首页 > 最新文献

Proceedings of the 23rd ACM Conference on Economics and Computation最新文献

英文 中文
Asymmetric Taxation, Pass-through and Market Competition: Evidence from Ride-sharing and Taxis 不对称税收、传递与市场竞争:来自拼车和出租车的证据
Pub Date : 2022-07-12 DOI: 10.1145/3490486.3538245
Mario Leccese
When deciding whether to tax a product, policymakers need to consider the effects of the intervention on price and output. While the existing literature focuses on “symmetric taxes,” i.e., on schemes imposing the same tax amount on all products in the market, in practice, some taxes are “asymmetric”, in the sense that they levy different amounts on competing products, or even affect only a subset of them. Since the equilibrium responses to asymmetric taxes are going to affect the relative prices of different products in the market, asymmetric taxes can have large effects on competition and market outcomes. The goal of this paper is to study empirically the effects of asymmetric taxes on market outcomes. In January 2020, nominally motivated by a desire to reduce congestion and raise revenues for the city budget, the city of Chicago taxed ride-sharing (e.g., Uber and Lyft) but did not impose any surcharge to riders taking rides with traditional taxis. By taxing ride-sharing up to $3.00 per trip, this policy imposed the highest surcharge faced by ride-sharing companies in the US, providing an informative case study to investigate the consequences of asymmetric taxes. First, I investigate the pass-through rate of the tax on ride-sharing. Ride-sharing companies are peer-to-peer marketplaces which connect riders to drivers. This generates additional insights to the analysis of pass-through because the reduction in demand following a tax levied on riders can reduce drivers’ willingness to supply rides, which, in turn, increases the equilibrium price of ride-sharing. This means that, in a two-sided market, indirect network effects make it easier to rationalize tax overshifting than it would be in a conventional one-sided firm analysis. Second, I quantify the extent to which the tax shifts demand back to traditional taxis, and how this effect varies across different areas of the city. This sheds light on the substitutability between traditional taxis and ride-sharing and on its determinants. Third, I consider the effect of the policy on congestion. In fact, the exacerbation of congestion is a critical issue in many large and growing metropolitan areas, and congestion taxes have been a widely used tool to reduce traffic. Finally, I study the impact of the tax on consumer welfare, by developing and calibrating a logit demand framework that accommodates asymmetric tax schedules. The results of my analyses provide evidence that the tax on ride-sharing had economically significant effects on markets outcomes. Consistently with the existence of indirect network effects, I estimate pass-through rates exceeding unity on single rides, while for shared rides I find incomplete pass-through. This pattern can be explained by a higher elasticity of demand for shared rides as compared to single ones. The change in prices of ride-sharing shifts demand back to traditional taxis but only for downtown rides, where the number of equilibrium taxi pickups increases by 3.63%. T
在决定是否对某种产品征税时,政策制定者需要考虑干预对价格和产出的影响。虽然现有文献关注的是“对称税”,即对市场上所有产品征收相同税额的方案,但在实践中,有些税是“不对称的”,也就是说,它们对竞争产品征收不同的税额,甚至只影响其中的一部分。由于对不对称税收的均衡反应将影响市场上不同产品的相对价格,因此不对称税收对竞争和市场结果有很大的影响。本文的目的是实证研究不对称税收对市场结果的影响。2020年1月,名义上是出于减少拥堵和增加城市预算收入的愿望,芝加芝加市对拼车(如优步和Lyft)征税,但没有对乘坐传统出租车的乘客征收任何附加费。这项政策对拼车服务每趟最高征收3美元的附加费,是美国拼车公司面临的最高附加费,为调查不对称税收的后果提供了一个翔实的案例研究。首先,我调查了拼车税的传递率。拼车公司是将乘客和司机联系起来的点对点市场。这为传递分析提供了额外的见解,因为对乘客征税后需求的减少会降低司机提供乘车服务的意愿,这反过来又会提高拼车的均衡价格。这意味着,在双边市场中,与传统的单边企业分析相比,间接网络效应使税收过度转移更容易合理化。其次,我量化了税收将需求转移回传统出租车的程度,以及这种影响在城市不同地区的差异。这揭示了传统出租车与拼车之间的可替代性及其决定因素。第三,我考虑了交通拥堵政策的影响。事实上,在许多大型和发展中的大都市地区,拥堵加剧是一个关键问题,拥堵税已被广泛使用来减少交通。最后,我研究了税收对消费者福利的影响,通过开发和校准一个逻辑需求框架,以适应不对称的税收时间表。我的分析结果提供了证据,证明对拼车征税对市场结果具有显著的经济影响。与间接网络效应的存在一致,我估计单次乘车的传递率超过统一,而对于共享乘车,我发现传递率不完全。这种模式可以解释为,与单独出行相比,共享出行的需求弹性更高。拼车价格的变化将需求转移回传统出租车,但仅限于市中心,在市中心,均衡的出租车接送数量增加了3.63%。这与市区拼车服务和传统出租车服务之间的激烈竞争是一致的。总的来说,这项税收重塑了芝加哥的乘车需求,但没有减少拼车和出租车的每日总出行次数。因此,对拥堵没有明显的影响。最后,将市场份额重新分配给出租车是以减少消费者剩余为代价的,估计每趟市中心和非市中心的损失分别为1.74美元和0.49美元。
