simsek’s own empirical analysis of the Blue Chip Financial Forecasts in Ricardo Caballero and Alp Simsek (“Monetary Policy with OpinionatedMarkets” [Working Paper no. 27313, NBER, Cambridge, MA, 2020]) finds evidence in support of confident disagreement: past individual forecasts are abetter predictor for future individual forecasts than past consensus forecasts. This fact seems to indicate that forecasters have dogmatic beliefs and do not consider the other agents to have useful informationwhen forming expectations for the future. It is important to take this into account for understanding how agents respond to new information, he claimed. The authors answered to the remarks on the role of disagreement among agents arguing that it does not have material consequences for the implications of their theory. There are two arguments that support this conclusion. First, the actual level of information precision is irrelevant for shaping aggregate outcomes. It is the perceived level of precision","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"35 1","pages":"112 - 114"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2021-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/712316","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"47382225","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Comment 评论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2021-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/712323
V. Ramey
This insightful paper byGuren,McKay,Nakamura, and Steinsson (Guren et al.) contributes to the literature that seeks to translate effects estimated on data at one level of geographic aggregation to another level of geographic aggregation. It can also be seen as a companion paper to their paper on the effects of variations of housingwealth on consumption (Guren et al. forthcoming). The current paper develops a very clever method for recovering “partial equilibrium” effects from regressions using variation across subnational units, such as cities and states. It then applies thismethod to estimating the marginal propensity to consume out of housing wealth. Separately, it offers a solution to a puzzle that has arisen with respect to the widely used Saiz (2010) instrument used for house prices.
这篇由Guren、McKay、Nakamura和Steinsson (Guren et al.)撰写的有见地的论文为寻求将一个地理聚集水平的数据估计效应转化为另一个地理聚集水平的文献做出了贡献。它也可以被视为他们关于住房财富变化对消费影响的论文的配套论文(Guren等人即将出版)。目前的论文开发了一种非常聪明的方法,可以利用城市和州等次国家单位的变化,从回归中恢复“部分平衡”效应。然后将该方法应用于估算住房财富的边际消费倾向。另外,它为广泛使用的用于房价的Saiz(2010)工具所产生的难题提供了解决方案。
{"title":"Comment","authors":"V. Ramey","doi":"10.1086/712323","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/712323","url":null,"abstract":"This insightful paper byGuren,McKay,Nakamura, and Steinsson (Guren et al.) contributes to the literature that seeks to translate effects estimated on data at one level of geographic aggregation to another level of geographic aggregation. It can also be seen as a companion paper to their paper on the effects of variations of housingwealth on consumption (Guren et al. forthcoming). The current paper develops a very clever method for recovering “partial equilibrium” effects from regressions using variation across subnational units, such as cities and states. It then applies thismethod to estimating the marginal propensity to consume out of housing wealth. Separately, it offers a solution to a puzzle that has arisen with respect to the widely used Saiz (2010) instrument used for house prices.","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"35 1","pages":"232 - 241"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2021-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/712323","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"46695485","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Imperfect Macroeconomic Expectations: Evidence and Theory 不完全宏观经济预期:证据与理论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2020-06-01 DOI: 10.1086/712313
G. Angeletos, Zhengxin Huo, Karthik A. Sastry
We document a new fact about expectations: in response to the main shocks driving the business cycle, expectations under-react initially but over-shoot later on. We show how previous, seemingly conflicting, evidence can be understood as different facets of this fact. We finally explain what the cumulated evidence means for macroeconomic theory. There is little support for theories emphasizing under-extrapolation or two close cousins of it, cognitive discounting and level-K thinking. Instead, the evidence favors the combination of dispersed, noisy information and over-extrapolation.
我们记录了一个关于预期的新事实:为了应对推动商业周期的主要冲击,预期最初反应不足,但后来反应过度。我们展示了以前看似矛盾的证据如何被理解为这一事实的不同方面。我们最后解释了累积证据对宏观经济理论的意义。很少有人支持强调外推法或其两个近亲——认知折扣和K级思维的理论。相反,证据支持分散、嘈杂的信息和过度推断的结合。
{"title":"Imperfect Macroeconomic Expectations: Evidence and Theory","authors":"G. Angeletos, Zhengxin Huo, Karthik A. Sastry","doi":"10.1086/712313","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/712313","url":null,"abstract":"We document a new fact about expectations: in response to the main shocks driving the business cycle, expectations under-react initially but over-shoot later on. We show how previous, seemingly conflicting, evidence can be understood as different facets of this fact. We finally explain what the cumulated evidence means for macroeconomic theory. There is little support for theories emphasizing under-extrapolation or two close cousins of it, cognitive discounting and level-K thinking. Instead, the evidence favors the combination of dispersed, noisy information and over-extrapolation.","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"35 1","pages":"1 - 86"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2020-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/712313","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"45845620","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 107
Why Has the US Economy Recovered So Consistently from Every Recession in the Past 70 Years? 为什么美国经济在过去70年的每一次衰退中都如此稳定地复苏?
