首页 > 最新文献

Manufacturing & Service Operations Management最新文献

英文 中文
Supply Chain Finance Redefined: A Supply Chain-Centric Viewpoint of Working Capital, Hedging, and Risk Management 供应链金融的重新定义:以供应链为中心的营运资金、套期保值和风险管理观点
Pub Date : 2023-08-29 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2022.0606
Panos Kouvelis
Problem definition: The narrow definition of supply chain finance (SCF) as a financing scheme for accounts receivables fails to capture the knowledge creation of MSOM research scholars of the last 25 years who labored in the area under this label. A redefined definition of the research-and-application field, under the acronym integrated SCF (iSCF), better reflects the interplay of operational, financial, and risk management decisions our scholars and practitioners care about. The foundational knowledge of this field is ready to come into the classroom and elevate SCF courses from the typical “accounting and finance for supply chain managers” content to a supply-chain-centric viewpoint of important decisions in working capital management, effective cash-flow hedging, and integrated risk management of global supply chain risks. We outline the main research themes behind the iSCF research, and teaching, field; highlight concepts ready for the classroom; and pose some open research questions pointing to the future promise of the field. Methodology/results: Forum paper. MSOM Fellow opinion on topic of supply chain finance and risk management based on his published research. Managerial implications: A supply-chain-centric view on state-of-the-art practices for improved working capital, hedging, and risk management in global supply chains (integrated supply chain finance).
问题定义:将供应链金融(SCF)狭义地定义为一种应收账款融资方案,未能体现过去25年来在这一标签下从事该领域研究的MSOM学者的知识创造。对研究与应用领域的重新定义,简称为综合SCF (iSCF),更好地反映了我们的学者和从业者所关心的运营、财务和风险管理决策之间的相互作用。该领域的基础知识已经准备好进入课堂,并将SCF课程从典型的“供应链经理的会计和财务”内容提升到以供应链为中心的观点,包括营运资金管理中的重要决策,有效的现金流对冲以及全球供应链风险的综合风险管理。我们概述了iSCF研究和教学领域背后的主要研究主题;突出课堂准备的概念;并提出一些开放的研究问题,指出该领域的未来前景。方法/结果:论坛文件。MSOM Fellow基于其已发表的研究成果对供应链金融与风险管理主题的看法。管理含义:以供应链为中心的观点,在全球供应链(集成供应链金融)中改进营运资金、对冲和风险管理的最新实践。
{"title":"Supply Chain Finance Redefined: A Supply Chain-Centric Viewpoint of Working Capital, Hedging, and Risk Management","authors":"Panos Kouvelis","doi":"10.1287/msom.2022.0606","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.0606","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: The narrow definition of supply chain finance (SCF) as a financing scheme for accounts receivables fails to capture the knowledge creation of MSOM research scholars of the last 25 years who labored in the area under this label. A redefined definition of the research-and-application field, under the acronym integrated SCF (iSCF), better reflects the interplay of operational, financial, and risk management decisions our scholars and practitioners care about. The foundational knowledge of this field is ready to come into the classroom and elevate SCF courses from the typical “accounting and finance for supply chain managers” content to a supply-chain-centric viewpoint of important decisions in working capital management, effective cash-flow hedging, and integrated risk management of global supply chain risks. We outline the main research themes behind the iSCF research, and teaching, field; highlight concepts ready for the classroom; and pose some open research questions pointing to the future promise of the field. Methodology/results: Forum paper. MSOM Fellow opinion on topic of supply chain finance and risk management based on his published research. Managerial implications: A supply-chain-centric view on state-of-the-art practices for improved working capital, hedging, and risk management in global supply chains (integrated supply chain finance).","PeriodicalId":119284,"journal":{"name":"Manufacturing & Service Operations Management","volume":"410 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-08-29","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"127679856","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Sustainability Implications of Supply Chain Responsiveness 供应链响应的可持续性含义
Pub Date : 2023-08-16 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2022.0152
A. Tuna, R. Swinney
Problem definition: A critical decision made by firms is whether to adopt a responsive supply chain (prioritizing speed) or an efficient supply chain (prioritizing cost). We consider the environmental implications of this choice, distinguishing between responsiveness achieved via three pathways: responsive offshore supply chains increase speed by using expedited production and distribution methods; responsive nearshore supply chains increase speed by reducing the physical distance between source and destination for all production; and hybrid nearshore supply chains produce in multiple locations simultaneously, increasing speed by reducing distance on some portion of production. Methodology/results: Using a model wherein responsiveness increases fixed and marginal costs, decreases leadtimes, and changes the per-unit environmental impact of production and distribution, we identify several results. First, all types of responsiveness can decrease environmental impact relative to an efficient supply chain, showing any form of responsiveness has potential to improve sustainability. Second, despite this, all types of responsiveness can also increase environmental impact relative to an efficient supply chain, particularly if demand variability is high. This is precisely when responsiveness is most profitable to the firm, indicating a tension between firm and environmental preferences. Third, a win-win outcome in which responsiveness both maximizes firm profit and minimizes environmental impact is most likely to occur when demand variability is high and unsatisfied customers substitute with a product that generates high environmental impact. Fourth, the firm may have incentive to choose a supply chain that does not minimize (and may maximize) environmental impact, especially at low-to-moderate demand variability. Managerial implications: While responsive supply chains can improve sustainability, they also generate the potential for misalignment of profit and environmental performance. We discuss the implications of this for firms and for policymakers seeking to encourage firms to use supply chains that generate the least environmental impact. Supplemental Material: The e-companion is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.0152 .
