首页 > 最新文献

Manufacturing & Service Operations Management最新文献

英文 中文
Primary Care First Initiative: Impact on Care Delivery and Outcomes 初级保健第一倡议:对护理提供和结果的影响
Pub Date : 2023-04-03 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2023.1207
Elodie Adida, Fernanda Bravo
Problem definition: The Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services launched the Primary Care First (PCF) initiative in January 2021. The initiative builds upon prior innovative payment models and aims at incentivizing a redesign of primary care delivery, including new modes of delivery, such as remote care. To achieve this goal, the initiative blends capitation and fee-for-service (FFS) payments and includes performance-based adjustments linked to service quality and health outcomes. We analyze a model motivated by this new payment system, and its impact on the different stakeholders, and derive insights on how to design it to reach the best possible outcome. Methodology/results: We propose an analytical model that captures patient heterogeneity in terms of health complexity, provider choice of care-delivery mode (referral to a specialist, in-person visit, or remote care), and quality of service (health outcomes and wait time). We analyze the provider decision on the mode of care delivery under both FFS and PCF and study whether PCF can be designed to yield a socially optimal outcome. We characterize analytically when patients, payer, and providers are better off under PCF and show that, in many cases, PCF can be designed to yield a socially optimal outcome. We numerically calibrate our model for 14 states in the United States. We observe that the average health status in a state is a source of heterogeneity that crucially drives the performance of PCF. We find that the model motivated by the current PCF implementation results in too much adoption of referral care and too little adoption of remote care. In addition, states with poor average health status may use more in-person care than socially optimal under a baseline (low) level of capitation. Moreover, relying on high levels of capitation leads to low adoption of in-person care. Managerial implications: Our results have health policy implications by shedding light on how PCF might impact patients, payer, and providers. Under the current performance-based adjustments, low levels of capitation should be preferred. PCF has the potential to be designed to achieve socially optimal outcomes. However, the fee per visit may need to be tailored to the local population’s health status. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1207 .
问题定义:医疗保险和医疗补助服务中心于2021年1月启动了初级保健优先(PCF)计划。该倡议以以前的创新支付模式为基础,旨在鼓励重新设计初级保健服务,包括新的提供模式,如远程保健。为实现这一目标,该倡议将按人头支付和按服务收费(FFS)相结合,并包括与服务质量和健康结果相关的基于绩效的调整。我们分析了由这种新的支付系统驱动的模型,以及它对不同利益相关者的影响,并得出如何设计它以达到最佳结果的见解。方法/结果:我们提出了一个分析模型,该模型捕捉了患者在健康复杂性、提供者选择的护理提供模式(转介给专家、亲自就诊或远程护理)和服务质量(健康结果和等待时间)方面的异质性。我们分析了在FFS和PCF下提供者对护理提供模式的决策,并研究了PCF是否可以设计为产生社会最优结果。我们分析了在PCF下患者、支付方和提供者的情况,并表明在许多情况下,PCF可以设计为产生社会最优结果。我们对美国14个州的模型进行了数值校准。我们观察到,一个州的平均健康状态是异质性的来源,这对PCF的性能至关重要。我们发现,由当前PCF实施驱动的模型导致转诊护理的采用过多,而远程护理的采用过少。此外,平均健康状况较差的州可能比基线(低)人均水平下的社会最佳护理使用更多的面对面护理。此外,依赖于高水平的人头导致很少采用亲自护理。管理意义:通过揭示PCF如何影响患者、付款人和提供者,我们的结果具有卫生政策意义。根据目前基于业绩的调整,应优先考虑低水平的人均收入。PCF有可能被设计成实现社会最优结果。但是,每次就诊的费用可能需要根据当地人口的健康状况进行调整。补充材料:在线附录可在https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1207上获得。
{"title":"Primary Care First Initiative: Impact on Care Delivery and Outcomes","authors":"Elodie Adida, Fernanda Bravo","doi":"10.1287/msom.2023.1207","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1207","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: The Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services launched the Primary Care First (PCF) initiative in January 2021. The initiative builds upon prior innovative payment models and aims at incentivizing a redesign of primary care delivery, including new modes of delivery, such as remote care. To achieve this goal, the initiative blends capitation and fee-for-service (FFS) payments and includes performance-based adjustments linked to service quality and health outcomes. We analyze a model motivated by this new payment system, and its impact on the different stakeholders, and derive insights on how to design it to reach the best possible outcome. Methodology/results: We propose an analytical model that captures patient heterogeneity in terms of health complexity, provider choice of care-delivery mode (referral to a specialist, in-person visit, or remote care), and quality of service (health outcomes and wait time). We analyze the provider decision on the mode of care delivery under both FFS and PCF and study whether PCF can be designed to yield a socially optimal outcome. We characterize analytically when patients, payer, and providers are better off under PCF and show that, in many cases, PCF can be designed to yield a socially optimal outcome. We numerically calibrate our model for 14 states in the United States. We observe that the average health status in a state is a source of heterogeneity that crucially drives the performance of PCF. We find that the model motivated by the current PCF implementation results in too much adoption of referral care and too little adoption of remote care. In addition, states with poor average health status may use more in-person care than socially optimal under a baseline (low) level of capitation. Moreover, relying on high levels of capitation leads to low adoption of in-person care. Managerial implications: Our results have health policy implications by shedding light on how PCF might impact patients, payer, and providers. Under the current performance-based adjustments, low levels of capitation should be preferred. PCF has the potential to be designed to achieve socially optimal outcomes. However, the fee per visit may need to be tailored to the local population’s health status. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1207 .","PeriodicalId":119284,"journal":{"name":"Manufacturing & Service Operations Management","volume":"42 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-04-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"124531989","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Managing Customer Search: Assortment Planning for a Subscription Box Service 管理客户搜索:订阅箱服务的分类规划
Pub Date : 2023-03-27 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2023.1204
Fernando Bernstein, Yuan Guo
Problem definition: This paper focuses on subscription box services in which a provider selects the assortment of products to include in the box by taking into account the customer’s preferences. Customers interested in purchasing a product choose between engaging in active search (i.e., visit physical stores) or subscribing to a box delivery service. We study the subscription box company’s problem of selecting the optimal contents of the box to maximize expected revenue (by driving demand from customers). Methodology/results: Because a product may be both available at a store and included in the box, the assortment in a box affects the set of stores that a customer would visit under active search and, therefore, the customer’s subscription decision. We model such interaction by applying a cross-nested logit framework that correlates the contents in the box with the products available at the stores. We find that the box should include a collection of popular subsets of the store products for customers that experience a relatively low or relatively high search cost. If a preview of the box is available, we find that, for customers with intermediate values of the search cost, it may be optimal to include a so-called utility loss leader, that is, a product with relatively low valuation, to entice customers to subscribe to the box delivery service and therefore increase the likelihood of a sale. We use rational expectations to model a setting in which a preview of the box is not available. In such cases, it is never optimal to include a utility loss leader in the box. Managerial implications: Our model captures the impact of product overlap across different shopping channels on customer choice and the subscription box company assortment decision. We derive insights on how the subscription service provider should determine the contents of the box in anticipation of the customer’s search behavior. We also examine the decision of offering exclusive products in addition to branded items. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1204 .
