首页 > 最新文献

William and Mary law review最新文献

英文 中文
Revisiting the Impact of Judicial Review on Agency Rulemakings: An Empirical Investigation 重新审视司法审查对机构规则制定的影响:一项实证调查
Pub Date : 2012-02-05 DOI: 10.15781/T2VM42Z5B
W. Wagner
It is generally believed that the judicial review of agency rulemakings helps protect the public interest against industry capture. Yet very little empirical research has been done to assess the accuracy of this conventional wisdom. This study examines the entire set of air toxic emission regulations promulgated by the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA), with particular attention to those rules appealed to judgment in the court of appeals, and discovers significant disconnects between popular understanding of judicial review and rule-making reality. Of these air toxic rules (N=90), the courts were summoned to review only a small fraction (8%), despite evidence that many air toxic rules may have problems, at least from the public interest perspective. Moreover, although virtually all of the litigation brought by public interest groups against the EPA’s air toxic rules was successful, the resulting victories have not yet had much impact in practice. For most of its vacated regulations, the EPA has either ignored or limited the courts’ opinions and has not re-promulgated revised rules. Thus, while the tenor of the opinions seems to re-affirm the courts’ role as guardian of the public interest, the actual impact of these opinions on agency practice may be less influential than one might expect. A concluding section takes the analysis one step further and explores the possibility that the net effect of judicial review may actually be more perverse. The ability of the dominant parties (which in the case of EPA’s air toxic rules is regulated industry) to threaten the agency with expensive and time-consuming litigation could provide these groups with legal leverage that, in the aggregate serves to further undermine the agency’s ability to act on behalf of the public interest.
人们普遍认为,对机构规则制定的司法审查有助于保护公共利益免受行业垄断。然而,很少有实证研究来评估这种传统智慧的准确性。本研究审查了环境保护署(EPA)颁布的整套空气毒性排放条例,特别注意上诉法院判决的那些规则,并发现普遍对司法审查的理解与规则制定现实之间存在重大脱节。在这些空气毒性规定(N=90)中,法院被传唤审查的只有一小部分(8%),尽管有证据表明,许多空气毒性规定可能存在问题,至少从公共利益的角度来看。此外,尽管几乎所有由公共利益团体发起的针对环保署空气毒性规定的诉讼都取得了成功,但最终的胜利尚未在实践中产生多大影响。对于大多数被撤销的法规,环境保护署要么无视法院的意见,要么限制法院的意见,也没有重新颁布修订后的法规。因此,虽然这些意见的主旨似乎再次肯定了法院作为公共利益守护者的作用,但这些意见对机构实践的实际影响可能不如人们预期的那么大。结论部分进一步分析,并探讨司法审查的净效果实际上可能更加反常的可能性。占主导地位的各方(在EPA的空气毒性规则中是受监管的行业)以昂贵而耗时的诉讼威胁该机构的能力,可能会为这些团体提供法律杠杆,从而进一步削弱该机构代表公众利益行事的能力。
{"title":"Revisiting the Impact of Judicial Review on Agency Rulemakings: An Empirical Investigation","authors":"W. Wagner","doi":"10.15781/T2VM42Z5B","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.15781/T2VM42Z5B","url":null,"abstract":"It is generally believed that the judicial review of agency rulemakings helps protect the public interest against industry capture. Yet very little empirical research has been done to assess the accuracy of this conventional wisdom. This study examines the entire set of air toxic emission regulations promulgated by the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA), with particular attention to those rules appealed to judgment in the court of appeals, and discovers significant disconnects between popular understanding of judicial review and rule-making reality. Of these air toxic rules (N=90), the courts were summoned to review only a small fraction (8%), despite evidence that many air toxic rules may have problems, at least from the public interest perspective. Moreover, although virtually all of the litigation brought by public interest groups against the EPA’s air toxic rules was successful, the resulting victories have not yet had much impact in practice. For most of its vacated regulations, the EPA has either ignored or limited the courts’ opinions and has not re-promulgated revised rules. Thus, while the tenor of the opinions seems to re-affirm the courts’ role as guardian of the public interest, the actual impact of these opinions on agency practice may be less influential than one might expect. A concluding section takes the analysis one step further and explores the possibility that the net effect of judicial review may actually be more perverse. The ability of the dominant parties (which in the case of EPA’s air toxic rules is regulated industry) to threaten the agency with expensive and time-consuming litigation could provide these groups with legal leverage that, in the aggregate serves to further undermine the agency’s ability to act on behalf of the public interest.","PeriodicalId":75324,"journal":{"name":"William and Mary law review","volume":"53 1","pages":"1717"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2012-02-05","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"67098255","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 7
Globalization and Structure 全球化与结构
Pub Date : 2011-09-20 DOI: 10.1093/acprof:osobl/9780199837427.003.0003
Julian G. Ku, J. Yoo
Globalization creates pressure for increased international cooperation, and to reap the benefits of collective action, international cooperation is likely to take forms that resemble those of the American administrative state. An international regulatory regime generally will need to reach all activity, regardless of each individual nation’s internal hierarchy of authority. Although relatively new to the international scene, these forms and orders should sound familiar to students of the American administrative state. Just as new international regimes seek more pervasive regulation of garden-variety conduct, so too did the New Deal seek national control over private economic decisions that had once rested within the control of the states. The Kyoto accords, for example, had their counterpart in the federal government’s efforts to control the production of every bushel of wheat on every American farm, as discussed in Wickard v. Filburn. The New Deal’s stretching of constitutional doctrine sparked a confrontation between President Franklin D. Roosevelt (FDR) and the Supreme Court, which initially espoused a narrower and less flexible vision of federal power and the role of administrative agencies. Without a theory that allows for an accommodation of international policy demands with the U.S. constitutional system, these new forms of international cooperation may well produce an analogous collision with constitutional law. This article will offer the outlines of such a theory.