问题定义:企业做出的一个关键决策是,是采用响应式供应链(优先考虑速度)还是高效供应链(优先考虑成本)。我们考虑了这种选择对环境的影响,区分了通过三种途径实现的响应性:响应式海上供应链通过使用快速生产和分销方法来提高速度;响应式近岸供应链通过缩短所有生产源和目的地之间的物理距离来提高速度;混合近岸供应链同时在多个地点生产,通过减少部分生产的距离来提高速度。方法/结果:使用响应性增加固定成本和边际成本,缩短交货时间,并改变生产和分销的单位环境影响的模型,我们确定了几个结果。首先,与高效的供应链相比,所有类型的响应都可以减少对环境的影响,这表明任何形式的响应都有可能提高可持续性。其次,尽管如此,与高效的供应链相比,所有类型的响应也会增加对环境的影响,特别是在需求变化很大的情况下。这恰恰是响应性对企业最有利的时候,表明企业和环境偏好之间存在紧张关系。第三,当需求可变性高,不满意的客户替代产生高环境影响的产品时,最可能出现双赢的结果,即响应性既使公司利润最大化,又使环境影响最小化。第四,企业可能有动机选择一个不会最小化(也可能最大化)环境影响的供应链,特别是在低到中等需求变化的情况下。管理意义:虽然响应式供应链可以提高可持续性,但它们也会产生利润和环境绩效不一致的可能性。我们讨论了这对企业和政策制定者的影响,这些政策制定者试图鼓励企业使用对环境影响最小的供应链。补充材料:电子伴侣可在https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.0152上获得。
{"title":"Sustainability Implications of Supply Chain Responsiveness","authors":"A. Tuna, R. Swinney","doi":"10.1287/msom.2022.0152","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.0152","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: A critical decision made by firms is whether to adopt a responsive supply chain (prioritizing speed) or an efficient supply chain (prioritizing cost). We consider the environmental implications of this choice, distinguishing between responsiveness achieved via three pathways: responsive offshore supply chains increase speed by using expedited production and distribution methods; responsive nearshore supply chains increase speed by reducing the physical distance between source and destination for all production; and hybrid nearshore supply chains produce in multiple locations simultaneously, increasing speed by reducing distance on some portion of production. Methodology/results: Using a model wherein responsiveness increases fixed and marginal costs, decreases leadtimes, and changes the per-unit environmental impact of production and distribution, we identify several results. First, all types of responsiveness can decrease environmental impact relative to an efficient supply chain, showing any form of responsiveness has potential to improve sustainability. Second, despite this, all types of responsiveness can also increase environmental impact relative to an efficient supply chain, particularly if demand variability is high. This is precisely when responsiveness is most profitable to the firm, indicating a tension between firm and environmental preferences. Third, a win-win outcome in which responsiveness both maximizes firm profit and minimizes environmental impact is most likely to occur when demand variability is high and unsatisfied customers substitute with a product that generates high environmental impact. Fourth, the firm may have incentive to choose a supply chain that does not minimize (and may maximize) environmental impact, especially at low-to-moderate demand variability. Managerial implications: While responsive supply chains can improve sustainability, they also generate the potential for misalignment of profit and environmental performance. We discuss the implications of this for firms and for policymakers seeking to encourage firms to use supply chains that generate the least environmental impact. Supplemental Material: The e-companion is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.0152 .","PeriodicalId":119284,"journal":{"name":"Manufacturing & Service Operations Management","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-08-16","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"117241785","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Performance Guarantees for Network Revenue Management with Flexible Products 柔性产品网络收益管理的性能保证
Pub Date : 2023-08-11 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2022.0583
Wenchang Zhu, Huseyin Topaloglu
Problem definition: We consider network revenue management problems with flexible products. We have a network of resources with limited capacities. To each customer arriving into the system, we offer an assortment of products. The customer chooses a product within the offered assortment or decides to leave without a purchase. The products are flexible in the sense that there are multiple possible combinations of resources that we can use to serve a customer with a purchase for a particular product. We refer to each such combination of resources as a route. The service provider chooses the route to serve a customer with a purchase for a particular product. Such flexible products occur, for example, when customers book at-home cleaning services but leave the timing of service to the company that provides the service. Our goal is to find a policy to decide which assortment of products to offer to each customer to maximize the total expected revenue, making sure that there are always feasible route assignments for the customers with purchased products. Methodology/results: We start by considering the case in which we make the route assignments at the end of the selling horizon. The dynamic programming formulation of the problem is significantly different from its analogue without flexible products as the state variable keeps track of the number of purchases for each product rather than the remaining capacity of each resource. Letting L be the maximum number of resources in a route, we give a policy that obtains at least [Formula: see text] fraction of the optimal total expected revenue. We extend our policy to the case in which we make the route assignments periodically over the selling horizon. Managerial implications: To our knowledge, the policy that we develop is the first with a performance guarantee under flexible products. Thus, our work constructs policies that can be implemented in practice under flexible products, also providing performance guarantees. Funding: The work of H. Topaloglu was partly funded by the National Science Foundation [Grant CMMI-1825406]. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.0583 .
问题定义:我们考虑灵活产品的网络收益管理问题。我们的资源网络能力有限。对于每个进入系统的客户,我们提供各种各样的产品。顾客在提供的分类中选择一种产品,或者决定不购买而离开。产品是灵活的,因为我们可以使用多种可能的资源组合来为购买特定产品的客户提供服务。我们把每一个这样的资源组合称为一条路线。服务提供者选择为购买特定产品的客户提供服务的路线。例如,当客户预订家庭清洁服务,但将服务时间留给提供服务的公司时,就会出现这种灵活的产品。我们的目标是找到一个策略来决定向每个客户提供哪种产品分类以最大化总预期收益,并确保对于购买产品的客户总是有可行的路线分配。方法/结果:我们首先考虑在销售周期结束时进行路线分配的情况。由于状态变量跟踪的是每种产品的购买数量,而不是每种资源的剩余容量,因此问题的动态规划表述与没有柔性产品的模拟有很大不同。设L为一条路线上的最大资源数,我们给出一个策略,该策略至少获得最优总期望收益的[公式:见文本]部分。我们将我们的政策扩展到我们定期在销售范围内进行路线分配的情况。管理启示:据我们所知,我们制定的政策是第一个在柔性产品下提供性能保证的政策。因此,我们的工作构建了在灵活产品下可以在实践中实施的策略,也提供了性能保证。资助:H. Topaloglu的工作部分由美国国家科学基金会资助[Grant CMMI-1825406]。补充材料:在线附录可在https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.0583上获得。
{"title":"Performance Guarantees for Network Revenue Management with Flexible Products","authors":"Wenchang Zhu, Huseyin Topaloglu","doi":"10.1287/msom.2022.0583","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.0583","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: We consider network revenue management problems with flexible products. We have a network of resources with limited capacities. To each customer arriving into the system, we offer an assortment of products. The customer chooses a product within the offered assortment or decides to leave without a purchase. The products are flexible in the sense that there are multiple possible combinations of resources that we can use to serve a customer with a purchase for a particular product. We refer to each such combination of resources as a route. The service provider chooses the route to serve a customer with a purchase for a particular product. Such flexible products occur, for example, when customers book at-home cleaning services but leave the timing of service to the company that provides the service. Our goal is to find a policy to decide which assortment of products to offer to each customer to maximize the total expected revenue, making sure that there are always feasible route assignments for the customers with purchased products. Methodology/results: We start by considering the case in which we make the route assignments at the end of the selling horizon. The dynamic programming formulation of the problem is significantly different from its analogue without flexible products as the state variable keeps track of the number of purchases for each product rather than the remaining capacity of each resource. Letting L be the maximum number of resources in a route, we give a policy that obtains at least [Formula: see text] fraction of the optimal total expected revenue. We extend our policy to the case in which we make the route assignments periodically over the selling horizon. Managerial implications: To our knowledge, the policy that we develop is the first with a performance guarantee under flexible products. Thus, our work constructs policies that can be implemented in practice under flexible products, also providing performance guarantees. Funding: The work of H. Topaloglu was partly funded by the National Science Foundation [Grant CMMI-1825406]. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.0583 .","PeriodicalId":119284,"journal":{"name":"Manufacturing & Service Operations Management","volume":"21 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-08-11","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"132814626","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
On the Distributed Energy Storage Investment and Operations 分布式储能投资与运营研究
Pub Date : 2023-08-09 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2020.0652
Owen Q. Wu, R. Kapuscinski, S. Suresh
Problem definition: Energy storage has become an indispensable part of power distribution systems, necessitating prudent investment decisions. We analyze an energy storage facility location problem and compare the benefits of centralized storage (adjacent to a central energy generation site) versus distributed storage (localized at demand sites). This problem encompasses optimizing storage capacities across all locations, with the objective of minimizing the total storage investment and energy generation costs. Methodology/results: We employ a stylized model that captures essential features of an energy distribution system, including convex costs, stochastic demand, storage efficiency, and line losses. Using dynamic programming, we optimize storage operations and derive value function properties that are key to analyzing the storage investment decisions. We discern fundamental differences between centralization/localization decisions at the capacity investment stage and the centralization/localization decisions at the storage operations level. Operationally, centrally stored energy offers more flexibility, which is consistent with the conventional understanding of inventory pooling. However, we find that localized storage often emerges as the preferred option at the investment stage under various circumstances. Managerial implications: Storage investment should first be made at the demand locations with positive minimum demand regardless of the level of demand variability. Subsequent storage investment should consider the tradeoffs between centralized versus localized investment. Operationally, the relative magnitudes of storage and line losses drive different optimal storage policies. Despite the differences, these policies are guided by common principles such as pooling inventory and balancing local storage levels. Supplemental Material: The online appendices are available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2020.0652 .