问题定义:本文关注订阅盒服务,其中提供商通过考虑客户的偏好来选择要包含在订阅盒中的产品分类。对购买产品感兴趣的客户可以在主动搜索(即访问实体店)或订阅快递服务之间进行选择。我们研究了订阅盒公司选择最佳内容以最大化预期收入的问题(通过驱动客户需求)。方法/结果:因为产品可能在商店中可用,也可能包含在盒子中,所以盒子中的分类会影响客户在主动搜索下访问的商店集,从而影响客户的订阅决策。我们通过应用一个交叉嵌套的logit框架来为这种交互建模,该框架将盒子中的内容与商店中可用的产品关联起来。我们发现,对于搜索成本相对较低或较高的客户,该盒子应该包含商店产品的热门子集的集合。如果可以获得盒子的预览,我们发现,对于搜索成本处于中间值的客户来说,包含所谓的效用损失领导者(即估值相对较低的产品)可能是最优的,以吸引客户订阅盒子交付服务,从而增加销售的可能性。我们使用理性期望来模拟无法获得预览框的设置。在这种情况下,在盒子里加入公用事业损失引线从来都不是最佳选择。管理意义:我们的模型捕捉了不同购物渠道的产品重叠对客户选择和订阅箱公司分类决策的影响。我们得出了订阅服务提供商应该如何根据客户的搜索行为来确定盒子内容的见解。我们还研究了除了品牌商品外提供独家产品的决定。补充材料:在线附录可在https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1204上获得。
{"title":"Managing Customer Search: Assortment Planning for a Subscription Box Service","authors":"Fernando Bernstein, Yuan Guo","doi":"10.1287/msom.2023.1204","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1204","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: This paper focuses on subscription box services in which a provider selects the assortment of products to include in the box by taking into account the customer’s preferences. Customers interested in purchasing a product choose between engaging in active search (i.e., visit physical stores) or subscribing to a box delivery service. We study the subscription box company’s problem of selecting the optimal contents of the box to maximize expected revenue (by driving demand from customers). Methodology/results: Because a product may be both available at a store and included in the box, the assortment in a box affects the set of stores that a customer would visit under active search and, therefore, the customer’s subscription decision. We model such interaction by applying a cross-nested logit framework that correlates the contents in the box with the products available at the stores. We find that the box should include a collection of popular subsets of the store products for customers that experience a relatively low or relatively high search cost. If a preview of the box is available, we find that, for customers with intermediate values of the search cost, it may be optimal to include a so-called utility loss leader, that is, a product with relatively low valuation, to entice customers to subscribe to the box delivery service and therefore increase the likelihood of a sale. We use rational expectations to model a setting in which a preview of the box is not available. In such cases, it is never optimal to include a utility loss leader in the box. Managerial implications: Our model captures the impact of product overlap across different shopping channels on customer choice and the subscription box company assortment decision. We derive insights on how the subscription service provider should determine the contents of the box in anticipation of the customer’s search behavior. We also examine the decision of offering exclusive products in addition to branded items. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1204 .","PeriodicalId":119284,"journal":{"name":"Manufacturing & Service Operations Management","volume":"61 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-03-27","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"121194077","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Retail Sample Boxes: Counteracting the Adverse Effect of Accelerated Learning via Future Credit 零售样盒:通过未来信用抵消加速学习的不利影响
Pub Date : 2023-03-23 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2023.1206
Alireza Yazdani, E. Çil, Michael S. Pangburn
Problem definition: Consumers often try a few varieties of an experience product before establishing a shopping routine. In retailing, a sample box typically refers to a package of multiple trial-sized varieties within a product category. Sample boxes potentially create value by helping consumers resolve their uncertainties regarding these varieties earlier and at a lower cost. In this paper, we study how firms and consumers share this added value under different market scenarios. We also derive the optimal pricing of sample boxes in product categories for which consumers make ongoing purchases over time. Academic/practical relevance: We thus extend the literature by proposing a framework that integrates sequential search and seller-induced learning. Methodology: We analyze a firm’s pricing decisions when consumers either purchase full-sized options sequentially or bypass that process via a sample box. We use dynamic programming to analyze consumers’ search problem (in the absence of a sample box) and nonlinear optimization to analyze the firm’s problem. Results: As anticipated, the informational value of a sample box yields an optimal price premium relative to the prices of individual products. Despite this price premium, we show that the firm’s expected profit may decrease because a sample box accelerates consumer learning, and thus, it may help consumers settle upon an outside option earlier. We establish that a firm can reverse the potential adverse profit impact of selling sample boxes by introducing an optimally specified future credit. Managerial implications: Offering sample boxes is a common practice in retailing. Contrasting the resulting expected profits with and without the sample box option, our results highlight that managers may be ill-advised to offer a sample box in the absence of the future credit mechanism. This study is the first to address the pricing of sample boxes and show the optimality of offering credit toward a subsequent purchase. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1206 .
问题定义:消费者在建立购物习惯之前,通常会尝试几种不同的体验产品。在零售业中,样品盒通常是指一个产品类别中包含多个试用大小的品种的包装。样品盒通过帮助消费者以更低的成本更早地解决他们对这些品种的不确定性,从而潜在地创造价值。本文研究了在不同的市场情景下,企业和消费者如何分享这一附加价值。我们还推导出消费者在一段时间内持续购买的产品类别中样品盒的最优定价。学术/实践相关性:因此,我们通过提出一个整合顺序搜索和卖方诱导学习的框架来扩展文献。方法:我们分析了当消费者依次购买全尺寸期权或通过样品盒绕过该过程时,公司的定价决策。我们使用动态规划分析消费者的搜索问题(在没有样本盒的情况下),并使用非线性优化分析企业的问题。结果:正如预期的那样,样本盒的信息价值相对于单个产品的价格产生了最优的价格溢价。尽管存在这种价格溢价,但我们表明,公司的预期利润可能会下降,因为样品盒加速了消费者的学习,因此,它可能有助于消费者更早地选择外部选项。我们建立了一个公司可以扭转销售样品盒的潜在不利的利润影响,通过引入一个最优指定的未来信贷。管理启示:提供样品盒是零售业的常见做法。对比有和没有样本箱选项的预期利润,我们的结果强调,在缺乏未来信用机制的情况下,管理者提供样本箱可能是不明智的。这项研究是第一个解决样品盒的定价问题,并展示了为后续购买提供信贷的最优性。补充材料:在线附录可在https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1206上获得。
{"title":"Retail Sample Boxes: Counteracting the Adverse Effect of Accelerated Learning via Future Credit","authors":"Alireza Yazdani, E. Çil, Michael S. Pangburn","doi":"10.1287/msom.2023.1206","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1206","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: Consumers often try a few varieties of an experience product before establishing a shopping routine. In retailing, a sample box typically refers to a package of multiple trial-sized varieties within a product category. Sample boxes potentially create value by helping consumers resolve their uncertainties regarding these varieties earlier and at a lower cost. In this paper, we study how firms and consumers share this added value under different market scenarios. We also derive the optimal pricing of sample boxes in product categories for which consumers make ongoing purchases over time. Academic/practical relevance: We thus extend the literature by proposing a framework that integrates sequential search and seller-induced learning. Methodology: We analyze a firm’s pricing decisions when consumers either purchase full-sized options sequentially or bypass that process via a sample box. We use dynamic programming to analyze consumers’ search problem (in the absence of a sample box) and nonlinear optimization to analyze the firm’s problem. Results: As anticipated, the informational value of a sample box yields an optimal price premium relative to the prices of individual products. Despite this price premium, we show that the firm’s expected profit may decrease because a sample box accelerates consumer learning, and thus, it may help consumers settle upon an outside option earlier. We establish that a firm can reverse the potential adverse profit impact of selling sample boxes by introducing an optimally specified future credit. Managerial implications: Offering sample boxes is a common practice in retailing. Contrasting the resulting expected profits with and without the sample box option, our results highlight that managers may be ill-advised to offer a sample box in the absence of the future credit mechanism. This study is the first to address the pricing of sample boxes and show the optimality of offering credit toward a subsequent purchase. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1206 .","PeriodicalId":119284,"journal":{"name":"Manufacturing & Service Operations Management","volume":"12 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-03-23","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"133183494","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