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2020-05-01 DOI: 10.1086/718588
Robert E. Hall, Marianna Kudlyak
A remarkable fact about the historical US business cycle is that, after unemployment reached its peak in a recession, and a recovery begins, the annual reduction in the unemployment rate is stable at around one tenth of the current level of unemployment. We document this fact in a companion paper, Hall and Kudlyak (2020a). Here, we consider explanations for the surprising consistency of recoveries. We show that the evolution of the labor market from recession to recovery involves more than the direct effect of persistent unemployment of job-losers from the recession shock -- unemployment during the recovery is above normal for people who did not lose jobs during the recession. We explore models of the labor market's self-recovery that imply gradual working off of unemployment following a recession shock. We emphasize the feedback from high unemployment to the forces driving job creation. These models also explain why the recovery of market-wide unemployment is so much slower than the rate at which individual unemployed workers find new jobs. The reasons include the fact that the path that individual job-losers follow back to stable employment often includes several brief interim jobs.
美国历史商业周期的一个显著事实是,在失业率在衰退中达到峰值并开始复苏后,失业率的年度下降稳定在当前失业水平的十分之一左右。我们在一篇配套论文Hall和Kudlyak(2020a)中记录了这一事实。在这里,我们考虑对回收率惊人一致性的解释。我们表明,劳动力市场从衰退到复苏的演变不仅仅涉及衰退冲击中失业者持续失业的直接影响——对于在衰退期间没有失业的人来说,复苏期间的失业率高于正常水平。我们探索了劳动力市场自我复苏的模型,这意味着在经济衰退冲击后,失业率会逐渐降低。我们强调高失业率对创造就业的力量的反馈。这些模型也解释了为什么整个市场失业率的复苏速度比失业工人个人找到新工作的速度慢得多。原因包括,失业者重返稳定就业的道路通常包括几个短暂的临时工作。
{"title":"Why Has the US Economy Recovered So Consistently from Every Recession in the Past 70 Years?","authors":"Robert E. Hall, Marianna Kudlyak","doi":"10.1086/718588","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/718588","url":null,"abstract":"A remarkable fact about the historical US business cycle is that, after unemployment reached its peak in a recession, and a recovery begins, the annual reduction in the unemployment rate is stable at around one tenth of the current level of unemployment. We document this fact in a companion paper, Hall and Kudlyak (2020a). Here, we consider explanations for the surprising consistency of recoveries. We show that the evolution of the labor market from recession to recovery involves more than the direct effect of persistent unemployment of job-losers from the recession shock -- unemployment during the recovery is above normal for people who did not lose jobs during the recession. We explore models of the labor market's self-recovery that imply gradual working off of unemployment following a recession shock. We emphasize the feedback from high unemployment to the forces driving job creation. These models also explain why the recovery of market-wide unemployment is so much slower than the rate at which individual unemployed workers find new jobs. The reasons include the fact that the path that individual job-losers follow back to stable employment often includes several brief interim jobs.","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"36 1","pages":"1 - 55"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2020-05-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"44725087","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 27
Innovative Growth Accounting 创新增长会计
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2020-04-01 DOI: 10.1086/712325
Peter J. Klenow, Huiyu Li
Recent work highlights a falling entry rate of new firms and a rising market share of large firms in the United States. To understand how these changing firm demographics have affected growth, we decompose productivity growth into the firms doing the innovating. We trace how much each firm innovates by the rate at which it opens and closes plants, the market share of those plants, and how fast its surviving plants grow. Using data on all nonfarm businesses from 1982–2013, we find that new and young firms (ages 0 to 5 years) account for almost one-half of growth – three times their share of employment. Large established firms contribute only one-tenth of growth despite representing one-fourth of employment. Older firms do explain most of the speedup and slowdown during the middle of our sample. Finally, most growth takes the form of incumbents improving their own products, as opposed to creative destruction or new varieties.
最近的工作突出了美国新公司进入率的下降和大公司市场份额的上升。为了了解这些不断变化的企业人口结构如何影响增长,我们将生产力增长分解为进行创新的企业。我们通过开设和关闭工厂的速度、这些工厂的市场份额以及幸存工厂的生长速度来追踪每家公司的创新程度。利用1982年至2013年所有非农企业的数据,我们发现新企业和年轻企业(0至5岁)几乎占了增长的一半,是其就业份额的三倍。大型老牌企业虽然占就业人数的四分之一,但对经济增长的贡献仅为十分之一。在我们的样本中期,老公司确实解释了大部分的加速和减速。最后,大多数增长都是以在位者改进自己的产品的形式实现的,而不是创造性的破坏或新品种。
{"title":"Innovative Growth Accounting","authors":"Peter J. Klenow, Huiyu Li","doi":"10.1086/712325","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/712325","url":null,"abstract":"Recent work highlights a falling entry rate of new firms and a rising market share of large firms in the United States. To understand how these changing firm demographics have affected growth, we decompose productivity growth into the firms doing the innovating. We trace how much each firm innovates by the rate at which it opens and closes plants, the market share of those plants, and how fast its surviving plants grow. Using data on all nonfarm businesses from 1982–2013, we find that new and young firms (ages 0 to 5 years) account for almost one-half of growth – three times their share of employment. Large established firms contribute only one-tenth of growth despite representing one-fourth of employment. Older firms do explain most of the speedup and slowdown during the middle of our sample. Finally, most growth takes the form of incumbents improving their own products, as opposed to creative destruction or new varieties.","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"35 1","pages":"245 - 295"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2020-04-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/712325","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"42633607","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 14
期刊
Nber Macroeconomics Annual
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1