问题定义:储能已成为配电系统不可或缺的一部分,需要谨慎的投资决策。我们分析了一个储能设施的选址问题,并比较了集中式储能(靠近中央发电站点)与分布式储能(位于需求站点)的优势。这个问题包括优化所有地点的存储容量,目标是最小化总存储投资和能源生产成本。方法/结果:我们采用了一个程式化的模型来捕捉能源分配系统的基本特征,包括凸成本、随机需求、存储效率和线路损耗。利用动态规划,我们优化了存储操作,并得出了分析存储投资决策的关键价值函数属性。我们发现容量投资阶段的集中化/本地化决策与存储操作级别的集中化/本地化决策之间存在根本性差异。在操作上,集中储存能源提供了更大的灵活性,这与库存池的传统理解是一致的。然而,我们发现在各种情况下,本地化存储往往成为投资阶段的首选。管理意义:无论需求变化的程度如何,存储投资应该首先在具有正最小需求的需求位置进行。后续的存储投资应该考虑集中式和本地化投资之间的权衡。操作上,存储和线路损耗的相对大小驱动不同的最优存储策略。尽管存在差异,但这些策略都遵循共同的原则,例如汇集库存和平衡本地存储水平。补充材料:在线附录可在https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2020.0652上获得。
{"title":"On the Distributed Energy Storage Investment and Operations","authors":"Owen Q. Wu, R. Kapuscinski, S. Suresh","doi":"10.1287/msom.2020.0652","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2020.0652","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: Energy storage has become an indispensable part of power distribution systems, necessitating prudent investment decisions. We analyze an energy storage facility location problem and compare the benefits of centralized storage (adjacent to a central energy generation site) versus distributed storage (localized at demand sites). This problem encompasses optimizing storage capacities across all locations, with the objective of minimizing the total storage investment and energy generation costs. Methodology/results: We employ a stylized model that captures essential features of an energy distribution system, including convex costs, stochastic demand, storage efficiency, and line losses. Using dynamic programming, we optimize storage operations and derive value function properties that are key to analyzing the storage investment decisions. We discern fundamental differences between centralization/localization decisions at the capacity investment stage and the centralization/localization decisions at the storage operations level. Operationally, centrally stored energy offers more flexibility, which is consistent with the conventional understanding of inventory pooling. However, we find that localized storage often emerges as the preferred option at the investment stage under various circumstances. Managerial implications: Storage investment should first be made at the demand locations with positive minimum demand regardless of the level of demand variability. Subsequent storage investment should consider the tradeoffs between centralized versus localized investment. Operationally, the relative magnitudes of storage and line losses drive different optimal storage policies. Despite the differences, these policies are guided by common principles such as pooling inventory and balancing local storage levels. Supplemental Material: The online appendices are available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2020.0652 .","PeriodicalId":119284,"journal":{"name":"Manufacturing & Service Operations Management","volume":"39 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-08-09","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"115517462","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Disease Bundling or Specimen Bundling? Cost- and Capacity-Efficient Strategies for Multidisease Testing with Genetic Assays 疾病捆绑还是标本捆绑?多疾病基因检测的成本和能力效率策略
Pub Date : 2023-08-08 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2022.0296
D. R. Bish, E. Bish, Hussein El Hajj
Problem definition: Infectious disease screening can be expensive and capacity constrained. We develop cost- and capacity-efficient testing designs for multidisease screening, considering (1) multiplexing (disease bundling), where one assay detects multiple diseases using the same specimen (e.g., nasal swabs, blood), and (2) pooling (specimen bundling), where one assay is used on specimens from multiple subjects bundled in a testing pool. A testing design specifies an assay portfolio (mix of single-disease/multiplex assays) and a testing method (pooling/individual testing per assay). Methodology/results: We develop novel models for the nonlinear, combinatorial multidisease testing design problem: a deterministic model and a distribution-free, robust variation, which both generate Pareto frontiers for cost- and capacity-efficient designs. We characterize structural properties of optimal designs, formulate the deterministic counterpart of the robust model, and conduct a case study of respiratory diseases (including coronavirus disease 2019) with overlapping clinical presentation. Managerial implications: Key drivers of optimal designs include the assay cost function, the tester’s preference toward cost versus capacity efficiency, prevalence/coinfection rates, and for the robust model, prevalence uncertainty. When an optimal design uses multiple assays, it does so in conjunction with pooling, and it uses individual testing for at most one assay. Although prevalence uncertainty can be a design hurdle, especially for emerging or seasonal diseases, the integration of multiplexing and pooling, and the ordered partition property of optimal designs (under certain coinfection structures) serve to make the design more structurally robust to uncertainty. The robust model further increases robustness, and it is also practical as it needs only an uncertainty set around each disease prevalence. Our Pareto designs demonstrate the cost versus capacity trade-off and show that multiplexing-only or pooling-only designs need not be on the Pareto frontier. Our case study illustrates the benefits of optimally integrated designs over current practices and indicates a low price of robustness. Funding: This work was supported by the National Science Foundation [Grant 1761842]. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.0296 .