全球化为加强国际合作创造了压力,为了获得集体行动的好处,国际合作很可能采取类似于美国行政国家的形式。一般来说,国际监管制度需要涵盖所有活动,而不管每个国家的内部权威等级如何。尽管这些形式和秩序在国际舞台上相对较新,但对于研究美国行政国家的学生来说,它们应该听起来很熟悉。正如新的国际制度寻求对普通行为进行更普遍的监管一样,新政也寻求对曾经由国家控制的私人经济决策进行国家控制。例如,正如威卡德诉菲尔伯恩案所讨论的那样,《京都议定书》在联邦政府控制每个美国农场每蒲式耳小麦产量的努力中有相应的规定。新政对宪法原则的延伸引发了总统富兰克林·d·罗斯福(Franklin D. Roosevelt)与最高法院之间的对抗,最高法院最初对联邦权力和行政机构的作用持狭隘和不太灵活的看法。如果没有一种理论允许国际政策要求与美国宪法体系相适应,这些新形式的国际合作很可能会产生与宪法法律类似的冲突。本文将提供这样一个理论的概要。
{"title":"Globalization and Structure","authors":"Julian G. Ku, J. Yoo","doi":"10.1093/acprof:osobl/9780199837427.003.0003","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/acprof:osobl/9780199837427.003.0003","url":null,"abstract":"Globalization creates pressure for increased international cooperation, and to reap the benefits of collective action, international cooperation is likely to take forms that resemble those of the American administrative state. An international regulatory regime generally will need to reach all activity, regardless of each individual nation’s internal hierarchy of authority. Although relatively new to the international scene, these forms and orders should sound familiar to students of the American administrative state. Just as new international regimes seek more pervasive regulation of garden-variety conduct, so too did the New Deal seek national control over private economic decisions that had once rested within the control of the states. The Kyoto accords, for example, had their counterpart in the federal government’s efforts to control the production of every bushel of wheat on every American farm, as discussed in Wickard v. Filburn. The New Deal’s stretching of constitutional doctrine sparked a confrontation between President Franklin D. Roosevelt (FDR) and the Supreme Court, which initially espoused a narrower and less flexible vision of federal power and the role of administrative agencies. Without a theory that allows for an accommodation of international policy demands with the U.S. constitutional system, these new forms of international cooperation may well produce an analogous collision with constitutional law. This article will offer the outlines of such a theory.","PeriodicalId":75324,"journal":{"name":"William and Mary law review","volume":"32 1","pages":"431"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2011-09-20","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"60654938","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Business Courts and Interstate Competition 商业法庭和州际竞争
Pub Date : 2011-09-15 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.1928108
J. Coyle
Over the past two decades, nineteen states have established specialized trial courts that hear business disputes primarily or exclusively. To explain the recent surge of interest in these courts, policy-makers and scholars alike have cited the process of inter-jurisdictional competition. Specifically, these commentators have argued that business courts serve, among other purposes, to attract out-of-state companies to expand their business, re-incorporate, or litigate their disputes in the jurisdiction that created the business court. This Article critically evaluates each of these theories. It argues, first, that business courts do not serve to attract companies from other states because business expansion decisions in the United States are rarely driven by the high quality of the courts in a particular jurisdiction. It next argues that business courts are unlikely to attract incorporation business because their core attributes are such that they are unlikely to compete successfully with the Delaware Court of Chancery. The Article goes on to argue that while the creation of a business court may in some cases serve to divert litigation business to local lawyers, the opportunities for diversion are relatively limited. The Article then draws upon these insights to offer a number of suggestions as to how future business courts should be designed. It suggests that states should think twice before creating business and technology courts. It notes that major institutional reforms will be required if states wish to use business courts to attract incorporation business away from Delaware. It also identifies additional steps that states might take to more effectively attract litigation business. The Article concludes by briefly evaluating the viability of several non-competition-based rationales for establishing business courts.
在过去的二十年里,19个州建立了专门的审判法庭,主要或专门审理商业纠纷。为了解释最近对这些法院的兴趣激增,政策制定者和学者都引用了司法管辖区间竞争的过程。具体地说,这些评论者认为,商业法庭的作用,除其他目的外,是吸引州外的公司扩大业务,重新合并,或在设立商业法庭的司法管辖区提起诉讼。本文批判性地评价了这些理论。它认为,首先,商业法庭并不能吸引其他州的公司,因为在美国,商业扩张的决定很少是由特定司法管辖区的高质量法院推动的。接下来,它辩称,商业法庭不太可能吸引公司业务,因为它们的核心属性使它们不太可能与特拉华州衡平法院成功竞争。文章接着指出,虽然设立商业法庭在某些情况下可能有助于将诉讼业务转移给当地律师,但转移的机会相对有限。文章随后借鉴这些见解,就如何设计未来的商事法庭提出了一些建议。它建议各州在设立商业和技术法庭之前应该三思而后行。报告指出,如果各州希望利用商业法庭将公司业务从特拉华州吸引过来,就需要进行重大的制度改革。它还确定了各州可能采取的其他措施,以更有效地吸引诉讼业务。文章最后简要评价了建立商事法庭的若干基于非竞争的理由的可行性。
{"title":"Business Courts and Interstate Competition","authors":"J. Coyle","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.1928108","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.1928108","url":null,"abstract":"Over the past two decades, nineteen states have established specialized trial courts that hear business disputes primarily or exclusively. To explain the recent surge of interest in these courts, policy-makers and scholars alike have cited the process of inter-jurisdictional competition. Specifically, these commentators have argued that business courts serve, among other purposes, to attract out-of-state companies to expand their business, re-incorporate, or litigate their disputes in the jurisdiction that created the business court. This Article critically evaluates each of these theories. It argues, first, that business courts do not serve to attract companies from other states because business expansion decisions in the United States are rarely driven by the high quality of the courts in a particular jurisdiction. It next argues that business courts are unlikely to attract incorporation business because their core attributes are such that they are unlikely to compete successfully with the Delaware Court of Chancery. The Article goes on to argue that while the creation of a business court may in some cases serve to divert litigation business to local lawyers, the opportunities for diversion are relatively limited. The Article then draws upon these insights to offer a number of suggestions as to how future business courts should be designed. It suggests that states should think twice before creating business and technology courts. It notes that major institutional reforms will be required if states wish to use business courts to attract incorporation business away from Delaware. It also identifies additional steps that states might take to more effectively attract litigation business. The Article concludes by briefly evaluating the viability of several non-competition-based rationales for establishing business courts.","PeriodicalId":75324,"journal":{"name":"William and Mary law review","volume":"53 1","pages":"1915"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2011-09-15","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"67795915","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 12
What is the 'Invention'? 什么是“发明”?