{"title":"Asymmetric Taxation, Pass-through and Market Competition: Evidence from Ride-sharing and Taxis","authors":"Mario Leccese","doi":"10.1145/3490486.3538245","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1145/3490486.3538245","url":null,"abstract":"When deciding whether to tax a product, policymakers need to consider the effects of the intervention on price and output. While the existing literature focuses on “symmetric taxes,” i.e., on schemes imposing the same tax amount on all products in the market, in practice, some taxes are “asymmetric”, in the sense that they levy different amounts on competing products, or even affect only a subset of them. Since the equilibrium responses to asymmetric taxes are going to affect the relative prices of different products in the market, asymmetric taxes can have large effects on competition and market outcomes. The goal of this paper is to study empirically the effects of asymmetric taxes on market outcomes. In January 2020, nominally motivated by a desire to reduce congestion and raise revenues for the city budget, the city of Chicago taxed ride-sharing (e.g., Uber and Lyft) but did not impose any surcharge to riders taking rides with traditional taxis. By taxing ride-sharing up to $3.00 per trip, this policy imposed the highest surcharge faced by ride-sharing companies in the US, providing an informative case study to investigate the consequences of asymmetric taxes. First, I investigate the pass-through rate of the tax on ride-sharing. Ride-sharing companies are peer-to-peer marketplaces which connect riders to drivers. This generates additional insights to the analysis of pass-through because the reduction in demand following a tax levied on riders can reduce drivers’ willingness to supply rides, which, in turn, increases the equilibrium price of ride-sharing. This means that, in a two-sided market, indirect network effects make it easier to rationalize tax overshifting than it would be in a conventional one-sided firm analysis. Second, I quantify the extent to which the tax shifts demand back to traditional taxis, and how this effect varies across different areas of the city. This sheds light on the substitutability between traditional taxis and ride-sharing and on its determinants. Third, I consider the effect of the policy on congestion. In fact, the exacerbation of congestion is a critical issue in many large and growing metropolitan areas, and congestion taxes have been a widely used tool to reduce traffic. Finally, I study the impact of the tax on consumer welfare, by developing and calibrating a logit demand framework that accommodates asymmetric tax schedules. The results of my analyses provide evidence that the tax on ride-sharing had economically significant effects on markets outcomes. Consistently with the existence of indirect network effects, I estimate pass-through rates exceeding unity on single rides, while for shared rides I find incomplete pass-through. This pattern can be explained by a higher elasticity of demand for shared rides as compared to single ones. The change in prices of ride-sharing shifts demand back to traditional taxis but only for downtown rides, where the number of equilibrium taxi pickups increases by 3.63%. T","PeriodicalId":209859,"journal":{"name":"Proceedings of the 23rd ACM Conference on Economics and Computation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-07-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"122468532","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Blockchain Stretching & Squeezing: Manipulating Time for Your Best Interest 区块链拉伸与挤压:为您的最佳利益操纵时间
Pub Date : 2022-07-12 DOI: 10.1145/3490486.3538250
Aviv Yaish, Saar Tochner, Aviv Zohar