“I Quit”: Schedule Volatility as a Driver of Voluntary Employee Turnover “我辞职”:日程波动是员工自愿离职的驱动因素
Pub Date : 2023-03-15 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2023.1205
A. Bergman, G. David, Hummy Song
Problem definition: Employers across many sectors of the economy have been fast to adopt variable work scheduling policies. The cost of this flexibility for employers is usually borne by employees, for whom unstable work schedules create several disruptions. In the context of home healthcare, we examine how employer-driven volatility in nurses’ schedules impacts their decision to voluntarily leave their job. Methodology/results: Using an instrumental variables approach, we causally identify the effect of schedule volatility on nurses’ voluntary turnover. We begin by constructing an operational measure of schedule volatility using time-stamped work log data from one of the largest home health agencies in the United States. Because this measure may be endogenous to the worker’s decision to quit, we instrument for schedule volatility using paid days off taken by other nurses in the same branch. We find that higher levels of schedule volatility substantially increase a worker’s likelihood of quitting. Specifically, a one-standard-deviation increase in schedule volatility increases the average worker’s propensity to quit on a given day by more than threefold. Translated into yearly terms, 30 days of high schedule volatility over the course of the year increases the average worker’s probability of quitting that year by 20%. Our policy simulations of counterfactual scheduling policies suggest that excess schedule volatility can explain a significant portion of voluntary turnover, and some interventions have the potential to substantially reduce workers’ daily propensity to quit. Managerial implications: This work contributes to the understanding of the extent to which employees value control over their own work schedules and are averse to volatile work schedules that are dictated by employers. Especially in the current environment where there is a growing emphasis on work-life balance and employee-driven flexibility, finding a way to support stable schedules could be important for employers to attract and retain workers. Funding: This work was supported by the National Research Service Award Postdoctoral Fellowship, the Wharton Dean's Research Fund, the Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality [T32 Grant 5T32HS26116], and the Claude Marion Endowed Faculty Scholar Award. Supplemental Material: The e-companion is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1205 .
问题定义:经济中许多部门的雇主都在迅速采用可变的工作安排政策。对雇主来说,这种灵活性的成本通常由雇员承担,对他们来说,不稳定的工作时间表会造成一些干扰。在家庭医疗保健的背景下,我们研究了雇主驱动的护士时间表波动如何影响他们自愿离职的决定。方法/结果:使用工具变量方法,我们确定了时间表波动对护士自愿离职的影响。我们首先使用来自美国最大的家庭健康机构之一的带时间戳的工作日志数据构建一个时间表波动性的操作度量。由于这一措施可能是工人决定辞职的内生因素,我们使用同一分支中其他护士的带薪休假来测量时间表的波动性。我们发现,较高水平的时间表波动性大大增加了员工辞职的可能性。具体来说,工作日程的波动性每增加一个标准偏差,员工在某一天的辞职倾向就会增加三倍以上。按年计算,如果一年中有30天的工作日程高度不稳定,那么普通员工当年辞职的可能性会增加20%。我们对反事实调度政策的政策模拟表明,过度的调度波动可以解释自愿离职的很大一部分,一些干预措施有可能大大降低工人的日常辞职倾向。管理意义:这项工作有助于理解员工在多大程度上重视控制自己的工作时间表,并反对雇主规定的不稳定的工作时间表。尤其是在当前的环境中,人们越来越强调工作与生活的平衡和员工驱动的灵活性,找到一种方法来支持稳定的时间表对雇主吸引和留住员工可能很重要。资助:本研究得到了国家研究服务奖博士后奖学金、沃顿商学院院长研究基金、美国医疗保健研究与质量局[T32 Grant 5T32HS26116]和克劳德·马里恩捐赠教师学者奖的支持。补充材料:电子伴侣可在https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1205上获得。
{"title":"“I Quit”: Schedule Volatility as a Driver of Voluntary Employee Turnover","authors":"A. Bergman, G. David, Hummy Song","doi":"10.1287/msom.2023.1205","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1205","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: Employers across many sectors of the economy have been fast to adopt variable work scheduling policies. The cost of this flexibility for employers is usually borne by employees, for whom unstable work schedules create several disruptions. In the context of home healthcare, we examine how employer-driven volatility in nurses’ schedules impacts their decision to voluntarily leave their job. Methodology/results: Using an instrumental variables approach, we causally identify the effect of schedule volatility on nurses’ voluntary turnover. We begin by constructing an operational measure of schedule volatility using time-stamped work log data from one of the largest home health agencies in the United States. Because this measure may be endogenous to the worker’s decision to quit, we instrument for schedule volatility using paid days off taken by other nurses in the same branch. We find that higher levels of schedule volatility substantially increase a worker’s likelihood of quitting. Specifically, a one-standard-deviation increase in schedule volatility increases the average worker’s propensity to quit on a given day by more than threefold. Translated into yearly terms, 30 days of high schedule volatility over the course of the year increases the average worker’s probability of quitting that year by 20%. Our policy simulations of counterfactual scheduling policies suggest that excess schedule volatility can explain a significant portion of voluntary turnover, and some interventions have the potential to substantially reduce workers’ daily propensity to quit. Managerial implications: This work contributes to the understanding of the extent to which employees value control over their own work schedules and are averse to volatile work schedules that are dictated by employers. Especially in the current environment where there is a growing emphasis on work-life balance and employee-driven flexibility, finding a way to support stable schedules could be important for employers to attract and retain workers. Funding: This work was supported by the National Research Service Award Postdoctoral Fellowship, the Wharton Dean's Research Fund, the Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality [T32 Grant 5T32HS26116], and the Claude Marion Endowed Faculty Scholar Award. Supplemental Material: The e-companion is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1205 .","PeriodicalId":119284,"journal":{"name":"Manufacturing & Service Operations Management","volume":"206 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-03-15","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"123445790","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Competition and Collaboration on Fundraising for Short-Term Disaster Response: The Impact on Earmarking and Performance 短期救灾筹款的竞争与合作:对指定用途和绩效的影响
Pub Date : 2023-03-15 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2023.1202
A. Aflaki, Alfonso J. Pedraza-Martinez
Problem definition: Most humanitarian organizations (HOs) allow donors to earmark their donations (i.e., designate their contributions to a specific purpose). Allowing earmarking may increase donations; however, it creates operational inefficiencies that undermine the impact of those donations. Extant literature has mainly studied earmarking and its operational consequences in the absence of funding competition. We examine how competition for funding impacts earmarking decisions, fundraising costs, and HO performance in short-term disaster response. In addition to the competition model, we analyze two collaborative fundraising models: (i) full collaboration, where HOs contact donors as a unit and donors cannot donate to specific HOs on the fundraiser, and (ii) partial collaboration, where HOs contact donors as a unit and donors choose among the contacting HOs. Methodology: We use game theory to model the interactions between multiple HOs and a market of donors and build a multinomial logit model for the donor choice problem. Results: We find that competition for funding contributes to the prevalence of earmarked donations, increases fundraising costs, and hurts HO performance and utility. We show that two collaborative fundraising models can mitigate these issues depending on the availability of funding resources. When funding is abundant, full collaboration improves HO utility and reduces earmarking and fundraising costs. When funding is scarce, partial collaboration reduces fundraising costs and improves performance and HO utility. When funding is intermediate, these two forms of collaboration do not necessarily benefit HOs. Managerial implications: We illustrate how funding availability drives earmarking and fundraising decisions and key performance metrics of different funding models during short-term disaster response. Using data from the 2010 Haiti earthquake, our numerical study indicates that partial collaboration benefits response to disasters with funding shortage, whereas full collaboration suits disaster response with sufficient funding. HOs competing for funds can use our insights to improve their response effectiveness. Supplemental Material: The e-companion is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1202 .