Pub Date : 2011-08-29 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.1918841
C. Cotropia
Patent law is in flux, with recent disputes and change in doctrine fueled by increased attention from the Supreme Court and en banc activity by the Federal Circuit. The natural reaction is to analyze each doctrinal area involved on its own. However, upon a closer look, many of the cases concern a single, fundamental dispute. Conflicts in opinions on such issues as claim interpretation methodology and the written description requirement are really disagreements as to what exactly is the “invention” the courts should be considering.There are two concepts of invention currently in play in patent decisions. The first is an “external invention” definition, where courts define the invention by the detailed technology discussion in the patent specification’s descriptions and drawings. Other decisions invoke a “claim-centered invention” definition that relies almost exclusively on the claim, a single sentence at the end of the patent. These two definitions can be judged against common patent theories to determine which best fits the theories’ narratives. The external invention definition, by grounding exclusivity around what the inventor has actually done or plans to do, is more likely to cause the patent to operate as these theories assume. And once a definition of invention is selected, doctrinal conflicts and ambiguities are more easily resolvable.
专利法是不断变化的,最近的争议和理论的变化是由最高法院的关注和联邦巡回法院的全院活动推动的。自然的反应是单独分析每一个涉及的教义领域。然而,仔细一看,许多案例涉及一个单一的、基本的争端。在权利要求解释方法和书面描述要求等问题上的意见冲突实际上是对法院应该考虑的“发明”究竟是什么存在分歧。目前在专利决策中有两种发明概念。第一种是“外部发明”定义,法院通过专利说明书的描述和附图中详细的技术讨论来定义发明。其他判决援引了“以权利要求为中心的发明”的定义,这种定义几乎完全依赖于权利要求书,即专利末尾的一句话。这两种定义可以根据常见的专利理论来判断,以确定哪一个最适合理论的叙述。外部发明定义,通过将排他性建立在发明人实际做的或计划做的事情上,更有可能使专利按照这些理论的假设运作。一旦选择了发明的定义,理论冲突和歧义就更容易解决。
{"title":"What is the 'Invention'?","authors":"C. Cotropia","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.1918841","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.1918841","url":null,"abstract":"Patent law is in flux, with recent disputes and change in doctrine fueled by increased attention from the Supreme Court and en banc activity by the Federal Circuit. The natural reaction is to analyze each doctrinal area involved on its own. However, upon a closer look, many of the cases concern a single, fundamental dispute. Conflicts in opinions on such issues as claim interpretation methodology and the written description requirement are really disagreements as to what exactly is the “invention” the courts should be considering.There are two concepts of invention currently in play in patent decisions. The first is an “external invention” definition, where courts define the invention by the detailed technology discussion in the patent specification’s descriptions and drawings. Other decisions invoke a “claim-centered invention” definition that relies almost exclusively on the claim, a single sentence at the end of the patent. These two definitions can be judged against common patent theories to determine which best fits the theories’ narratives. The external invention definition, by grounding exclusivity around what the inventor has actually done or plans to do, is more likely to cause the patent to operate as these theories assume. And once a definition of invention is selected, doctrinal conflicts and ambiguities are more easily resolvable.","PeriodicalId":75324,"journal":{"name":"William and Mary law review","volume":"53 1","pages":"1855"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2011-08-29","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.2139/SSRN.1918841","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"67784487","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4
On the Evasion of Executive Term Limits 论规避行政任期限制
Pub Date : 2011-05-15 DOI: 10.26153/TSW/2241
Tom Ginsburg, J. Melton, Zachary Elkins
Executive term limits are pre-commitments through which the polity restricts its ability to retain a popular executive down the road. In recent years, many presidents around the world have chosen to remain in office even after their initial maximum term in office has expired. They have largely done so by amending the constitution, sometimes by replacing it entirely. The practice of revising higher law for the sake of a particular incumbent raises intriguing issues that touch ultimately on the normative justification for term limits in the first place. This article reviews the normative debate over term limits and identifies the key claims of proponents and opponents. It introduces the idea of characterizing term limits as a variety of default rule to be overcome if sufficient political support is apparent. It then turns to the historical evidence in order to assess the probability of attempts (both successful and unsuccessful) to evade term limits. It finds that, notwithstanding some high profile cases, term limits are observed with remarkable frequency. The final section considers alternative institutional designs that might accomplish some of the goals of term limits, but finds that none is likely to provide a perfect substitute. Term limits have the advantage of clarity, making them relatively easy constitutional rules to enforce, and they should be considered an effective part of the arsenal of democratic institutions.