问题定义:传染病筛查费用昂贵,能力有限。我们为多疾病筛查开发了成本和能力效率高的测试设计,考虑了(1)多路复用(疾病捆绑),其中一种检测方法使用相同的标本(例如鼻拭子、血液)检测多种疾病,以及(2)汇集(标本捆绑),其中一种检测方法用于捆绑在测试池中的多个受试者的标本。检测设计指定检测组合(单一疾病/多种检测的混合)和检测方法(每种检测的合并/单独检测)。方法/结果:我们为非线性组合多疾病测试设计问题开发了新的模型:一个确定性模型和一个无分布的鲁棒变化,它们都为成本和能力效率设计产生了帕累托边界。我们对优化设计的结构特性进行了表征,制定了稳健模型的确定性对应项,并对具有重叠临床表现的呼吸系统疾病(包括2019冠状病毒病)进行了案例研究。管理意义:优化设计的关键驱动因素包括分析成本函数、测试人员对成本与能力效率的偏好、流行/合并感染率,以及对于稳健模型,流行不确定性。当一个优化设计使用多个分析时,它与池化相结合,并且它最多使用一个分析的单个测试。尽管患病率的不确定性可能成为设计障碍,特别是对于新发疾病或季节性疾病,但多路复用和池化的集成以及优化设计的有序划分特性(在某些共感染结构下)有助于使设计在结构上对不确定性更具鲁棒性。鲁棒模型进一步增强了鲁棒性,而且它也很实用,因为它只需要每个疾病流行率的不确定性集。我们的Pareto设计展示了成本与容量的权衡,并表明仅复用或仅池的设计不需要在Pareto边界上。我们的案例研究说明了优化集成设计相对于当前实践的好处,并指出了稳健性的低代价。本研究由美国国家科学基金会资助[Grant 1761842]。补充材料:在线附录可在https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.0296上获得。
{"title":"Disease Bundling or Specimen Bundling? Cost- and Capacity-Efficient Strategies for Multidisease Testing with Genetic Assays","authors":"D. R. Bish, E. Bish, Hussein El Hajj","doi":"10.1287/msom.2022.0296","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.0296","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: Infectious disease screening can be expensive and capacity constrained. We develop cost- and capacity-efficient testing designs for multidisease screening, considering (1) multiplexing (disease bundling), where one assay detects multiple diseases using the same specimen (e.g., nasal swabs, blood), and (2) pooling (specimen bundling), where one assay is used on specimens from multiple subjects bundled in a testing pool. A testing design specifies an assay portfolio (mix of single-disease/multiplex assays) and a testing method (pooling/individual testing per assay). Methodology/results: We develop novel models for the nonlinear, combinatorial multidisease testing design problem: a deterministic model and a distribution-free, robust variation, which both generate Pareto frontiers for cost- and capacity-efficient designs. We characterize structural properties of optimal designs, formulate the deterministic counterpart of the robust model, and conduct a case study of respiratory diseases (including coronavirus disease 2019) with overlapping clinical presentation. Managerial implications: Key drivers of optimal designs include the assay cost function, the tester’s preference toward cost versus capacity efficiency, prevalence/coinfection rates, and for the robust model, prevalence uncertainty. When an optimal design uses multiple assays, it does so in conjunction with pooling, and it uses individual testing for at most one assay. Although prevalence uncertainty can be a design hurdle, especially for emerging or seasonal diseases, the integration of multiplexing and pooling, and the ordered partition property of optimal designs (under certain coinfection structures) serve to make the design more structurally robust to uncertainty. The robust model further increases robustness, and it is also practical as it needs only an uncertainty set around each disease prevalence. Our Pareto designs demonstrate the cost versus capacity trade-off and show that multiplexing-only or pooling-only designs need not be on the Pareto frontier. Our case study illustrates the benefits of optimally integrated designs over current practices and indicates a low price of robustness. Funding: This work was supported by the National Science Foundation [Grant 1761842]. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2022.0296 .","PeriodicalId":119284,"journal":{"name":"Manufacturing & Service Operations Management","volume":"65 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-08-08","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"133634631","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Does Social Media Dominate Government Report Cards in Influencing Nursing Home Demand? 社会媒体主导政府成绩单影响养老院需求吗?
Pub Date : 2023-08-02 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2021.0303
Yuanchen Li, Lauren Xiaoyuan Lu, S. F. Lu
Problem definition: Social media has become an indispensable platform for disseminating quality information to consumers across various service sectors. Recently, it has extended its influence to healthcare services, which traditionally relied on government report cards to disclose standardized quality information to the public. This article explores the impact of social media on consumer demand for healthcare services and compares its effectiveness with government report cards. Methodology/results: We analyze quality ratings of U.S. nursing homes collected from two information channels: (1) consumer ratings on Yelp and (2) government ratings on Nursing Home Compare, both of which adopt a five-star quality rating scale and are accessible on the Internet. We employ the method of difference-in-differences with continuous treatment intensity and instrumental variables to analyze the data. Using nursing home resident admissions as a proxy for consumer demand, we find that higher Yelp ratings led to higher consumer demand, particularly among Medicare-covered consumers. Furthermore, the effect of Yelp ratings was primarily driven by extreme ratings (one-star or five-star), as opposed to neutral ratings. We also find that Yelp ratings exerted a stronger effect on consumer demand than government ratings. This dominance of Yelp ratings over government ratings was observed primarily in markets with high Yelp penetration or markets with low and medium consumer education levels. Although higher Yelp ratings were associated with increased net incomes, we find little evidence that nursing homes made quality improvement in response to their Yelp ratings. Managerial implications: We recommend that the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services recognize social media platforms as valuable sources of information and collaborate with reputable platforms, such as Yelp, to promote public awareness of government report cards like Nursing Home Compare. Moreover, we advise nursing home operators to proactively manage their reputation on social media by promptly addressing consumer complaints and implementing quality improvement measures. Funding: Y. Li was supported by the Shanghai Sailing Program [Grant 22YF1451000] and the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities. S. F. Lu was supported by the Gerald Lyles rising star fund. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2021.0303 .