We present a novel way for cryptocurrency miners to manipulate the effective interest-rate on loans or deposits they make on decentralized finance (DeFi) platforms by manipulating difficulty-adjustment algorithms (DAAs) and changing the block-rate. This presents a new class of strategic manipulations available to miners. These manipulations allow miners to stretch and squeeze the time between consecutive blocks. We analyze these manipulations both analytically and empirically, and show that a 25% miner can stretch the time between consecutive blocks by up to 54% in Ethereum and 33% in Bitcoin, and squeeze it by up to 9% in Ethereum. Ethereum is particularly vulnerable, and even relatively small miners can seriously affect the block-rate. An interesting application of these manipulations is to create an artificial interest-rate gap between loans taken from one DeFi platform which accrues interest according to block height (such as Compound [66]) and deposited in some other platform that does so according to elapsed time (like a bank, or other DeFi platforms such as Aave [99]). Hence, stretching and squeezing the block-rate can decrease the interest paid on DeFi loans relative to external financial platforms. The profit made from this interest-rate gap provides a large incentive for miners to deviate. For example, a 25% Ethereum miner using our manipulations can increase mining profits by up to 35%, even after taking potential losses into consideration, such as less block-rewards. Our analysis of these manipulations and their mitigations has broad implications with regards to commonly-used cryptocurrency mechanisms and paradigms, such as Ethereum's difficulty-adjustment algorithm and reward schemes, with Ethereum's handling of uncle blocks being particularly manipulable. Interestingly, Bitcoin's mechanism is more resistant Ethereum's, owing to its larger incentives and a more resilient DAA.
我们提出了一种新颖的方法,让加密货币矿工通过操纵难度调整算法(DAAs)和改变区块利率来操纵他们在去中心化金融(DeFi)平台上的贷款或存款的有效利率。这为矿工们提供了一种新的战略操作。这些操作允许矿工在连续的区块之间延长和压缩时间。我们对这些操作进行了分析和经验分析,并表明25%的矿工可以将连续区块之间的时间在以太坊中延长54%,在比特币中延长33%,并在以太坊中将其压缩9%。以太坊特别脆弱,即使是相对较小的矿工也会严重影响区块率。这些操作的一个有趣的应用是在从一个DeFi平台提取的贷款(根据区块高度(如Compound[66])产生利息)和存入其他根据经过时间(如银行或其他DeFi平台(如Aave[99]))的其他平台之间创造一个人为的利率差距。因此,相对于外部金融平台,扩大和压缩整体利率可以降低DeFi贷款支付的利息。从这种利率差距中获得的利润为矿业公司提供了很大的偏离利率的动力。例如,一个25%的以太坊矿工使用我们的操作可以增加采矿利润高达35%,即使考虑到潜在的损失,比如更少的区块奖励。我们对这些操纵及其缓解措施的分析对常用的加密货币机制和范式具有广泛的影响,例如以太坊的难度调整算法和奖励计划,以太坊对叔块的处理特别容易操纵。有趣的是,比特币的机制更具抵抗力,因为它有更大的激励和更有弹性的DAA。
{"title":"Blockchain Stretching & Squeezing: Manipulating Time for Your Best Interest","authors":"Aviv Yaish, Saar Tochner, Aviv Zohar","doi":"10.1145/3490486.3538250","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1145/3490486.3538250","url":null,"abstract":"We present a novel way for cryptocurrency miners to manipulate the effective interest-rate on loans or deposits they make on decentralized finance (DeFi) platforms by manipulating difficulty-adjustment algorithms (DAAs) and changing the block-rate. This presents a new class of strategic manipulations available to miners. These manipulations allow miners to stretch and squeeze the time between consecutive blocks. We analyze these manipulations both analytically and empirically, and show that a 25% miner can stretch the time between consecutive blocks by up to 54% in Ethereum and 33% in Bitcoin, and squeeze it by up to 9% in Ethereum. Ethereum is particularly vulnerable, and even relatively small miners can seriously affect the block-rate. An interesting application of these manipulations is to create an artificial interest-rate gap between loans taken from one DeFi platform which accrues interest according to block height (such as Compound [66]) and deposited in some other platform that does so according to elapsed time (like a bank, or other DeFi platforms such as Aave [99]). Hence, stretching and squeezing the block-rate can decrease the interest paid on DeFi loans relative to external financial platforms. The profit made from this interest-rate gap provides a large incentive for miners to deviate. For example, a 25% Ethereum miner using our manipulations can increase mining profits by up to 35%, even after taking potential losses into consideration, such as less block-rewards. Our analysis of these manipulations and their mitigations has broad implications with regards to commonly-used cryptocurrency mechanisms and paradigms, such as Ethereum's difficulty-adjustment algorithm and reward schemes, with Ethereum's handling of uncle blocks being particularly manipulable. Interestingly, Bitcoin's mechanism is more resistant Ethereum's, owing to its larger incentives and a more resilient DAA.","PeriodicalId":209859,"journal":{"name":"Proceedings of the 23rd ACM Conference on Economics and Computation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-07-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"126793076","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 19