行政长官任期限制是预先承诺,政府通过它来限制其在未来保留受欢迎的行政长官的能力。近年来,世界各地的许多总统都选择在他们最初的最长任期届满后继续任职。他们主要是通过修改宪法,有时甚至完全取代宪法来实现这一目标。为了某一特定在职者的利益而修改高等法律的做法引发了一些有趣的问题,这些问题最终触及了任期限制的规范性正当性。本文回顾了关于任期限制的规范性辩论,并确定了支持者和反对者的主要主张。它引入了将任期限制定性为在明显有足够政治支持的情况下需要克服的各种默认规则的想法。然后,它转向历史证据,以评估试图(成功和不成功)逃避任期限制的可能性。报告发现,尽管有一些引人注目的案例,但任期限制的发生频率非常高。最后一节考虑了可能实现任期限制的一些目标的其他制度设计,但发现没有一个可能提供完美的替代品。任期限制具有明确的优势,使其相对容易被宪法规定执行,它们应该被视为民主制度武器库的有效组成部分。
{"title":"On the Evasion of Executive Term Limits","authors":"Tom Ginsburg, J. Melton, Zachary Elkins","doi":"10.26153/TSW/2241","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.26153/TSW/2241","url":null,"abstract":"Executive term limits are pre-commitments through which the polity restricts its ability to retain a popular executive down the road. In recent years, many presidents around the world have chosen to remain in office even after their initial maximum term in office has expired. They have largely done so by amending the constitution, sometimes by replacing it entirely. The practice of revising higher law for the sake of a particular incumbent raises intriguing issues that touch ultimately on the normative justification for term limits in the first place. This article reviews the normative debate over term limits and identifies the key claims of proponents and opponents. It introduces the idea of characterizing term limits as a variety of default rule to be overcome if sufficient political support is apparent. It then turns to the historical evidence in order to assess the probability of attempts (both successful and unsuccessful) to evade term limits. It finds that, notwithstanding some high profile cases, term limits are observed with remarkable frequency. The final section considers alternative institutional designs that might accomplish some of the goals of term limits, but finds that none is likely to provide a perfect substitute. Term limits have the advantage of clarity, making them relatively easy constitutional rules to enforce, and they should be considered an effective part of the arsenal of democratic institutions.","PeriodicalId":75324,"journal":{"name":"William and Mary law review","volume":"52 1","pages":"1807-1872"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2011-05-15","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"69258384","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 87
The Structural Role of Private Enforcement Mechanisms in Public Law 私法执行机制在公法中的结构性作用
Pub Date : 2011-02-22 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.1791897
J. Glover
The American regulatory system is unique in that it expressly relies upon a diffuse set of regulators, including private parties, rather than upon a centralized bureaucracy, for the effectuation of its substantive aims. In contrast with more traditional conceptions of private enforcement as an ad hoc supplement to public law, this Article argues that private regulation through litigation is an integral part of the structure of the modern regulatory state. Private litigation and the mechanisms that enable it are not merely add-ons to our regulatory regime, much less are they fundamentally at odds with it. Yet mechanisms of enforcement attendant to private suits are being restricted in numerous ways, and on numerous fronts, in the form of prohibitions on the use of the class action device, the recalibration of procedural mechanisms through private contract to discourage suit, the heightening of pleading standards, and the pre-emption of state law causes of action, just to name a few. Although these restrictions in some instances may provide necessary correctives to the system of private litigation in particular and the functioning of overall regulatory schemes more generally, in their broad-sweeping forms, they threaten to undermine systematically substantive regulatory law. Yet the larger regulatory consequences of these efforts receive inadequate attention.This Article thus offers a more systemic view of these mechanisms of private enforcement by providing elements of a conceptual framework for tailoring mechanisms of private litigation to the contours of particular regulatory regimes. This framework seeks to effectuate and extend the systemic interests in aligning private mechanisms with the regulatory goals of particular areas of substantive law, and at the same time seeks to balance the value of such mechanisms with concerns that they will, in some substantive regimes, generate undesired regulatory consequences. Indeed, this framework highlights the need, in some instances, for limitations on the use of private enforcement mechanisms, as well as the need, in other circumstances, for the creation of new mechanisms that are more carefully calibrated to address potential pathologies. This framework is therefore preferable to one-size-fits-all, abstract approaches to a number of seemingly disparate debates regarding restrictions on private enforcement mechanisms across our legal landscape. By offering a systemic view of various debates about these mechanisms, this framework offers the hope of eventual resolution of these seemingly intractable disputes. This framework also seeks to provide guidance to judges, agencies, and legislatures in the task of tailoring mechanisms of private enforcement to the achievement of public regulatory objectives.