问题定义:社交媒体已经成为向各个服务部门的消费者传播高质量信息的不可或缺的平台。最近,它已将影响力扩大到医疗保健服务领域,传统上,医疗保健服务依赖政府成绩单向公众披露标准化的质量信息。本文探讨了社交媒体对消费者医疗保健服务需求的影响,并将其有效性与政府报告卡进行了比较。方法/结果:我们分析了从两个信息渠道收集的美国养老院的质量评级:(1)Yelp上的消费者评级和(2)nursing Home Compare上的政府评级,这两个信息渠道都采用了五星级的质量评级量表,并且可以在互联网上获得。我们采用连续治疗强度和工具变量的差中差法来分析数据。使用养老院居民入院率作为消费者需求的代理,我们发现更高的Yelp评级导致更高的消费者需求,特别是在医疗保险覆盖的消费者中。此外,Yelp评级的影响主要是由极端评级(一星或五星)驱动的,而不是中性评级。我们还发现Yelp评级对消费者需求的影响强于政府评级。这种Yelp评级高于政府评级的主导地位主要出现在Yelp渗透率较高的市场或消费者教育水平较低和中等的市场。虽然较高的Yelp评级与净收入增加有关,但我们发现很少有证据表明养老院在回应其Yelp评级时做出了质量改进。管理意义:我们建议医疗保险和医疗补助服务中心将社交媒体平台视为有价值的信息来源,并与Yelp等知名平台合作,以提高公众对养老院比较等政府成绩单的认识。此外,我们建议养老院经营者积极管理其在社交媒体上的声誉,及时处理消费者投诉并实施质量改进措施。基金资助:李毅获上海帆船计划[基金号:22YF1451000]和中央高校基本科研业务费专项资助。吕绍夫得到了杰拉尔德莱尔斯新星基金的支持。补充材料:在线附录可在https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2021.0303上获得。
{"title":"Does Social Media Dominate Government Report Cards in Influencing Nursing Home Demand?","authors":"Yuanchen Li, Lauren Xiaoyuan Lu, S. F. Lu","doi":"10.1287/msom.2021.0303","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2021.0303","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: Social media has become an indispensable platform for disseminating quality information to consumers across various service sectors. Recently, it has extended its influence to healthcare services, which traditionally relied on government report cards to disclose standardized quality information to the public. This article explores the impact of social media on consumer demand for healthcare services and compares its effectiveness with government report cards. Methodology/results: We analyze quality ratings of U.S. nursing homes collected from two information channels: (1) consumer ratings on Yelp and (2) government ratings on Nursing Home Compare, both of which adopt a five-star quality rating scale and are accessible on the Internet. We employ the method of difference-in-differences with continuous treatment intensity and instrumental variables to analyze the data. Using nursing home resident admissions as a proxy for consumer demand, we find that higher Yelp ratings led to higher consumer demand, particularly among Medicare-covered consumers. Furthermore, the effect of Yelp ratings was primarily driven by extreme ratings (one-star or five-star), as opposed to neutral ratings. We also find that Yelp ratings exerted a stronger effect on consumer demand than government ratings. This dominance of Yelp ratings over government ratings was observed primarily in markets with high Yelp penetration or markets with low and medium consumer education levels. Although higher Yelp ratings were associated with increased net incomes, we find little evidence that nursing homes made quality improvement in response to their Yelp ratings. Managerial implications: We recommend that the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services recognize social media platforms as valuable sources of information and collaborate with reputable platforms, such as Yelp, to promote public awareness of government report cards like Nursing Home Compare. Moreover, we advise nursing home operators to proactively manage their reputation on social media by promptly addressing consumer complaints and implementing quality improvement measures. Funding: Y. Li was supported by the Shanghai Sailing Program [Grant 22YF1451000] and the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities. S. F. Lu was supported by the Gerald Lyles rising star fund. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2021.0303 .","PeriodicalId":119284,"journal":{"name":"Manufacturing & Service Operations Management","volume":"4 1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-08-02","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"116659138","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Strategic Inventories in Competitive Supply Chains Under Bargaining 议价条件下竞争性供应链的战略库存
Pub Date : 2023-07-25 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2020.0223
L. Chen, Weijia Gu, Qinshen Tang
Problem definition: Strategic inventory refers to the inventory held by firms purely out of strategic considerations other than operational reasons (e.g., economies of scale). In this paper, we investigate the roles of strategic inventory in a system with two parallel supply chains under both full bargaining and partial bargaining, which differ in whether inventory is included in the bargaining terms. Methodology/results: (i) Under full bargaining, horizontal competition can induce an asymmetric equilibrium, whereby only one of the chains carries strategic inventory and benefits from it when the holding cost is small. The whole system, however, is worse off. (ii) Under partial bargaining, regardless of whether there is horizontal competition, the retailer in a supply chain always carries inventory when his bargaining power is small and the inventory holding cost is low. Furthermore, with horizontal competition, inventory hurts (improves) the system performance when the inventory holding cost is small (above a threshold and not too big). (iii) Full bargaining can be inferior to partial bargaining when there is horizontal competition. Managerial implications: The conventional wisdom about strategic inventory should be taken with caution. Specifically, the traditional role of strategic inventory empowering the retailer in a supply chain is completely dominated by the full bargaining framework, yet it is still present if inventory is not bargained. The inventory driven by horizontal competition plays a different strategic role of signaling to the competitor to avoid an otherwise adverse quantity competition if both retailers carried high inventory. Furthermore, despite the full cooperation nature of the full bargaining framework, it is not always in the retailer’s interest to give up the decision power on inventory (partial bargaining) and include it in the negotiation process (full bargaining). Funding: Q. Tang was supported by Nanyang Technological University [Start-Up Grant 020022-00001]. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2020.0223 .