A System-Level Analysis of Conference Peer Review 会议同行评议的系统级分析
Pub Date : 2022-07-12 DOI: 10.1145/3490486.3538235
Yichi Zhang, Fang-Yi Yu, G. Schoenebeck, D. Kempe
We undertake a system-level analysis of the conference peer review process. The process involves three constituencies with different objectives: authors want their papers accepted at prestigious venues (and quickly), conferences want to present a program with many high-quality and few low-quality papers, and reviewers want to avoid being overburdened by reviews. These objectives are far from aligned; the key obstacle is that the evaluation of the merits of a submission (both by the authors and the reviewers) is inherently noisy. Over the years, conferences have experimented with numerous policies and innovations to navigate the tradeoffs. These experiments include setting various bars for acceptance, varying the number of reviews per submission, requiring prior reviews to be included with resubmissions, and others. The purpose of the present work is to investigate, both analytically and using agent-based simulations, how well various policies work, and more importantly, why they do or do not work. We model the conference-author interactions as a Stackelberg game in which a prestigious conference commits to a threshold acceptance policy which will be applied to the (noisy) reviews of each submitted paper; the authors best-respond by submitting or not submitting to the conference, the alternative being a "sure accept" (such as arXiv or a lightly refereed venue). Our findings include: observing that the conference should typically set a higher acceptance threshold than the actual desired quality, which we call the resubmission gap and quantify in terms of various parameters; observing that the reviewing load is heavily driven by resubmissions of borderline papers --- therefore, a judicious choice of acceptance threshold may lead to fewer reviews while incurring an acceptable loss in quality; observing that depending on the paper quality distribution, stricter reviewing may lead to higher or lower acceptance rates --- the former is the result of self selection by the authors. As a rule of thumb, a relatively small number of reviews per paper, coupled with a strict acceptance policy, tends to do well in trading off these two objectives; finding that a relatively small increase in review quality or in self assessment by the authors is much more effective for conference quality control (without a large increase in review burden) than increases in the quantity of reviews per paper.; showing that keeping track of past reviews of papers can help reduce the review burden without a decrease in conference quality. For robustness, we consider different models of paper quality and learn some of the parameters from real data.
我们对会议同行评议过程进行系统级分析。这个过程涉及三个具有不同目标的群体:作者希望他们的论文在著名的场所被接受(而且要快),会议希望展示一个有很多高质量论文和很少低质量论文的项目,审稿人希望避免审稿负担过重。这些目标远非一致;关键的障碍是(作者和审稿人)对提交的优点的评估本身就是嘈杂的。多年来,会议已经尝试了许多政策和创新,以应对权衡。这些实验包括设置不同的接受标准,改变每次提交的审查数量,要求在重新提交时包含先前的审查,等等。当前工作的目的是通过分析和使用基于代理的模拟来调查各种策略的工作效果,更重要的是,为什么它们起作用或不起作用。我们将会议与作者的互动建模为Stackelberg游戏,其中一个著名的会议承诺一个阈值接受政策,该政策将应用于每一篇提交论文的(嘈杂的)评论;作者最好的回应是提交或不提交会议,另一种选择是“确定接受”(如arXiv或轻度评审的地点)。我们的发现包括:观察到会议通常应该设定比实际期望质量更高的接受阈值,我们称之为重新提交差距,并根据各种参数进行量化;观察到审稿负荷很大程度上是由边缘论文的重新提交驱动的——因此,明智地选择接受阈值可能会导致审稿减少,同时导致可接受的质量损失;观察到根据论文质量分布的不同,更严格的审稿可能导致更高或更低的接受率——前者是作者自我选择的结果。根据经验,每篇论文相对较少的评论,加上严格的接受政策,往往可以很好地权衡这两个目标;发现相对较小的评审质量或作者自我评估的提高对会议质量控制(不增加评审负担)比每篇论文评审数量的增加更有效。表明跟踪过去的论文评审可以在不降低会议质量的情况下帮助减轻评审负担。为了提高鲁棒性,我们考虑了不同的纸张质量模型,并从实际数据中学习了一些参数。