问题定义:大多数人道主义组织允许捐助者指定其捐款(即指定其捐款用于特定目的)。允许指定用途可能会增加捐款;然而,它造成了运作效率低下,破坏了这些捐赠的影响。现有文献主要研究了在缺乏资金竞争的情况下指定用途及其操作后果。我们研究了资金竞争如何影响指定用途决策、筹资成本和世卫组织在短期灾害应对中的表现。除了竞争模式外,我们分析了两种合作筹款模式:(i)完全合作模式,即居屋以单位联系捐赠者,捐赠者不能在筹款活动中向特定的居屋捐款;(ii)部分合作模式,即居屋以单位联系捐赠者,捐赠者在联系的居屋中选择。方法:运用博弈论的方法对多个医院与供体市场之间的相互作用进行建模,建立了供体选择问题的多项逻辑模型。结果:我们发现,资金竞争导致了专项捐赠的盛行,增加了筹款成本,损害了卫生组织的绩效和效用。我们表明,根据资金资源的可用性,两种协作筹款模式可以缓解这些问题。当资金充足时,充分合作可以提高世卫组织的效用,减少指定用途和筹资成本。当资金短缺时,部分合作可以降低筹资成本,提高绩效和HO效用。如果资助是中间的,这两种形式的合作不一定对居屋有利。管理意义:我们说明了资金可用性如何驱动指定用途和筹款决策,以及短期灾害响应期间不同融资模式的关键绩效指标。利用2010年海地地震的数据,我们的数值研究表明,部分合作有利于应对资金短缺的灾害,而全面合作则适合应对资金充足的灾害。争夺资金的院舍可以利用我们的见解来提高其应对效率。补充材料:电子伴侣可在https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1202上获得。
{"title":"Competition and Collaboration on Fundraising for Short-Term Disaster Response: The Impact on Earmarking and Performance","authors":"A. Aflaki, Alfonso J. Pedraza-Martinez","doi":"10.1287/msom.2023.1202","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1202","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: Most humanitarian organizations (HOs) allow donors to earmark their donations (i.e., designate their contributions to a specific purpose). Allowing earmarking may increase donations; however, it creates operational inefficiencies that undermine the impact of those donations. Extant literature has mainly studied earmarking and its operational consequences in the absence of funding competition. We examine how competition for funding impacts earmarking decisions, fundraising costs, and HO performance in short-term disaster response. In addition to the competition model, we analyze two collaborative fundraising models: (i) full collaboration, where HOs contact donors as a unit and donors cannot donate to specific HOs on the fundraiser, and (ii) partial collaboration, where HOs contact donors as a unit and donors choose among the contacting HOs. Methodology: We use game theory to model the interactions between multiple HOs and a market of donors and build a multinomial logit model for the donor choice problem. Results: We find that competition for funding contributes to the prevalence of earmarked donations, increases fundraising costs, and hurts HO performance and utility. We show that two collaborative fundraising models can mitigate these issues depending on the availability of funding resources. When funding is abundant, full collaboration improves HO utility and reduces earmarking and fundraising costs. When funding is scarce, partial collaboration reduces fundraising costs and improves performance and HO utility. When funding is intermediate, these two forms of collaboration do not necessarily benefit HOs. Managerial implications: We illustrate how funding availability drives earmarking and fundraising decisions and key performance metrics of different funding models during short-term disaster response. Using data from the 2010 Haiti earthquake, our numerical study indicates that partial collaboration benefits response to disasters with funding shortage, whereas full collaboration suits disaster response with sufficient funding. HOs competing for funds can use our insights to improve their response effectiveness. Supplemental Material: The e-companion is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1202 .","PeriodicalId":119284,"journal":{"name":"Manufacturing & Service Operations Management","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-03-15","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"129609857","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Managing the Personalized Order-Holding Problem in Online Retailing 在线零售中个性化订单持有问题的管理
Pub Date : 2023-03-10 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2023.1201
Shouchang Chen, Zhenzhen Yan, Yun Fong Lim
Problem definition: A significant percentage of online consumers place consecutive orders within a short duration. To reduce the total order arrangement cost, an online retailer may consolidate consecutive orders from the same consumer. We investigate how long the retailer should hold the consumer’s orders before sending them to a third-party logistics provider (3PL) for processing. In this order-holding problem, we optimize the holding time to balance the total order arrangement cost and the potential delay in delivery. Methodology/results: We model the order-holding problem as a Markov decision process. We show that the optimal order-holding decisions follow a threshold-type policy that is straightforward to implement: Hold any pending orders if the holding time is within a threshold or send them to the 3PL otherwise. Whenever the consumer places a new order, the holding time is reset, and the threshold is updated based on a cumulative set of the past consecutive orders in the consumer’s shopping journey. Using a consumer’s sequential decision model, we personalize the threshold by finding its closed-form expression in the consumer’s order features. We determine the model’s coefficients and evaluate the threshold-type policy using the data of the 2020 MSOM Data Driven Research Challenge. Extensive numerical experiments suggest that the personalized threshold-type policy outperforms two commonly used benchmarks by having fewer order arrangements or shorter holding times. Furthermore, personalizing the order-holding decisions is significantly more valuable for “enterprise” customers. Managerial implications: Our research suggests a higher threshold for consumers who are more likely to place consecutive orders within a short duration. The consumers’ demographic information has a significant effect on the threshold. Specifically, the threshold is higher for “plus” consumers, female consumers, and consumers in the age group of 16–25 years. The threshold for tier 1 cities is lower than that for tier 2 to tier 4 cities but higher than that for tier 5 cities. History: This paper has been accepted for the Manufacturing & Service Operations Management Data Driven Challenge. Funding: This work was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China [Grants 71931009, 72201237, and 72231009], the Research Grants Council of Hong Kong [Grants 15501920 and 15501221], the Singapore Ministry of Education Academic Research Fund [Tier 1, Grant RG17/21; Tier 2, Grant MOE2019-T2-1-045], the Association of South-East Asian Nations Business Research Initiative Grant [Grant G17C20421], and the Neptune Orient Lines [Fellowship NOL21RP04]. Supplemental Material: The online appendices are available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1201 .