问题定义:战略库存是指企业纯粹出于战略考虑而不考虑经营原因(如规模经济)而持有的库存。本文研究了两个平行供应链在完全议价和部分议价条件下战略库存在系统中的作用,这两种情况下库存是否包含在议价条件中是不同的。方法/结果:(i)在充分议价条件下,横向竞争会导致不对称均衡,即只有一家连锁店拥有战略库存,并在持有成本较低时从中受益。然而,整个系统的情况却更糟了。(ii)在部分议价条件下,无论是否存在横向竞争,当供应链中的零售商的议价能力较小且库存持有成本较低时,零售商总是持有库存。此外,在横向竞争中,当库存持有成本较小(高于阈值且不太大)时,库存会损害(提高)系统性能。(三)当存在横向竞争时,充分议价可能劣于部分议价。管理启示:应该谨慎对待关于战略库存的传统智慧。具体来说,在供应链中,战略库存赋予零售商的传统角色完全由完整的讨价还价框架主导,但如果库存没有讨价还价,它仍然存在。如果两家零售商都有高库存,那么横向竞争驱动下的库存将发挥不同的战略作用,向竞争对手发出信号,以避免不利的数量竞争。此外,尽管完全议价框架具有充分合作的性质,但放弃库存决策权(部分议价)并将其纳入谈判过程(完全议价)并不总是符合零售商的利益。资助:唐强获南洋理工大学[创业基金020022-00001]资助。补充材料:在线附录可在https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2020.0223上获得。
{"title":"Strategic Inventories in Competitive Supply Chains Under Bargaining","authors":"L. Chen, Weijia Gu, Qinshen Tang","doi":"10.1287/msom.2020.0223","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2020.0223","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: Strategic inventory refers to the inventory held by firms purely out of strategic considerations other than operational reasons (e.g., economies of scale). In this paper, we investigate the roles of strategic inventory in a system with two parallel supply chains under both full bargaining and partial bargaining, which differ in whether inventory is included in the bargaining terms. Methodology/results: (i) Under full bargaining, horizontal competition can induce an asymmetric equilibrium, whereby only one of the chains carries strategic inventory and benefits from it when the holding cost is small. The whole system, however, is worse off. (ii) Under partial bargaining, regardless of whether there is horizontal competition, the retailer in a supply chain always carries inventory when his bargaining power is small and the inventory holding cost is low. Furthermore, with horizontal competition, inventory hurts (improves) the system performance when the inventory holding cost is small (above a threshold and not too big). (iii) Full bargaining can be inferior to partial bargaining when there is horizontal competition. Managerial implications: The conventional wisdom about strategic inventory should be taken with caution. Specifically, the traditional role of strategic inventory empowering the retailer in a supply chain is completely dominated by the full bargaining framework, yet it is still present if inventory is not bargained. The inventory driven by horizontal competition plays a different strategic role of signaling to the competitor to avoid an otherwise adverse quantity competition if both retailers carried high inventory. Furthermore, despite the full cooperation nature of the full bargaining framework, it is not always in the retailer’s interest to give up the decision power on inventory (partial bargaining) and include it in the negotiation process (full bargaining). Funding: Q. Tang was supported by Nanyang Technological University [Start-Up Grant 020022-00001]. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2020.0223 .","PeriodicalId":119284,"journal":{"name":"Manufacturing & Service Operations Management","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-07-25","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"129323789","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The Basic Core of a Parallel Machines Scheduling Game 并行机器调度博弈的基本核心
Pub Date : 2023-07-20 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2021.0337
Tzvi Alon, Shoshana Anily
Problem definition: We consider the parallel machine scheduling (PMS) under job-splitting game defined by a set of manufacturers where each holds uniform parallel machines and each is committed to produce some jobs submitted to her by her clients while bearing the cost of the sum of completion times of her jobs on her machines. An efficient algorithm for this scheduling problem is well known. We consider the corresponding cooperative game, where the manufacturers are players that want to join forces. We show that collaboration is profitable. Yet, the stability of the cooperation depends on the cost allocation scheme; we focus on the core of the game. Methodology/results: We prove that the PMS game is totally balanced and its core is infinitely large, by developing a sophisticated methodology of linear complexity that finds a line segment in its symmetric core. We call this segment the basic core of the game. Managerial implications: This PMS game has the potential for various applications both in traditional industry and in distributed computing systems in the hi-tech industry. The formation of a partnership among entrepreneurs, companies, or manufacturers necessitates not only a plan for joining forces toward the achievement of the ultimate goals, but also an acceptable agreement regarding the cost allocation among the partners. Core allocations guarantee the stability of the partnership as no subset of players can gain by defecting from the grand coalition. Funding: This work was supported by the Henry Crown Israeli Institute for Business Research, the Coller Foundation, and the Israel Science Foundation [Grant 1489/19].
问题定义:考虑作业分配博弈下的并行机调度(PMS)问题,该问题由一组制造商定义,其中每个制造商都拥有均匀的并行机,每个制造商都承诺生产客户提交给她的一些作业,同时承担自己的作业在自己的机器上完成的时间总和的成本。对于这个调度问题,一个有效的算法是众所周知的。我们考虑相应的合作博弈,其中制造商是想要联合起来的玩家。我们表明合作是有利可图的。然而,合作的稳定性取决于成本分配方案;我们专注于游戏的核心。方法/结果:我们证明PMS游戏是完全平衡的,它的核心是无限大的,通过开发一种复杂的线性复杂性方法,在其对称核心中找到线段。我们将此部分称为游戏的基本核心。管理意义:这个PMS游戏在传统工业和高科技工业的分布式计算系统中都有各种应用的潜力。企业家、公司或制造商之间的伙伴关系的形成不仅需要一个为实现最终目标而联合力量的计划,而且还需要一个关于伙伴之间成本分配的可接受的协议。核心分配保证了合作伙伴关系的稳定性,因为没有玩家的子集可以通过背叛大联盟而获益。资助:这项工作得到了Henry Crown以色列商业研究所、Coller基金会和以色列科学基金会的支持[Grant 1489/19]。
{"title":"The Basic Core of a Parallel Machines Scheduling Game","authors":"Tzvi Alon, Shoshana Anily","doi":"10.1287/msom.2021.0337","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2021.0337","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: We consider the parallel machine scheduling (PMS) under job-splitting game defined by a set of manufacturers where each holds uniform parallel machines and each is committed to produce some jobs submitted to her by her clients while bearing the cost of the sum of completion times of her jobs on her machines. An efficient algorithm for this scheduling problem is well known. We consider the corresponding cooperative game, where the manufacturers are players that want to join forces. We show that collaboration is profitable. Yet, the stability of the cooperation depends on the cost allocation scheme; we focus on the core of the game. Methodology/results: We prove that the PMS game is totally balanced and its core is infinitely large, by developing a sophisticated methodology of linear complexity that finds a line segment in its symmetric core. We call this segment the basic core of the game. Managerial implications: This PMS game has the potential for various applications both in traditional industry and in distributed computing systems in the hi-tech industry. The formation of a partnership among entrepreneurs, companies, or manufacturers necessitates not only a plan for joining forces toward the achievement of the ultimate goals, but also an acceptable agreement regarding the cost allocation among the partners. Core allocations guarantee the stability of the partnership as no subset of players can gain by defecting from the grand coalition. Funding: This work was supported by the Henry Crown Israeli Institute for Business Research, the Coller Foundation, and the Israel Science Foundation [Grant 1489/19].","PeriodicalId":119284,"journal":{"name":"Manufacturing & Service Operations Management","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-07-20","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"128799784","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Interpretable Policies and the Price of Interpretability in Hypertension Treatment Planning 高血压治疗计划的可解释性政策和可解释性的代价