{"title":"A System-Level Analysis of Conference Peer Review","authors":"Yichi Zhang, Fang-Yi Yu, G. Schoenebeck, D. Kempe","doi":"10.1145/3490486.3538235","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1145/3490486.3538235","url":null,"abstract":"We undertake a system-level analysis of the conference peer review process. The process involves three constituencies with different objectives: authors want their papers accepted at prestigious venues (and quickly), conferences want to present a program with many high-quality and few low-quality papers, and reviewers want to avoid being overburdened by reviews. These objectives are far from aligned; the key obstacle is that the evaluation of the merits of a submission (both by the authors and the reviewers) is inherently noisy. Over the years, conferences have experimented with numerous policies and innovations to navigate the tradeoffs. These experiments include setting various bars for acceptance, varying the number of reviews per submission, requiring prior reviews to be included with resubmissions, and others. The purpose of the present work is to investigate, both analytically and using agent-based simulations, how well various policies work, and more importantly, why they do or do not work. We model the conference-author interactions as a Stackelberg game in which a prestigious conference commits to a threshold acceptance policy which will be applied to the (noisy) reviews of each submitted paper; the authors best-respond by submitting or not submitting to the conference, the alternative being a \"sure accept\" (such as arXiv or a lightly refereed venue). Our findings include: observing that the conference should typically set a higher acceptance threshold than the actual desired quality, which we call the resubmission gap and quantify in terms of various parameters; observing that the reviewing load is heavily driven by resubmissions of borderline papers --- therefore, a judicious choice of acceptance threshold may lead to fewer reviews while incurring an acceptable loss in quality; observing that depending on the paper quality distribution, stricter reviewing may lead to higher or lower acceptance rates --- the former is the result of self selection by the authors. As a rule of thumb, a relatively small number of reviews per paper, coupled with a strict acceptance policy, tends to do well in trading off these two objectives; finding that a relatively small increase in review quality or in self assessment by the authors is much more effective for conference quality control (without a large increase in review burden) than increases in the quantity of reviews per paper.; showing that keeping track of past reviews of papers can help reduce the review burden without a decrease in conference quality. For robustness, we consider different models of paper quality and learn some of the parameters from real data.","PeriodicalId":209859,"journal":{"name":"Proceedings of the 23rd ACM Conference on Economics and Computation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-07-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"124193009","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Robustly Optimal Auction Design under Mean Constraints 均值约束下的稳健最优拍卖设计
Pub Date : 2022-07-12 DOI: 10.1145/3490486.3538357
Ethan Che
We study a seller who sells a single good to multiple bidders with uncertainty over the joint distribution of bidders' valuations, as well as bidders' higher-order beliefs about their opponents. The seller only knows the (possibly asymmetric) means of the marginal distributions of each bidder's valuation and the range. An adversarial nature chooses the worst-case distribution within this ambiguity set along with the worst-case information structure. We find that a second-price auction with a symmetric, random reserve price obtains the optimal revenue guarantee within a broad class of mechanisms we refer to as competitive mechanisms, which include standard auction formats such as the first-price auction. The optimal mechanism possesses two notable characteristics. First, the mechanism treats all bidders identically even in the presence of ex-ante asymmetries. Second, when bidders have identical means and the number of bidders n grows large, the seller's optimal reserve price converges in probability to a non-binding reserve price and the revenue guarantee converges to the mean at rate O(1/n).