问题定义:相当大比例的在线消费者在短时间内连续下单。为了降低总订单安排成本,在线零售商可以合并来自同一消费者的连续订单。我们调查零售商在将消费者的订单发送给第三方物流提供商(3PL)进行处理之前应该保留多长时间。在此订单保持问题中,我们优化保持时间以平衡总订单安排成本和潜在的交货延迟。方法/结果:我们将订单保持问题建模为马尔可夫决策过程。我们展示了最优的订单保持决策遵循一个易于实现的阈值类型策略:如果保持时间在阈值内,则保留任何未决订单,否则将其发送给第三方物流。每当消费者下一个新订单时,保持时间将被重置,并且阈值将根据消费者购物过程中过去连续订单的累积集更新。使用消费者的顺序决策模型,我们通过在消费者的订单特征中找到其封闭形式的表达式来个性化阈值。我们使用2020年MSOM数据驱动研究挑战赛的数据确定模型的系数并评估阈值型策略。大量的数值实验表明,个性化阈值型策略通过更少的订单安排或更短的保持时间优于两种常用的基准。此外,个性化保持订单的决策对“企业”客户来说更有价值。管理启示:我们的研究表明,对于那些更有可能在短时间内连续下单的消费者来说,门槛更高。消费者的人口统计信息对阈值有显著影响。具体来说,“plus”消费者、女性消费者和16-25岁年龄段的消费者的门槛更高。一线城市的门槛低于二至四线城市,但高于五线城市。历史:本文已被制造业和服务业运营管理数据驱动挑战赛接受。基金资助:中国国家自然科学基金[资助项目:71931009、72201237和72231009]、香港研究资助局[资助项目:15501920和15501221]、新加坡教育部学术研究基金[第一层,资助项目:RG17/21;第2级,资助MOE2019-T2-1-045,东南亚国家联盟商业研究倡议资助[资助G17C20421]和海王星东方航线[奖学金NOL21RP04]。补充材料:在线附录可在https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1201上获得。
{"title":"Managing the Personalized Order-Holding Problem in Online Retailing","authors":"Shouchang Chen, Zhenzhen Yan, Yun Fong Lim","doi":"10.1287/msom.2023.1201","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1201","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: A significant percentage of online consumers place consecutive orders within a short duration. To reduce the total order arrangement cost, an online retailer may consolidate consecutive orders from the same consumer. We investigate how long the retailer should hold the consumer’s orders before sending them to a third-party logistics provider (3PL) for processing. In this order-holding problem, we optimize the holding time to balance the total order arrangement cost and the potential delay in delivery. Methodology/results: We model the order-holding problem as a Markov decision process. We show that the optimal order-holding decisions follow a threshold-type policy that is straightforward to implement: Hold any pending orders if the holding time is within a threshold or send them to the 3PL otherwise. Whenever the consumer places a new order, the holding time is reset, and the threshold is updated based on a cumulative set of the past consecutive orders in the consumer’s shopping journey. Using a consumer’s sequential decision model, we personalize the threshold by finding its closed-form expression in the consumer’s order features. We determine the model’s coefficients and evaluate the threshold-type policy using the data of the 2020 MSOM Data Driven Research Challenge. Extensive numerical experiments suggest that the personalized threshold-type policy outperforms two commonly used benchmarks by having fewer order arrangements or shorter holding times. Furthermore, personalizing the order-holding decisions is significantly more valuable for “enterprise” customers. Managerial implications: Our research suggests a higher threshold for consumers who are more likely to place consecutive orders within a short duration. The consumers’ demographic information has a significant effect on the threshold. Specifically, the threshold is higher for “plus” consumers, female consumers, and consumers in the age group of 16–25 years. The threshold for tier 1 cities is lower than that for tier 2 to tier 4 cities but higher than that for tier 5 cities. History: This paper has been accepted for the Manufacturing & Service Operations Management Data Driven Challenge. Funding: This work was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China [Grants 71931009, 72201237, and 72231009], the Research Grants Council of Hong Kong [Grants 15501920 and 15501221], the Singapore Ministry of Education Academic Research Fund [Tier 1, Grant RG17/21; Tier 2, Grant MOE2019-T2-1-045], the Association of South-East Asian Nations Business Research Initiative Grant [Grant G17C20421], and the Neptune Orient Lines [Fellowship NOL21RP04]. Supplemental Material: The online appendices are available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1201 .","PeriodicalId":119284,"journal":{"name":"Manufacturing & Service Operations Management","volume":"107 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-03-10","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"133230555","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Vehicle Rebalancing in a Shared Micromobility System with Rider Crowdsourcing 基于骑手众包的共享微移动系统中的车辆再平衡
Pub Date : 2023-03-06 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2023.1199
Ziliang Jin, Yulan Wang, Yun Fong Lim, Kai Pan, Z. Shen
Problem definition: Shared micromobility vehicles provide an eco-friendly form of short-distance travel within an urban area. Because customers pick up and drop off vehicles in any service region at any time, such convenience often leads to a severe imbalance between vehicle supply and demand in different service regions. To overcome this, a micromobility operator can crowdsource individual riders with reward incentives in addition to engaging a third-party logistics provider (3PL) to relocate the vehicles. Methodology/results: We construct a time-space network with multiple service regions and formulate a two-stage stochastic mixed-integer program considering uncertain customer demands. In the first stage, the operator decides the initial vehicle allocation for the regions, whereas in the second stage, the operator determines subsequent vehicle relocation across the regions over an operational horizon. We develop an efficient solution approach that incorporates scenario-based and time-based decomposition techniques. Our approach outperforms a commercial solver in solution quality and computational time for solving large-scale problem instances based on real data. Managerial implications: The budgets for acquiring vehicles and for rider crowdsourcing significantly impact the vehicle initial allocation and subsequent relocation. Introducing rider crowdsourcing in addition to the 3PL can significantly increase profit, reduce demand loss, and improve the vehicle utilization rate of the system without affecting any existing commitment with the 3PL. The 3PL is more efficient for mass relocation than rider crowdsourcing, whereas the latter is more efficient in handling sporadic relocation needs. To serve a region, the 3PL often relocates vehicles in batches from faraway, low-demand regions around peak hours of a day, whereas rider crowdsourcing relocates a few vehicles each time from neighboring regions throughout the day. Furthermore, rider crowdsourcing relocates more vehicles under a unimodal customer arrival pattern than a bimodal pattern, whereas the reverse holds for the 3PL. Funding: This work was supported by the Research Grants Council of Hong Kong [Grants 15501319 and 15505318] and the National Natural Science Foundation of China [Grant 71931009]. Z. Jin was supported by the Hong Kong PhD Fellowship Scheme. Y. F. Lim was supported by the Lee Kong Chian School of Business, Singapore Management University [Maritime and Port Authority Research Fellowship]. Supplemental Material: The online appendices are available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1199 .