Pub Date : 2023-07-18 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2021.0373
Gian-Gabriel P. Garcia, L. Steimle, Wesley J. Marrero, J. Sussman
Problem definition: Effective hypertension management is critical to reducing the consequences of atherosclerotic cardiovascular disease, a leading cause of death in the United States. Clinical guidelines for hypertension can be enhanced using decision-analytic approaches capable of capturing complexities in treatment planning. However, model-generated recommendations may be uninterpretable/unintuitive, limiting their clinical acceptability. We address this challenge by investigating interpretable treatment plans. Methodology/results: We formulate interpretable treatment plans as Markov decision processes (MDPs) and analyze the problems of optimizing monotone policies, which prohibit decreasing treatment intensity for sicker patients, and class-ordered monotone policies, which generalize monotone policies. We establish that both policies depend on initial state distributions and that optimal monotone policies can be generated tractably for many treatment planning problems. Next, we propose exact formulations for optimizing interpretable policies broadly. Then, we analyze the price of interpretability, proving that the class-ordered monotone policy’s price of interpretability does not exceed the monotone policy’s price of interpretability. Finally, we formulate and evaluate MDPs for hypertension treatment planning using a large nationally representative data set of the U.S. population. We compare the structure and performance of optimal monotone policies and class-ordered monotone policies with optimal MDP-based policies and current clinical guidelines. At the patient level, optimal MDP-based policies may be unintuitive, recommending more aggressive treatment for healthier patients than sicker patients. Conversely, monotone policies and class-ordered monotone policies never deescalate treatment, reflecting clinical intuition. Across 66.5 million patients, optimized monotone policies and class-ordered monotone policies outperform clinical guidelines, saving over 3,246 quality-adjusted life years per 100,000 patients, with both policies paying a low price of interpretability. Sensitivity analysis illustrates that monotone policies and class-ordered monotone policies are robust to various definitions of “interpretability.” Managerial implications: Interpretable policies can be tractably optimized, drastically outperform existing guidelines, and perform near optimally—potentially increasing the acceptability of decision-analytic approaches in practice. Funding: L. N. Steimle and W. J. Marrero received support from the National Science Foundation Graduate Research Fellowship [Grant DGE 1256260]. J. B. Sussman received support from the National Institutes of Health [Grants R01NS102715 and RF1AG068410], the U.S. Department of Veterans Affairs [Grants 1I01-HX003304 and 1I50-HX003251], and the Michigan Department of Health and Human Services. Supplemental Material: The e-companion is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2021.0373 .
问题定义:有效的高血压管理对于减少动脉粥样硬化性心血管疾病的后果至关重要,动脉粥样硬化性心血管疾病是美国的主要死亡原因。高血压的临床指南可以通过决策分析方法来加强,这些决策分析方法能够捕捉到治疗计划中的复杂性。然而,模型生成的建议可能无法解释/不直观,限制了它们的临床可接受性。我们通过研究可解释的治疗方案来解决这一挑战。方法/结果:我们将可解释的治疗计划制定为马尔可夫决策过程(mdp),并分析了单调政策的优化问题,单调政策禁止对病情较重的患者降低治疗强度,类有序单调政策推广单调政策。我们建立了这两种策略都依赖于初始状态分布,并且对于许多治疗计划问题可以生成可跟踪的最优单调策略。接下来,我们提出了广泛优化可解释策略的精确公式。然后,我们分析了可解释性的价格,证明了类序单调策略的可解释性价格不超过单调策略的可解释性价格。最后,我们使用具有全国代表性的美国人口数据集来制定和评估高血压治疗计划的mdp。我们比较了最优单调策略和类有序单调策略的结构和性能,以及基于mdp的最优策略和当前临床指南。在患者层面,基于mdp的最佳政策可能不直观,建议对健康的患者进行比病情较重的患者更积极的治疗。相反,单调政策和分类有序单调政策从不降低治疗的级别,这反映了临床直觉。在6650万名患者中,优化的单调政策和分类有序的单调政策优于临床指南,每10万名患者节省了3246个质量调整生命年,两种政策的可解释性都很低。敏感性分析表明,单调策略和类有序单调策略对各种“可解释性”定义都具有鲁棒性。管理意义:可解释的策略可以被跟踪优化,大大超过现有的指导方针,并执行接近最优-潜在地增加决策分析方法在实践中的可接受性。资助:L. N. Steimle和W. J. Marrero获得了美国国家科学基金会研究生研究奖学金[Grant DGE 1256260]的支持。J. B. Sussman得到了美国国立卫生研究院[赠款R01NS102715和RF1AG068410]、美国退伍军人事务部[赠款1I01-HX003304和1I50-HX003251]和密歇根州卫生与公众服务部的支持。补充材料:电子伴侣可在https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2021.0373上获得。
{"title":"Interpretable Policies and the Price of Interpretability in Hypertension Treatment Planning","authors":"Gian-Gabriel P. Garcia, L. Steimle, Wesley J. Marrero, J. Sussman","doi":"10.1287/msom.2021.0373","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2021.0373","url":null,"abstract":"Problem definition: Effective hypertension management is critical to reducing the consequences of atherosclerotic cardiovascular disease, a leading cause of death in the United States. Clinical guidelines for hypertension can be enhanced using decision-analytic approaches capable of capturing complexities in treatment planning. However, model-generated recommendations may be uninterpretable/unintuitive, limiting their clinical acceptability. We address this challenge by investigating interpretable treatment plans. Methodology/results: We formulate interpretable treatment plans as Markov decision processes (MDPs) and analyze the problems of optimizing monotone policies, which prohibit decreasing treatment intensity for sicker patients, and class-ordered monotone policies, which generalize monotone policies. We establish that both policies depend on initial state distributions and that optimal monotone policies can be generated tractably for many treatment planning problems. Next, we propose exact formulations for optimizing interpretable policies broadly. Then, we analyze the price of interpretability, proving that the class-ordered monotone policy’s price of interpretability does not exceed the monotone policy’s price of interpretability. Finally, we formulate and evaluate MDPs for hypertension treatment planning using a large nationally representative data set of the U.S. population. We compare the structure and performance of optimal monotone policies and class-ordered monotone policies with optimal MDP-based policies and current clinical guidelines. At the patient level, optimal MDP-based policies may be unintuitive, recommending more aggressive treatment for healthier patients than sicker patients. Conversely, monotone policies and class-ordered monotone policies never deescalate treatment, reflecting clinical intuition. Across 66.5 million patients, optimized monotone policies and class-ordered monotone policies outperform clinical guidelines, saving over 3,246 quality-adjusted life years per 100,000 patients, with both policies paying a low price of interpretability. Sensitivity analysis illustrates that monotone policies and class-ordered monotone policies are robust to various definitions of “interpretability.” Managerial implications: Interpretable policies can be tractably optimized, drastically outperform existing guidelines, and perform near optimally—potentially increasing the acceptability of decision-analytic approaches in practice. Funding: L. N. Steimle and W. J. Marrero received support from the National Science Foundation Graduate Research Fellowship [Grant DGE 1256260]. J. B. Sussman received support from the National Institutes of Health [Grants R01NS102715 and RF1AG068410], the U.S. Department of Veterans Affairs [Grants 1I01-HX003304 and 1I50-HX003251], and the Michigan Department of Health and Human Services. Supplemental Material: The e-companion is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2021.0373 .","PeriodicalId":119284,"journal":{"name":"Manufacturing & Service Operations Management","volume":"62 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-07-18","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"134240764","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4