我们研究了一个将单一商品出售给多个竞标者的卖家,在竞标者估值的共同分布以及竞标者对其对手的高阶信念方面存在不确定性。卖方只知道(可能不对称的)每个竞标者估值的边际分布和范围。一个对抗性的性质选择最坏情况分布与最坏情况的信息结构在这个模糊集中。我们发现,具有对称随机底价的第二价格拍卖在我们称之为竞争机制的广泛机制类别中获得了最优收益保证,其中包括标准拍卖格式,如第一价格拍卖。最优机制具有两个显著特征。首先,该机制对所有竞标者一视同仁,即使存在事前不对称。其次,当投标人均值相同且投标人数量n增大时,卖方最优保留价格以概率收敛于非约束性保留价格,收益保证以速率O(1/n)收敛于均值。
{"title":"Robustly Optimal Auction Design under Mean Constraints","authors":"Ethan Che","doi":"10.1145/3490486.3538357","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1145/3490486.3538357","url":null,"abstract":"We study a seller who sells a single good to multiple bidders with uncertainty over the joint distribution of bidders' valuations, as well as bidders' higher-order beliefs about their opponents. The seller only knows the (possibly asymmetric) means of the marginal distributions of each bidder's valuation and the range. An adversarial nature chooses the worst-case distribution within this ambiguity set along with the worst-case information structure. We find that a second-price auction with a symmetric, random reserve price obtains the optimal revenue guarantee within a broad class of mechanisms we refer to as competitive mechanisms, which include standard auction formats such as the first-price auction. The optimal mechanism possesses two notable characteristics. First, the mechanism treats all bidders identically even in the presence of ex-ante asymmetries. Second, when bidders have identical means and the number of bidders n grows large, the seller's optimal reserve price converges in probability to a non-binding reserve price and the revenue guarantee converges to the mean at rate O(1/n).","PeriodicalId":209859,"journal":{"name":"Proceedings of the 23rd ACM Conference on Economics and Computation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-07-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"127884873","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
Do Peer Preferences Matter in School Choice Market Design?: Theory and Evidence 同伴偏好对择校市场设计有影响吗?:理论与证据
Pub Date : 2022-07-12 DOI: 10.1145/3490486.3538274
Natalie Cox, R. Fonseca, Bobak Pakzad-Hurson
Can a school-choice clearinghouse generate a stable matching if it does not allow students to express preferences over peers? Theoretically, we show stable matchings exist with peer preferences under mild conditions but finding one via canonical mechanisms is unlikely. Increasing transparency about the previous cohort's matching induces a tâtonnement process wherein prior matchings function as prices. We develop a test for stability and implement it empirically in the college admissions market in New South Wales, Australia. We find evidence of preferences over relative peer ability, but no convergence to stability. We propose a mechanism improving upon the current assignment process. Link to full version of paper: https://tinyurl.com/25kdz22e
如果学校选择信息交换中心不允许学生表达对同龄人的偏好,它能产生稳定的匹配吗?从理论上讲,我们表明在温和的条件下,同伴偏好存在稳定的匹配,但通过规范机制找到一个不太可能。增加对先前队列匹配的透明度导致了一个 tonment过程,其中先前的匹配作为价格。我们开发了一种稳定性测试,并在澳大利亚新南威尔士州的大学招生市场进行了实证研究。我们发现了偏好相对同伴能力的证据,但没有趋同到稳定。我们建议建立一种机制,改进目前的分配过程。链接到论文完整版:https://tinyurl.com/25kdz22e
{"title":"Do Peer Preferences Matter in School Choice Market Design?: Theory and Evidence","authors":"Natalie Cox, R. Fonseca, Bobak Pakzad-Hurson","doi":"10.1145/3490486.3538274","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1145/3490486.3538274","url":null,"abstract":"Can a school-choice clearinghouse generate a stable matching if it does not allow students to express preferences over peers? Theoretically, we show stable matchings exist with peer preferences under mild conditions but finding one via canonical mechanisms is unlikely. Increasing transparency about the previous cohort's matching induces a tâtonnement process wherein prior matchings function as prices. We develop a test for stability and implement it empirically in the college admissions market in New South Wales, Australia. We find evidence of preferences over relative peer ability, but no convergence to stability. We propose a mechanism improving upon the current assignment process. Link to full version of paper: https://tinyurl.com/25kdz22e","PeriodicalId":209859,"journal":{"name":"Proceedings of the 23rd ACM Conference on Economics and Computation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-07-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"130226230","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Tight Incentive Analysis on Sybil Attacks to Market Equilibrium of Resource Exchange over General Networks 一般网络上Sybil攻击对资源交换市场均衡的严格激励分析