问题定义:共享微型交通工具在城市区域内提供了一种环保的短途出行方式。由于客户在任何服务区都可以随时接送车辆,这种便利性往往会导致不同服务区的车辆供需严重失衡。为了克服这一问题,微移动运营商除了与第三方物流提供商(3PL)合作重新安置车辆外,还可以通过奖励激励的方式将个人乘客众包。方法/结果:构建了一个具有多个服务区域的时空网络,并在考虑客户需求不确定的情况下,制定了一个两阶段随机混合整数规划。在第一阶段,操作员决定区域的初始车辆分配,而在第二阶段,操作员决定在操作范围内跨区域的后续车辆重新安置。我们开发了一种有效的解决方案方法,它结合了基于场景和基于时间的分解技术。我们的方法在解决基于真实数据的大规模问题实例的解决方案质量和计算时间方面优于商业求解器。管理意义:购买车辆和骑手众包的预算对车辆的初始分配和随后的重新安置有重大影响。在第三方物流之外引入骑手众包可以显著增加利润,减少需求损失,提高系统的车辆利用率,而不会影响与第三方物流的任何现有承诺。第三方物流在大规模搬迁方面比骑手众包更有效,而后者在处理零星搬迁需求方面更有效。为了服务一个地区,第三方物流通常会在一天的高峰时段从遥远的低需求地区批量调运车辆,而骑手众包则每天从邻近地区调运少量车辆。此外,骑手众包在单峰客户到达模式下比双峰模式下重新安置更多的车辆,而对于第三方物流则相反。基金资助:本研究得到香港研究资助局[资助项目:15501319和15505318]和中国国家自然科学基金[资助项目:71931009]的资助。Jin博士获香港博士奖学金计划资助。林毅峰获新加坡管理大学李光前商学院[海事及港务管理局研究奖学金]资助。补充材料:在线附录可在https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1199上获得。
{"title":"Vehicle Rebalancing in a Shared Micromobility System with Rider Crowdsourcing","authors":"Ziliang Jin, Yulan Wang, Yun Fong Lim, Kai Pan, Z. Shen","doi":"10.1287/msom.2023.1199","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1199","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: Shared micromobility vehicles provide an eco-friendly form of short-distance travel within an urban area. Because customers pick up and drop off vehicles in any service region at any time, such convenience often leads to a severe imbalance between vehicle supply and demand in different service regions. To overcome this, a micromobility operator can crowdsource individual riders with reward incentives in addition to engaging a third-party logistics provider (3PL) to relocate the vehicles. Methodology/results: We construct a time-space network with multiple service regions and formulate a two-stage stochastic mixed-integer program considering uncertain customer demands. In the first stage, the operator decides the initial vehicle allocation for the regions, whereas in the second stage, the operator determines subsequent vehicle relocation across the regions over an operational horizon. We develop an efficient solution approach that incorporates scenario-based and time-based decomposition techniques. Our approach outperforms a commercial solver in solution quality and computational time for solving large-scale problem instances based on real data. Managerial implications: The budgets for acquiring vehicles and for rider crowdsourcing significantly impact the vehicle initial allocation and subsequent relocation. Introducing rider crowdsourcing in addition to the 3PL can significantly increase profit, reduce demand loss, and improve the vehicle utilization rate of the system without affecting any existing commitment with the 3PL. The 3PL is more efficient for mass relocation than rider crowdsourcing, whereas the latter is more efficient in handling sporadic relocation needs. To serve a region, the 3PL often relocates vehicles in batches from faraway, low-demand regions around peak hours of a day, whereas rider crowdsourcing relocates a few vehicles each time from neighboring regions throughout the day. Furthermore, rider crowdsourcing relocates more vehicles under a unimodal customer arrival pattern than a bimodal pattern, whereas the reverse holds for the 3PL. Funding: This work was supported by the Research Grants Council of Hong Kong [Grants 15501319 and 15505318] and the National Natural Science Foundation of China [Grant 71931009]. Z. Jin was supported by the Hong Kong PhD Fellowship Scheme. Y. F. Lim was supported by the Lee Kong Chian School of Business, Singapore Management University [Maritime and Port Authority Research Fellowship]. Supplemental Material: The online appendices are available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1199 .","PeriodicalId":119284,"journal":{"name":"Manufacturing & Service Operations Management","volume":"275 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-03-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"115886356","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Intertemporal Price Discrimination via Randomized Promotions 随机促销的跨期价格歧视
Pub Date : 2023-03-06 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2023.1194
Hongqiao Chen, Ming Hu, Jiahua Wu
Problem definition: The undesirable but inevitable consequence of running promotions is that consumers can be trained to time their purchases strategically. In this paper, we study randomized promotions, where the firm randomly offers discounts over time, as an alternative strategy of intertemporal price discrimination. Methodology/results: We consider a base model where a monopolist sells a single product to a market with a constant stream of two market segments. The segments are heterogeneous in both their product valuations and patience levels. The firm precommits to a price distribution, and in each period, a price is randomly drawn from the committed distribution. We characterize the optimal price distribution as a randomized promotion policy and show that it serves as an intertemporal price discrimination mechanism such that high-valuation customers would make a purchase immediately at a regular price upon arrival, and low-valuation customers would wait for a random promotion. Compared against the optimal cyclic pricing policy, which is optimal within the strategy space of all deterministic pricing policies, the optimal randomized pricing policy beats it if low-valuation customers are sufficiently patient and the absolute discrepancy between high and low customer valuations is large enough. We extend the model in three directions. First, we consider the case where a portion of customers are myopic and would never wait. We show that the existence of myopic customers is detrimental to the firm’s profitability, and the expected profit from an optimal randomized pricing policy decreases as the proportion of myopic customers in the population increases. Second, we consider Markovian pricing policies where prices are allowed to be intertemporally correlated in a Markovian fashion. This additional maneuver allows the firm to reap an even higher profit when low-valuation customers are sufficiently patient by avoiding consecutive promotions but, on average, running the promotion more frequently with a smaller discount size. Lastly, we consider a model with multiple customer segments and show that a two-point price distribution remains optimal, and our conclusion from the two-segment base model still holds under certain conditions that are adopted in the literature. Managerial implications: Our results imply that the firm may want to deliberately randomize promotions in the presence of forward-looking customers. Funding: This work was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China [Grant 72201124], the Natural Sciences and Engineering Research Council of Canada [Grants RGPIN-2015-06757 and RGPIN-2021-04295], and the Youth Project of the Humanities and Social Science Foundation of the Ministry of Education of China [Grant 22YJC630006]. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1194 .