Inventory Sharing Under Service Competition 服务竞争下的库存共享
Pub Date : 2023-07-17 DOI: 10.1287/msom.2020.0584
Xiaomeng Guo, Baojun Jiang
Problem description: In many markets with demand uncertainties, competing retailers may share inventories for common products that they offer consumers. This paper examines how competitors’ product sharing affects their inventory and service-quality decisions. The existing literature has mainly focused on inventory sharing among independent retailers who do not compete with each other. Our research aims to fill the gap in this literature by investigating the tradeoffs of inventory sharing between retailers who directly compete for customers based on service quality. Methodology/results: We develop a game-theoretical model in which two retailers selling a common product from the same manufacturer compete for customers by offering differentiated services together with the product. Each retailer faces stochastic demand that increases in its service quality and decreases in the competitor’s service quality. When a retailer runs out of stock of the product, it may replenish its inventory directly from the manufacturer and/or request the competitor’s excess inventory if they have an inventory-sharing agreement. We find that inventory sharing may soften or intensify service competition, depending on the transfer price for the shared inventory. Specifically, when retailers agree to share inventory, their service levels decrease in the transfer price if their preseason inventory levels are exogenous, but are nonmonotone in the transfer price if the retailers endogenously choose inventory levels. Moreover, our analysis reveals that the retailers’ equilibrium inventory levels will increase in the transfer price and can be higher or lower than their levels in the case without inventory sharing. We also find that with exogenous inventory, the retailers prefer to share inventory at the highest nonmoot transfer price, whereas with endogenous inventory, the retailers may prefer not to share inventory, even at the optimal transfer price, when the level of competition and the preorder cost are high. Finally, we show that with service competition, inventory sharing cannot achieve full coordination under any transfer price. Managerial implications: When deciding whether to share inventory with competitors, managers should consider not only the benefits of inventory pooling, but also the strategic effect of sharing on the firms’ inventory choices and service levels. Funding: X. Guo has received research support from the Research Grants Council of Hong Kong [RGC Reference No. 15501820]. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2020.0584 .
问题描述:在许多需求不确定的市场中,相互竞争的零售商可能会共享他们提供给消费者的共同产品的库存。本文考察了竞争对手的产品共享如何影响他们的库存和服务质量决策。现有文献主要关注不相互竞争的独立零售商之间的库存共享。我们的研究旨在通过调查基于服务质量直接竞争客户的零售商之间的库存共享权衡来填补这一文献的空白。方法/结果:我们建立了一个博弈论模型,其中两个零售商销售来自同一制造商的共同产品,通过提供差异化的服务和产品来争夺客户。每个零售商都面临随机需求,这种随机需求使零售商的服务质量提高,而竞争对手的服务质量下降。当零售商的产品库存耗尽时,它可以直接从制造商那里补充库存,或者在竞争对手有库存共享协议的情况下,要求竞争对手提供多余的库存。我们发现,库存共享可能会减弱或加剧服务竞争,这取决于共享库存的转让价格。具体而言,当零售商同意共享库存时,如果零售商的季前库存水平是外生的,那么零售商的服务水平在转移价格中会下降,但如果零售商内生地选择库存水平,则其服务水平在转移价格中是非单调的。此外,我们的分析表明,零售商的均衡库存水平会随着转移价格的增加而增加,并且在没有库存共享的情况下可以高于或低于他们的水平。我们还发现,对于外生库存,零售商倾向于在最高的无争议转移价格下共享库存,而对于内生库存,即使在竞争水平和预购成本较高的最优转移价格下,零售商也可能不愿意共享库存。最后表明,在服务竞争的情况下,在任何转让价格下,库存共享都不能达到充分协调。管理启示:当决定是否与竞争对手共享库存时,管理者不仅要考虑库存池的好处,还要考虑共享对公司库存选择和服务水平的战略影响。基金资助:郭欣获得香港研究资助局的研究资助[研资局参考编号:15501820]。补充材料:在线附录可在https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2020.0584上获得。
{"title":"Inventory Sharing Under Service Competition","authors":"Xiaomeng Guo, Baojun Jiang","doi":"10.1287/msom.2020.0584","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2020.0584","url":null,"abstract":"Problem description: In many markets with demand uncertainties, competing retailers may share inventories for common products that they offer consumers. This paper examines how competitors’ product sharing affects their inventory and service-quality decisions. The existing literature has mainly focused on inventory sharing among independent retailers who do not compete with each other. Our research aims to fill the gap in this literature by investigating the tradeoffs of inventory sharing between retailers who directly compete for customers based on service quality. Methodology/results: We develop a game-theoretical model in which two retailers selling a common product from the same manufacturer compete for customers by offering differentiated services together with the product. Each retailer faces stochastic demand that increases in its service quality and decreases in the competitor’s service quality. When a retailer runs out of stock of the product, it may replenish its inventory directly from the manufacturer and/or request the competitor’s excess inventory if they have an inventory-sharing agreement. We find that inventory sharing may soften or intensify service competition, depending on the transfer price for the shared inventory. Specifically, when retailers agree to share inventory, their service levels decrease in the transfer price if their preseason inventory levels are exogenous, but are nonmonotone in the transfer price if the retailers endogenously choose inventory levels. Moreover, our analysis reveals that the retailers’ equilibrium inventory levels will increase in the transfer price and can be higher or lower than their levels in the case without inventory sharing. We also find that with exogenous inventory, the retailers prefer to share inventory at the highest nonmoot transfer price, whereas with endogenous inventory, the retailers may prefer not to share inventory, even at the optimal transfer price, when the level of competition and the preorder cost are high. Finally, we show that with service competition, inventory sharing cannot achieve full coordination under any transfer price. Managerial implications: When deciding whether to share inventory with competitors, managers should consider not only the benefits of inventory pooling, but also the strategic effect of sharing on the firms’ inventory choices and service levels. Funding: X. Guo has received research support from the Research Grants Council of Hong Kong [RGC Reference No. 15501820]. Supplemental Material: The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2020.0584 .","PeriodicalId":119284,"journal":{"name":"Manufacturing & Service Operations Management","volume":"11 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-07-17","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"125577303","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Manufacturing & Service Operations Management
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1