Pub Date : 2022-07-12 DOI: 10.1145/3490486.3538378
Yukun Cheng, Xiaotie Deng, Yuhao Li, X. Yan
The Internet-scale peer-to-peer (P2P) systems usually build their success on distributed protocols. For example, the well-known BitTorrent network for resource exchange is based on the proportional response protocol, where each participant exchanges its resources with its neighbors in proportion to what it has received in the previous round. The dynamics of such a protocol has been proved to converge to a market equilibrium. On the other hand, it requires thorough incentive analysis to show the robustness of such protocol, as the distributed agents may strategically manipulate the system once they are able to benefit. Recent studies have developed strategyproofness results of the proportional response protocol against agent deviations in the forms of weight cheating and edge deleting. However, the protocol is not truthful against Sybil attacks, under which an agent may create several fictitious identities and control these fictitious identities to exchange resources with others. In this paper, we apply the concept of incentive ratio to measure how much the utility of a strategic agent in a market equilibrium can be improved by playing Sybil attacks. We prove a tight incentive ratio of two for any agent launching Sybil attacks over general networks. The tight incentive ratio of two closes an open problem modeling the successful tit-for-tat protocol for Internet resource exchanging and also presents a complete picture in this line of theoretical studies with real applications.
互联网规模的点对点(P2P)系统通常在分布式协议的基础上取得成功。例如,众所周知的BitTorrent资源交换网络是基于比例响应协议的,其中每个参与者与邻居交换其资源的比例与它在前一轮收到的资源成比例。这种协议的动力学已被证明收敛于市场均衡。另一方面,它需要彻底的激励分析来显示这种协议的鲁棒性,因为一旦分布式代理能够受益,它们可能会有策略地操纵系统。最近的研究已经开发了比例响应协议对权重欺骗和边缘删除形式的代理偏差的策略验证结果。然而,该协议对Sybil攻击并不真实,在Sybil攻击下,代理可以创建多个虚拟身份并控制这些虚拟身份与其他代理交换资源。在本文中,我们应用激励比率的概念来衡量战略主体在市场均衡中通过实施西比尔攻击可以提高多少效用。我们证明了在一般网络上发起Sybil攻击的任何代理的激励比为2。两者的紧密激励比为互联网资源交换中成功的以牙还牙协议的建模提供了一个开放问题,也为这一理论研究和实际应用提供了一个完整的图景。
{"title":"Tight Incentive Analysis on Sybil Attacks to Market Equilibrium of Resource Exchange over General Networks","authors":"Yukun Cheng, Xiaotie Deng, Yuhao Li, X. Yan","doi":"10.1145/3490486.3538378","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1145/3490486.3538378","url":null,"abstract":"The Internet-scale peer-to-peer (P2P) systems usually build their success on distributed protocols. For example, the well-known BitTorrent network for resource exchange is based on the proportional response protocol, where each participant exchanges its resources with its neighbors in proportion to what it has received in the previous round. The dynamics of such a protocol has been proved to converge to a market equilibrium. On the other hand, it requires thorough incentive analysis to show the robustness of such protocol, as the distributed agents may strategically manipulate the system once they are able to benefit. Recent studies have developed strategyproofness results of the proportional response protocol against agent deviations in the forms of weight cheating and edge deleting. However, the protocol is not truthful against Sybil attacks, under which an agent may create several fictitious identities and control these fictitious identities to exchange resources with others. In this paper, we apply the concept of incentive ratio to measure how much the utility of a strategic agent in a market equilibrium can be improved by playing Sybil attacks. We prove a tight incentive ratio of two for any agent launching Sybil attacks over general networks. The tight incentive ratio of two closes an open problem modeling the successful tit-for-tat protocol for Internet resource exchanging and also presents a complete picture in this line of theoretical studies with real applications.","PeriodicalId":209859,"journal":{"name":"Proceedings of the 23rd ACM Conference on Economics and Computation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-07-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"116140568","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Optimal Strategic Mining Against Cryptographic Self-Selection in Proof-of-Stake 权益证明中针对密码自选择的最优策略挖掘