美国监管体系的独特之处在于,它明确地依赖于一组分散的监管机构,包括私人团体,而不是一个集中的官僚机构,以实现其实质性目标。与将私人执行作为公法的特别补充的传统观念相反,本文认为通过诉讼进行的私人监管是现代监管国家结构的一个组成部分。私人诉讼和促成诉讼的机制不仅仅是我们监管制度的附加,更不用说从根本上与之相悖了。然而,私人诉讼的执行机制在许多方面受到限制,在许多方面,以禁止使用集体诉讼手段的形式,通过私人合同重新调整程序机制以阻止诉讼,提高辩护标准,以及优先考虑州法诉讼原因,仅举几例。虽然这些限制在某些情况下可能特别对私人诉讼制度和更普遍的全面管制计划的运作提供必要的纠正,但它们以广泛的形式有可能有步骤地破坏实质性管制法。然而,这些努力带来的更大的监管后果却没有得到足够的重视。因此,本文通过提供一个概念框架的要素,以使私人诉讼机制适应特定监管制度的轮廓,对这些私人执法机制提供了一个更系统的观点。这一框架力求实现和扩大使私人机制与实体法特定领域的监管目标保持一致的系统利益,同时力求平衡这种机制的价值与它们在某些实体法制度中可能产生不希望的监管后果的担忧。的确,这一框架突出表明,在某些情况下,有必要限制使用私人执行机制,在其他情况下,有必要建立新的机制,更仔细地加以校准,以解决潜在的问题。因此,这一框架比一刀切的抽象方法更可取,这些方法涉及我们法律领域中对私人执法机制的限制的许多看似不同的辩论。通过对这些机制的各种争论提供一个系统的观点,这个框架为最终解决这些看似棘手的争端提供了希望。这一框架还试图为法官、机构和立法机构提供指导,使其能够根据实现公共监管目标而调整私人执法机制。
{"title":"The Structural Role of Private Enforcement Mechanisms in Public Law","authors":"J. Glover","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.1791897","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.1791897","url":null,"abstract":"The American regulatory system is unique in that it expressly relies upon a diffuse set of regulators, including private parties, rather than upon a centralized bureaucracy, for the effectuation of its substantive aims. In contrast with more traditional conceptions of private enforcement as an ad hoc supplement to public law, this Article argues that private regulation through litigation is an integral part of the structure of the modern regulatory state. Private litigation and the mechanisms that enable it are not merely add-ons to our regulatory regime, much less are they fundamentally at odds with it. Yet mechanisms of enforcement attendant to private suits are being restricted in numerous ways, and on numerous fronts, in the form of prohibitions on the use of the class action device, the recalibration of procedural mechanisms through private contract to discourage suit, the heightening of pleading standards, and the pre-emption of state law causes of action, just to name a few. Although these restrictions in some instances may provide necessary correctives to the system of private litigation in particular and the functioning of overall regulatory schemes more generally, in their broad-sweeping forms, they threaten to undermine systematically substantive regulatory law. Yet the larger regulatory consequences of these efforts receive inadequate attention.This Article thus offers a more systemic view of these mechanisms of private enforcement by providing elements of a conceptual framework for tailoring mechanisms of private litigation to the contours of particular regulatory regimes. This framework seeks to effectuate and extend the systemic interests in aligning private mechanisms with the regulatory goals of particular areas of substantive law, and at the same time seeks to balance the value of such mechanisms with concerns that they will, in some substantive regimes, generate undesired regulatory consequences. Indeed, this framework highlights the need, in some instances, for limitations on the use of private enforcement mechanisms, as well as the need, in other circumstances, for the creation of new mechanisms that are more carefully calibrated to address potential pathologies. This framework is therefore preferable to one-size-fits-all, abstract approaches to a number of seemingly disparate debates regarding restrictions on private enforcement mechanisms across our legal landscape. By offering a systemic view of various debates about these mechanisms, this framework offers the hope of eventual resolution of these seemingly intractable disputes. This framework also seeks to provide guidance to judges, agencies, and legislatures in the task of tailoring mechanisms of private enforcement to the achievement of public regulatory objectives.","PeriodicalId":75324,"journal":{"name":"William and Mary law review","volume":"53 1","pages":"1137"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2011-02-22","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"67746325","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 31
Original Sin and Judicial Independence: Providing Accountability for Justices 原罪与司法独立:法官问责制
Pub Date : 2009-03-01 DOI: 10.31228/osf.io/ut8je
Paul D. Carrington, R. C. Cramton
TABLE OF CONTENTS I. A DEFINING CHALLENGE A. The Founding Vision 1. The Federalists' "Ark of Safety" B. Removing a Disabled Judge: The Pickering Case C. The Impeachment of Justice Chase: Are Justices Different? 1. How To Remove a Justice CONCLUSION I. A DEFINING CHALLENGE The independence of the judiciary is an enduring and defining objective of the legal profession. We lawyers, of all citizens, have the greatest stake in shielding judges from intimidation or reward. And that task of protecting judicial independence stands today at the very top of the agenda of the American legal profession. (1) The integrity of law and legal institutions requires more than just the protection of judges. It is equally dependent on the willingness and ability of judges to maintain virtuous disinterest in their work. (2) Some might explain their occasional failings as manifestations of the original sin inherited from Adam; (3) whatever their source, the proclivities of judges to indulge or celebrate themselves are perpetual temptations and judicial self-restraint is a perpetual challenge. As Cardozo explained: "The great tides and currents which engulf the rest of men do not turn aside in their course and pass the judges by." (4) A primary and indispensable constraint on those who judge is the moral constraint imposed by the professional community to which they belong. The primary function of transparency in proceedings at trials and arguments, and of published decisions and opinions explicating judges' rulings, is to manifest their disinterest not only to the parties whose contentions they judge, but also to their lawyers, who share responsibility for imposing moral judgment on the professionalism of judges. (5) Judicial disinterest may have been made increasingly difficult in the twentieth century by the replacement of legal formalism with a legal realism that commissions judges to be less constrained by preexisting texts and more attentive to the social consequences of their judgments. (6) A secondary effect may be to inflate the collective vanity of the judiciary. The greater freedom judges assert in taking account of the social consequences of their decisions, the harder it may be for them to lay aside their personal political preferences, the related interests of their friends and allies, and the adoration or hostility of a public that either celebrates or attacks them, depending on the reaction to the policy consequences of their decisions. There is, to be sure, no empirical evidence of this effect, but it is reasonable to suspect that it occurs and contributes to public concerns about possible excesses of judicial independence. As judicial virtue has become more difficult to practice, it has become more in need. The present and rising mistrust of the American judiciary is not a direct consequence of the change in legal philosophy, but there is an obvious connection. As judges have increasingly and openly presumed to shape our polity, citizens who disagree w