问题定义:进行促销活动的一个不受欢迎但不可避免的后果是,消费者可能会被训练得有策略地选择购买时间。本文研究随机促销,即企业随时间随机提供折扣,作为跨期价格歧视的一种替代策略。方法/结果:我们考虑一个基本模型,其中垄断者向市场销售单一产品,市场有两个细分市场的恒定流。这些细分市场在产品估值和耐心水平上都是异质的。公司预先承诺一个价格分布,在每个时期,从承诺的分布中随机抽取一个价格。我们将最优价格分配描述为随机促销政策,并表明它作为一种跨期价格歧视机制,使得高价值的客户在到达后立即以常规价格购买,而低价值的客户将等待随机促销。与在所有确定性定价策略的策略空间内最优的最优循环定价策略相比,当低价值客户有足够的耐心,且高、低价值客户估值之间的绝对差异足够大时,最优随机定价策略优于最优循环定价策略。我们在三个方向上扩展了这个模型。首先,我们考虑这样一种情况:一部分顾客目光短浅,从不等待。我们证明了近视顾客的存在不利于企业的盈利能力,并且最优随机定价策略的预期利润随着近视顾客在人口中所占比例的增加而降低。其次,我们考虑马尔可夫定价政策,其中价格允许以马尔可夫方式进行跨期相关。这种额外的策略使公司能够在低价值客户足够耐心的情况下获得更高的利润,避免连续促销,但平均而言,以较小的折扣规模进行更频繁的促销。最后,我们考虑了一个具有多个客户细分的模型,并表明两点价格分布仍然是最优的,并且我们从两细分基础模型得出的结论在文献中采用的某些条件下仍然成立。管理启示:我们的研究结果表明,公司可能有意在前瞻性客户面前随机进行促销。基金资助:中国国家自然科学基金[Grant 72201124]、加拿大自然科学与工程研究理事会[Grant RGPIN-2015-06757和RGPIN-2021-04295]、中国教育部人文社会科学基金青年项目[Grant 22YJC630006]资助。补充材料:在线附录可在https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1194上获得。
{"title":"Intertemporal Price Discrimination via Randomized Promotions","authors":"Hongqiao Chen, Ming Hu, Jiahua Wu","doi":"10.1287/msom.2023.1194","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1194","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: The undesirable but inevitable consequence of running promotions is that consumers can be trained to time their purchases strategically. In this paper, we study randomized promotions, where the firm randomly offers discounts over time, as an alternative strategy of intertemporal price discrimination. Methodology/results: We consider a base model where a monopolist sells a single product to a market with a constant stream of two market segments. The segments are heterogeneous in both their product valuations and patience levels. The firm precommits to a price distribution, and in each period, a price is randomly drawn from the committed distribution. We characterize the optimal price distribution as a randomized promotion policy and show that it serves as an intertemporal price discrimination mechanism such that high-valuation customers would make a purchase immediately at a regular price upon arrival, and low-valuation customers would wait for a random promotion. Compared against the optimal cyclic pricing policy, which is optimal within the strategy space of all deterministic pricing policies, the optimal randomized pricing policy beats it if low-valuation customers are sufficiently patient and the absolute discrepancy between high and low customer valuations is large enough. We extend the model in three directions. First, we consider the case where a portion of customers are myopic and would never wait. We show that the existence of myopic customers is detrimental to the firm’s profitability, and the expected profit from an optimal randomized pricing policy decreases as the proportion of myopic customers in the population increases. Second, we consider Markovian pricing policies where prices are allowed to be intertemporally correlated in a Markovian fashion. This additional maneuver allows the firm to reap an even higher profit when low-valuation customers are sufficiently patient by avoiding consecutive promotions but, on average, running the promotion more frequently with a smaller discount size. Lastly, we consider a model with multiple customer segments and show that a two-point price distribution remains optimal, and our conclusion from the two-segment base model still holds under certain conditions that are adopted in the literature. Managerial implications: Our results imply that the firm may want to deliberately randomize promotions in the presence of forward-looking customers. Funding: This work was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China [Grant 72201124], the Natural Sciences and Engineering Research Council of Canada [Grants RGPIN-2015-06757 and RGPIN-2021-04295], and the Youth Project of the Humanities and Social Science Foundation of the Ministry of Education of China [Grant 22YJC630006]. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1194 .","PeriodicalId":119284,"journal":{"name":"Manufacturing & Service Operations Management","volume":"46 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-03-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"122650680","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
The Value of Social Media Data in Fashion Forecasting 社交媒体数据在时尚预测中的价值
Pub Date : 2023-03-01 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2023.1193
Youran Fu, M. Fisher
Problem definition: How to use social media to predict style color and jeans fit sales for a retailer. Academic/practical relevance: Neither retail practice nor the academic literature provides a method for using social media to predict style color and jeans fit sales for a retailer. We present and validate a systematic approach for doing that. Methodology: Demand forecasting in the fashion industry is challenging due to short product lifetimes, long manufacturing lead times, and constant innovation of fashion products. We investigate the value of social media information for color trends and jeans fit forecasting. We partner with three multinational retailers, two apparel and one footwear, and combine their proprietary data sets with web-crawled publicly available data on Twitter and the Google Search Volume Index. We implement a variety of machine learning models to develop forecasts that can be used in setting the initial shipment quantity for an item, arguably the most important decision for fashion retailers. Results: Our findings show that fine-grained social media information has significant predictive power in forecasting color and fit demands months in advance of the sales season, and therefore greatly helps in making the initial shipment quantity decision. The predictive power of including social media features, measured by the improvement of the out-of-sample mean absolute deviation over current practice ranges from 24% to 57%. Managerial implications: To our knowledge, this study is the first to explore and demonstrate the value of social media information in fashion demand forecasting in a way that is practical and operable for fashion retailers. With consistent results across all three retailers, we demonstrate the robustness of our findings over market and geographic heterogeneity, and different forecast horizons. Moreover, we discuss potential mechanisms that might be driving this significant predictive power. Our results suggest that changes in fashion demand are driven more by “bottom-up” changes in consumer preferences than by “top-down” influence from the fashion industry. Funding: This work was supported by Wharton School Fishman-Davidson Center for Service and Operations Management, the Wharton School Baker Retailing Center, and the Wharton School Risk Management Center Russell Ackoff Doctoral Student Fellowship. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1193 .