目录1.一个决定性的挑战A.创始愿景1。联邦党人的“安全方舟”b罢免残疾法官:皮克林案c弹劾法官蔡斯:法官不同吗?1. 司法独立是法律职业的一个持久和明确的目标。在所有公民中,保护法官不受恐吓或奖励对我们律师最为重要。今天,保护司法独立的任务是美国法律职业议程的重中之重。(1)法律和法律制度的健全需要的不仅仅是对法官的保护。这同样取决于法官是否有意愿和能力在工作中保持无私的美德。有些人可能会把他们偶尔的失败解释为从亚当那里继承来的原罪的表现;(3)无论其来源如何,法官放纵或自我陶醉的倾向是永恒的诱惑,司法自我约束是永恒的挑战。正如卡多佐所解释的那样:“吞没其他人的伟大潮流和潮流不会在他们的过程中转过身来,而忽略了法官。”(4)对法官的主要和必不可少的约束是他们所属的专业团体施加的道德约束。审判和辩论程序的透明度,以及公布的解释法官裁决的决定和意见的透明度,其主要功能是表明他们不仅对他们所评判的当事人不感兴趣,而且对他们的律师也不感兴趣,因为他们有责任对法官的专业精神进行道德判断。(5)在20世纪,由于法律形式主义被法律现实主义所取代,司法公正可能变得越来越困难,因为法律现实主义使法官较少受到先前存在的文本的约束,而更加注意其判决的社会后果。(6)第二个影响可能是使司法机构的集体虚荣心膨胀。法官在考虑其决定的社会后果时主张的自由越大,他们就越难以抛开个人的政治偏好、朋友和盟友的相关利益,以及公众对他们的崇拜或敌意(取决于对其决定的政策后果的反应)。当然,没有经验证据证明这种影响,但有理由怀疑它的发生,并助长了公众对司法独立可能过度的担忧。随着司法德性实践难度的加大,司法德性也变得更加需要。目前对美国司法机构日益增长的不信任并不是法律哲学变化的直接后果,但两者之间存在明显的联系。随着法官越来越公开地认为自己塑造了我们的政治,不同意他们政治立场的公民认为有理由不信任他们的冷漠,并挑战他们的独立性。(7)公民律师在履行审判法官的职责时,也越来越难以保持自己的无私。人类普遍存在的一种弱点是,公民律师倾向于将他们对法官的尊重和支持与他们自己对案件结果和法官决定的政治问题的偏好联系起来。但另一个是对司法不加批判的忠诚。如果这个职业不能批评司法上的不当行为,就会使法官丧失对同行的道德责任感,而这种责任感有时是加强他们了解和约束自己的能力所必需的。明智地审判法官,就像明智地审判案件一样,需要公民律师及其专业组织的自我认识、自律和道德勇气。…
{"title":"Original Sin and Judicial Independence: Providing Accountability for Justices","authors":"Paul D. Carrington, R. C. Cramton","doi":"10.31228/osf.io/ut8je","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.31228/osf.io/ut8je","url":null,"abstract":"TABLE OF CONTENTS I. A DEFINING CHALLENGE A. The Founding Vision 1. The Federalists' \"Ark of Safety\" B. Removing a Disabled Judge: The Pickering Case C. The Impeachment of Justice Chase: Are Justices Different? 1. How To Remove a Justice CONCLUSION I. A DEFINING CHALLENGE The independence of the judiciary is an enduring and defining objective of the legal profession. We lawyers, of all citizens, have the greatest stake in shielding judges from intimidation or reward. And that task of protecting judicial independence stands today at the very top of the agenda of the American legal profession. (1) The integrity of law and legal institutions requires more than just the protection of judges. It is equally dependent on the willingness and ability of judges to maintain virtuous disinterest in their work. (2) Some might explain their occasional failings as manifestations of the original sin inherited from Adam; (3) whatever their source, the proclivities of judges to indulge or celebrate themselves are perpetual temptations and judicial self-restraint is a perpetual challenge. As Cardozo explained: \"The great tides and currents which engulf the rest of men do not turn aside in their course and pass the judges by.\" (4) A primary and indispensable constraint on those who judge is the moral constraint imposed by the professional community to which they belong. The primary function of transparency in proceedings at trials and arguments, and of published decisions and opinions explicating judges' rulings, is to manifest their disinterest not only to the parties whose contentions they judge, but also to their lawyers, who share responsibility for imposing moral judgment on the professionalism of judges. (5) Judicial disinterest may have been made increasingly difficult in the twentieth century by the replacement of legal formalism with a legal realism that commissions judges to be less constrained by preexisting texts and more attentive to the social consequences of their judgments. (6) A secondary effect may be to inflate the collective vanity of the judiciary. The greater freedom judges assert in taking account of the social consequences of their decisions, the harder it may be for them to lay aside their personal political preferences, the related interests of their friends and allies, and the adoration or hostility of a public that either celebrates or attacks them, depending on the reaction to the policy consequences of their decisions. There is, to be sure, no empirical evidence of this effect, but it is reasonable to suspect that it occurs and contributes to public concerns about possible excesses of judicial independence. As judicial virtue has become more difficult to practice, it has become more in need. The present and rising mistrust of the American judiciary is not a direct consequence of the change in legal philosophy, but there is an obvious connection. As judges have increasingly and openly presumed to shape our polity, citizens who disagree w","PeriodicalId":75324,"journal":{"name":"William and Mary law review","volume":"50 1","pages":"1105"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2009-03-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"69640619","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Baghdad, Tokyo, Kabul,...: Constitution Making in Occupied States 巴格达、东京、喀布尔……:占领区的宪法制定
Pub Date : 2007-10-22 DOI: 10.26153/TSW/2249
Zachary Elkins, Tom Ginsburg, J. Melton
We identify and document instances of "occupation constitutions," those drafted under conditions of foreign military occupation. Not every occupation produces a constitution, and it appears that certain occupying powers have a greater propensity to encourage or force a constitution-writing process. We anticipate ex ante that occupation constitutions should be less enduring, and provide some supportive evidence to this effect. Some occupation constitutions do endure, however, and we conduct a case study of the Japanese Constitution of 1946. We argue that it had a self-enforcing quality that has allowed it to endure un-amended for over six decades. Unlike conventional understandings of that document as an American imposition that imposed foreign values, we argue that Japanese participation in the adoption process, and familiarity with some of the rights provisions that had already appeared in the Meiji Constitution, helped make the document self-enforcing. Most important of all, however, was that it embodied a political bargain that fit the basic cleavages in Japanese society.
我们查明并记录“占领宪法”的实例,即在外国军事占领条件下起草的宪法。并不是每一次占领都会产生一部宪法,而且某些占领国似乎更倾向于鼓励或强制制定宪法。我们事先预计,占领宪法应该不那么持久,并为此提供一些支持性证据。然而,一些占领宪法确实存在,我们对1946年的日本宪法进行了案例研究。我们认为,它具有一种自我执行的性质,使它能够在六十多年的时间里不加修改。与将该文件视为美国强加外国价值观的传统理解不同,我们认为,日本参与了采纳过程,并熟悉明治宪法中已经出现的一些权利条款,有助于使该文件具有自我执行力。然而,最重要的是,它体现了一种符合日本社会基本分裂的政治交易。
{"title":"Baghdad, Tokyo, Kabul,...: Constitution Making in Occupied States","authors":"Zachary Elkins, Tom Ginsburg, J. Melton","doi":"10.26153/TSW/2249","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.26153/TSW/2249","url":null,"abstract":"We identify and document instances of \"occupation constitutions,\" those drafted under conditions of foreign military occupation. Not every occupation produces a constitution, and it appears that certain occupying powers have a greater propensity to encourage or force a constitution-writing process. We anticipate ex ante that occupation constitutions should be less enduring, and provide some supportive evidence to this effect. Some occupation constitutions do endure, however, and we conduct a case study of the Japanese Constitution of 1946. We argue that it had a self-enforcing quality that has allowed it to endure un-amended for over six decades. Unlike conventional understandings of that document as an American imposition that imposed foreign values, we argue that Japanese participation in the adoption process, and familiarity with some of the rights provisions that had already appeared in the Meiji Constitution, helped make the document self-enforcing. Most important of all, however, was that it embodied a political bargain that fit the basic cleavages in Japanese society.","PeriodicalId":75324,"journal":{"name":"William and Mary law review","volume":"49 1","pages":"1139"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2007-10-22","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"69258428","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 25
Political Judges and Popular Justice: A Conservative Victory or a Conservative Dilemma? 政治法官与人民正义:保守党的胜利还是保守党的困境?
Pub Date : 2007-10-10 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.1008952
George D. Brown
Most of the judges in America are elected. Yet the institution of the elected judiciary is in trouble, perhaps in crisis. The pressures of campaigning, particularly raising money, have produced an intensity of electioneering that many observers see as damaging to the institution itself. In an extraordinary development, four justices of the Supreme Court recently expressed concern over possible loss of trust in state judicial systems. Yet mechanisms that states have put in place to strike a balance between the accountability values of an elected judiciary and rule of law values of unbiased adjudication are increasingly invalidated by the federal courts. This article presents an argument against this transformation of the American judiciary. It is aimed at conservatives, for they are the driving force in the movement to make campaigns for judicial offices exactly like campaigns for other "political" offices. I seek to establish, as a matter of policy, that conservative principles argue for a presumption against politicization. I review the judicial "parity" debate, and conclude that conservatives have a tremendous stake in the health and viability of state courts - and in perceptions of the quality of those courts. Broader issues of federalism are at stake as well - particularly the "laboratory" value of state experimentation in seeking the optimal balance between accountability and rule of law values. With this policy perspective in place, the article then examines the Supreme Court decision in Republican Party of Minnesota v. White, the major victory for the pro-politicization position. I argue that White rests on flawed premises and should be narrowly construed.
美国的大多数法官都是选举产生的。然而,选举产生的司法机构正陷入困境,甚至可能陷入危机。竞选活动的压力,尤其是筹集资金的压力,已经产生了一种激烈的竞选活动,许多观察人士认为,这对该机构本身是有害的。最近,最高法院的四名法官对人们可能对州司法系统失去信任表示担忧,这是一个不同寻常的进展。然而,各州为在民选司法机构的问责价值观和公正裁决的法治价值观之间取得平衡而建立的机制,正日益被联邦法院推翻。本文对美国司法体制的这种转变提出了反对意见。它的目标是保守派,因为他们是这场运动的推动力,使司法职位的竞选活动与其他“政治”职位的竞选活动完全一样。作为一项政策,我试图确立,保守主义原则主张反对政治化的假设。我回顾了关于司法“平等”的辩论,并得出结论:保守派对州法院的健康和生存能力——以及对这些法院质量的看法——有着巨大的利害关系。联邦制更广泛的问题也处于危险之中——尤其是寻求问责制和法治价值之间最佳平衡的国家实验的“实验室”价值。从这一政策角度出发,本文接着考察了最高法院在明尼苏达州共和党诉怀特案中的判决,这是亲政治化立场的重大胜利。我认为怀特建立在有缺陷的前提上,应该被狭义地解释。
{"title":"Political Judges and Popular Justice: A Conservative Victory or a Conservative Dilemma?","authors":"George D. Brown","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.1008952","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1008952","url":null,"abstract":"Most of the judges in America are elected. Yet the institution of the elected judiciary is in trouble, perhaps in crisis. The pressures of campaigning, particularly raising money, have produced an intensity of electioneering that many observers see as damaging to the institution itself. In an extraordinary development, four justices of the Supreme Court recently expressed concern over possible loss of trust in state judicial systems. Yet mechanisms that states have put in place to strike a balance between the accountability values of an elected judiciary and rule of law values of unbiased adjudication are increasingly invalidated by the federal courts. This article presents an argument against this transformation of the American judiciary. It is aimed at conservatives, for they are the driving force in the movement to make campaigns for judicial offices exactly like campaigns for other \"political\" offices. I seek to establish, as a matter of policy, that conservative principles argue for a presumption against politicization. I review the judicial \"parity\" debate, and conclude that conservatives have a tremendous stake in the health and viability of state courts - and in perceptions of the quality of those courts. Broader issues of federalism are at stake as well - particularly the \"laboratory\" value of state experimentation in seeking the optimal balance between accountability and rule of law values. With this policy perspective in place, the article then examines the Supreme Court decision in Republican Party of Minnesota v. White, the major victory for the pro-politicization position. I argue that White rests on flawed premises and should be narrowly construed.","PeriodicalId":75324,"journal":{"name":"William and Mary law review","volume":"49 1","pages":"1543-1620"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2007-10-10","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68123242","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Inefficient Customs in International Law 国际法中的低效海关