问题定义:如何使用社交媒体来预测零售商的款式、颜色和牛仔裤的销量。学术/实践相关性:无论是零售实践还是学术文献都没有提供一种方法来使用社交媒体来预测零售商的款式、颜色和牛仔裤的销量。我们提出并验证了这样做的系统方法。方法:由于产品寿命短,制造交货期长,以及时尚产品的不断创新,时尚行业的需求预测具有挑战性。我们调查了社交媒体信息对颜色趋势和牛仔裤合身度预测的价值。我们与三家跨国零售商(两家服装零售商和一家鞋类零售商)合作,并将它们的专有数据集与Twitter和谷歌搜索量指数(Google Search Volume Index)上的网络抓取公开数据结合起来。我们实现了各种机器学习模型来开发预测,可用于设置商品的初始出货量,这可以说是时尚零售商最重要的决策。结果:我们的研究结果表明,细粒度的社交媒体信息在销售季节前几个月预测颜色和合身需求方面具有显着的预测能力,因此对初步出货数量决策有很大帮助。包括社交媒体特征的预测能力,通过改善样本外平均绝对偏差来衡量,目前的实践范围在24%到57%之间。管理启示:据我们所知,这项研究首次探索并证明了社交媒体信息在时尚需求预测中的价值,这对时尚零售商来说是一种实用和可操作的方式。在所有三家零售商的一致结果中,我们证明了我们的发现在市场和地理异质性以及不同预测范围内的稳健性。此外,我们还讨论了可能推动这种重要预测能力的潜在机制。我们的研究结果表明,时尚需求的变化更多地是由消费者偏好的“自下而上”变化所驱动,而不是由时尚产业的“自上而下”影响所驱动。资助:本研究得到了沃顿商学院Fishman-Davidson服务与运营管理中心、沃顿商学院贝克零售中心和沃顿商学院风险管理中心罗素·阿科夫博士生奖学金的支持。补充材料:在线附录可在https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1193上获得。
{"title":"The Value of Social Media Data in Fashion Forecasting","authors":"Youran Fu, M. Fisher","doi":"10.1287/msom.2023.1193","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1193","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: How to use social media to predict style color and jeans fit sales for a retailer. Academic/practical relevance: Neither retail practice nor the academic literature provides a method for using social media to predict style color and jeans fit sales for a retailer. We present and validate a systematic approach for doing that. Methodology: Demand forecasting in the fashion industry is challenging due to short product lifetimes, long manufacturing lead times, and constant innovation of fashion products. We investigate the value of social media information for color trends and jeans fit forecasting. We partner with three multinational retailers, two apparel and one footwear, and combine their proprietary data sets with web-crawled publicly available data on Twitter and the Google Search Volume Index. We implement a variety of machine learning models to develop forecasts that can be used in setting the initial shipment quantity for an item, arguably the most important decision for fashion retailers. Results: Our findings show that fine-grained social media information has significant predictive power in forecasting color and fit demands months in advance of the sales season, and therefore greatly helps in making the initial shipment quantity decision. The predictive power of including social media features, measured by the improvement of the out-of-sample mean absolute deviation over current practice ranges from 24% to 57%. Managerial implications: To our knowledge, this study is the first to explore and demonstrate the value of social media information in fashion demand forecasting in a way that is practical and operable for fashion retailers. With consistent results across all three retailers, we demonstrate the robustness of our findings over market and geographic heterogeneity, and different forecast horizons. Moreover, we discuss potential mechanisms that might be driving this significant predictive power. Our results suggest that changes in fashion demand are driven more by “bottom-up” changes in consumer preferences than by “top-down” influence from the fashion industry. Funding: This work was supported by Wharton School Fishman-Davidson Center for Service and Operations Management, the Wharton School Baker Retailing Center, and the Wharton School Risk Management Center Russell Ackoff Doctoral Student Fellowship. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1193 .","PeriodicalId":119284,"journal":{"name":"Manufacturing & Service Operations Management","volume":"17 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-03-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"121322723","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Blockchain Operations in the Presence of Security Concerns 存在安全问题的区块链操作
Pub Date : 2023-02-27 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2023.1197
Jiahao He, Guangyuan Zhang, Jiheng Zhang, Rachel Q. Zhang
Problem definition: A blockchain payment system, such as Bitcoin or Ethereum, validates electronic transactions and stores them in a chain of blocks without a central authority. Miners with computing power compete for the rights to create blocks according to a preset protocol, referred to as hashing or mining, and, in return, earn fees paid by users who submit transactions. Because of security concerns caused by decentralization, a transaction is confirmed after a number of additional blocks are subsequently extended to the block containing it. This confirmation latency introduces an intricate interplay between miners and users. This paper provides approximate system equilibria and studies optimal designs of a blockchain. Methodology/results: The hashing process is essentially a single-server queue with batch services based on a fee-based priority discipline, and confirmation latency adds complexity to the equilibrium behavior and optimal design. We analyze how miners’ participation decisions interact with users’ participation and fee decisions and identify optimal designs when the goal is to maximize the throughput or social welfare. We validate our model and conduct numerical studies using data from Bitcoin. Managerial implications: By incorporating security issues, we uncover the interdependence of the decisions between users and miners and the driver for nonzero entrance fees in practice. We show that miners and users may end up in either a vicious or virtuous cycle, depending on the initial system state. By allowing the entrance fee to be a design parameter, we are able to establish that it is optimal to simply run a blockchain system at its full capacity and a block size as small as possible. Funding: This work was supported by the Hong Kong Research Grants Council [Grants 16200019, 16200617, 16200821, 16208120, and 16214121]. Supplemental Material: The e-companion is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1197 .
问题定义:区块链支付系统,如比特币或以太坊,验证电子交易并将其存储在没有中央权威的区块链中。拥有计算能力的矿工根据预先设定的协议(称为哈希或挖矿)竞争创建区块的权利,并作为回报,获得提交交易的用户支付的费用。由于去中心化引起的安全问题,在随后将一些额外的块扩展到包含它的块之后,交易才被确认。这种确认延迟在矿工和用户之间引入了复杂的相互作用。本文给出了近似系统均衡,并研究了区块链的优化设计。方法/结果:哈希过程本质上是基于基于费用的优先级原则的批处理服务的单服务器队列,确认延迟增加了平衡行为和最佳设计的复杂性。我们分析了矿工的参与决策如何与用户的参与和费用决策相互作用,并确定了当目标是最大化吞吐量或社会福利时的最佳设计。我们验证了我们的模型,并使用比特币的数据进行了数值研究。管理意义:通过纳入安全问题,我们揭示了用户和矿工之间的决策相互依赖,以及在实践中非零入场费的驱动程序。我们表明,矿工和用户最终可能会陷入恶性循环或良性循环,这取决于初始系统状态。通过将入场费作为一个设计参数,我们能够确定,简单地以最大容量运行区块链系统和尽可能小的块大小是最优的。资助:本研究得到香港研究资助局资助[资助项16200019、16200617、16200821、16208120及16214121]。补充材料:电子伴侣可在https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1197上获得。
{"title":"Blockchain Operations in the Presence of Security Concerns","authors":"Jiahao He, Guangyuan Zhang, Jiheng Zhang, Rachel Q. Zhang","doi":"10.1287/msom.2023.1197","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1197","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: A blockchain payment system, such as Bitcoin or Ethereum, validates electronic transactions and stores them in a chain of blocks without a central authority. Miners with computing power compete for the rights to create blocks according to a preset protocol, referred to as hashing or mining, and, in return, earn fees paid by users who submit transactions. Because of security concerns caused by decentralization, a transaction is confirmed after a number of additional blocks are subsequently extended to the block containing it. This confirmation latency introduces an intricate interplay between miners and users. This paper provides approximate system equilibria and studies optimal designs of a blockchain. Methodology/results: The hashing process is essentially a single-server queue with batch services based on a fee-based priority discipline, and confirmation latency adds complexity to the equilibrium behavior and optimal design. We analyze how miners’ participation decisions interact with users’ participation and fee decisions and identify optimal designs when the goal is to maximize the throughput or social welfare. We validate our model and conduct numerical studies using data from Bitcoin. Managerial implications: By incorporating security issues, we uncover the interdependence of the decisions between users and miners and the driver for nonzero entrance fees in practice. We show that miners and users may end up in either a vicious or virtuous cycle, depending on the initial system state. By allowing the entrance fee to be a design parameter, we are able to establish that it is optimal to simply run a blockchain system at its full capacity and a block size as small as possible. Funding: This work was supported by the Hong Kong Research Grants Council [Grants 16200019, 16200617, 16200821, 16208120, and 16214121]. Supplemental Material: The e-companion is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2023.1197 .","PeriodicalId":119284,"journal":{"name":"Manufacturing & Service Operations Management","volume":"32 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-02-27","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"134080253","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
期刊
Manufacturing & Service Operations Management
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1