Pub Date : 2007-03-01 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.969831
E. Kontorovich
This Article explores whether and when rules of customary international law (CIL) can be expected to be efficient. Customary rules are often regarded as desirable because in certain circumstances, they promote the welfare of the group in which they arise. Unless these circumstances apply among states, the efficiency arguments for the legalization of customary norms do not apply. The Article takes as its central observation the divergent treatment of custom in domestic and international law. In international law, if a customary behavior of states can be identified, it is automatically elevated to the status of legal obligation without any independent examination of whether the custom is a good one. International custom is customary international law. This reification of custom is in marked contrast to the treatment of custom in private law. No one doubts that customary behaviors exist in various societal subgroups, but tort law does not assume that customs are normatively desirable, and does not automatically transform customs into legally binding obligations. Thus tort law does not take custom to dictate the standard of care; the fact-finder must independently determine whether the practice is efficient, though its customary status has some positive evidentiary value. Law and economics scholars have varied views about whether custom is presumptively efficient in the private law context. The most optimistic view holds that private custom will generally be welfare enhancing, and thus courts should give legal recognition to such practices. Yet even the optimistic view holds that efficient custom would only arise in certain circumstances: when there are thickly repeated dealings between members of an insular, homogenous group whose members play reciprocal roles. The Article takes these earmarks of efficient custom and examines whether they apply to international custom. It finds that much of international custom should not be expected to be efficient even in the most optimistic view of custom. Some areas of CIL, like diplomatic privileges, might satisfy efficient custom criteria. This suggests that, contrary to current practice, CIL should not be treated as one undifferentiated phenomenon. Rather, the standards for establishing a CIL norm should vary across different substantive contexts and different groups of states.
本文探讨习惯国际法规则是否有效以及何时有效。习惯规则通常被认为是可取的,因为在某些情况下,它们促进了产生习惯规则的群体的福利。除非这些情况适用于国家之间,否则将习惯规范合法化的效率论点就不适用。本文以国内法与国际法对习惯的不同对待为中心。在国际法中,如果一个国家的习惯行为可以被识别,它就会自动被提升到法律义务的地位,而不需要对该习惯是否良好进行任何独立的审查。国际惯例是国际习惯法。这种对习惯的物化与私法中对习惯的处理形成了鲜明的对比。没有人怀疑习惯行为存在于不同的社会子群体中,但侵权法并不假设习惯在规范上是可取的,也不会自动将习惯转化为具有法律约束力的义务。因此,侵权行为法不以习惯来规定注意标准;事实发现者必须独立地确定实践是否有效,尽管其习惯地位具有一定的积极证据价值。在私法背景下,习惯法是否具有假定的效率,法律和经济学学者的观点各不相同。最乐观的观点认为,私人习俗通常会增加福利,因此法院应该在法律上承认这种做法。然而,即使是乐观的观点也认为,有效的习俗只会在某些情况下出现:当一个孤立的、同质的群体的成员之间存在大量重复的交易时,这些群体的成员扮演着相互的角色。本文以有效海关的这些特征为例,考察其是否适用于国际海关。报告发现,即使从最乐观的角度来看,许多国际惯例也不应该被期望是有效的。在某些领域,例如外交特权,可能会满足有效的海关标准。这表明,与目前的做法相反,不应将CIL视为一种无差别的现象。相反,建立CIL规范的标准应根据不同的实质性背景和不同的国家群体而有所不同。
{"title":"Inefficient Customs in International Law","authors":"E. Kontorovich","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.969831","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.969831","url":null,"abstract":"This Article explores whether and when rules of customary international law (CIL) can be expected to be efficient. Customary rules are often regarded as desirable because in certain circumstances, they promote the welfare of the group in which they arise. Unless these circumstances apply among states, the efficiency arguments for the legalization of customary norms do not apply. The Article takes as its central observation the divergent treatment of custom in domestic and international law. In international law, if a customary behavior of states can be identified, it is automatically elevated to the status of legal obligation without any independent examination of whether the custom is a good one. International custom is customary international law. This reification of custom is in marked contrast to the treatment of custom in private law. No one doubts that customary behaviors exist in various societal subgroups, but tort law does not assume that customs are normatively desirable, and does not automatically transform customs into legally binding obligations. Thus tort law does not take custom to dictate the standard of care; the fact-finder must independently determine whether the practice is efficient, though its customary status has some positive evidentiary value. Law and economics scholars have varied views about whether custom is presumptively efficient in the private law context. The most optimistic view holds that private custom will generally be welfare enhancing, and thus courts should give legal recognition to such practices. Yet even the optimistic view holds that efficient custom would only arise in certain circumstances: when there are thickly repeated dealings between members of an insular, homogenous group whose members play reciprocal roles. The Article takes these earmarks of efficient custom and examines whether they apply to international custom. It finds that much of international custom should not be expected to be efficient even in the most optimistic view of custom. Some areas of CIL, like diplomatic privileges, might satisfy efficient custom criteria. This suggests that, contrary to current practice, CIL should not be treated as one undifferentiated phenomenon. Rather, the standards for establishing a CIL norm should vary across different substantive contexts and different groups of states.","PeriodicalId":75324,"journal":{"name":"William and Mary law review","volume":"48 1","pages":"859-922"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2007-03-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.2139/SSRN.969831","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"67915632","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
期刊
William and Mary law review
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1