Pub Date : 2022-07-12 DOI: 10.1145/3490486.3538337
Matheus V. X. Ferreira, Ye Lin, Sally Hahn, S. Weinberg, Catherine Yu
Cryptographic Self-Selection is a subroutine used to select a leader for modern proof-of-stake consensus protocols. In cryptographic self-selection, each round r has a seed Qr. In round r, each account owner is asked to digitally sign Qr, hash their digital signature to produce a credential, and then broadcast this credential to the entire network. A publicly-known function scores each credential in a manner so that the distribution of the lowest scoring credential is identical to the distribution of stake owned by each account. The user who broadcasts the lowest-scoring credential is the leader for round r, and their credential becomes the seed Qr+1. Such protocols leave open the possibility of manipulation: a user who owns multiple accounts that each produce low-scoring credentials in round r can selectively choose which ones to broadcast in order to influence the seed for round r+1. Indeed, the user can pre-compute their credentials for round r+1 for each potential seed, and broadcast only the credential (among those with low enough score to be leader) that produces the most favorable seed. We consider an adversary who wishes to maximize the expected fraction of rounds in which an account they own is the leader. We show such an adversary always benefits from deviating from the intended protocol, regardless of the fraction of the stake controlled. We characterize the optimal strategy; first by proving the existence of optimal positive recurrent strategies whenever the adversary owns last than 3-5/2 ~38% of the stake. Then, we provide a Markov Decision Process formulation to compute the optimal strategy.
加密自选择是一种用于选择现代权益证明共识协议领导者的子程序。在密码学自选择中,每轮r都有一个种子Qr。在r轮中,每个帐户所有者被要求对Qr进行数字签名,散列他们的数字签名以生成凭据,然后将此凭据广播到整个网络。一个公开的函数以某种方式对每个凭据进行评分,以便最低评分凭据的分布与每个帐户拥有的权益的分布相同。广播得分最低的凭据的用户是r轮的领先者,他们的凭据成为种子Qr+1。这样的协议留下了操纵的可能性:拥有多个帐户的用户,每个帐户在第r轮中产生低得分凭据,可以选择性地选择广播哪些帐户,以影响第r+1轮的种子。实际上,用户可以为每个潜在种子预先计算r+1轮的凭据,并只广播产生最有利种子的凭据(在那些得分低到足以成为领导者的凭据中)。我们考虑一个对手,他希望最大化他们所拥有的账户领先的预期回合数。我们表明,这样的对手总是从偏离预期协议中获益,而不管所控制的股份的比例是多少。我们描述最优策略;首先,通过证明存在最优的正循环策略,当对手拥有超过3-5/2 ~38%的股权。然后,我们给出了一个马尔可夫决策过程公式来计算最优策略。
{"title":"Optimal Strategic Mining Against Cryptographic Self-Selection in Proof-of-Stake","authors":"Matheus V. X. Ferreira, Ye Lin, Sally Hahn, S. Weinberg, Catherine Yu","doi":"10.1145/3490486.3538337","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1145/3490486.3538337","url":null,"abstract":"Cryptographic Self-Selection is a subroutine used to select a leader for modern proof-of-stake consensus protocols. In cryptographic self-selection, each round r has a seed Qr. In round r, each account owner is asked to digitally sign Qr, hash their digital signature to produce a credential, and then broadcast this credential to the entire network. A publicly-known function scores each credential in a manner so that the distribution of the lowest scoring credential is identical to the distribution of stake owned by each account. The user who broadcasts the lowest-scoring credential is the leader for round r, and their credential becomes the seed Qr+1. Such protocols leave open the possibility of manipulation: a user who owns multiple accounts that each produce low-scoring credentials in round r can selectively choose which ones to broadcast in order to influence the seed for round r+1. Indeed, the user can pre-compute their credentials for round r+1 for each potential seed, and broadcast only the credential (among those with low enough score to be leader) that produces the most favorable seed. We consider an adversary who wishes to maximize the expected fraction of rounds in which an account they own is the leader. We show such an adversary always benefits from deviating from the intended protocol, regardless of the fraction of the stake controlled. We characterize the optimal strategy; first by proving the existence of optimal positive recurrent strategies whenever the adversary owns last than 3-5/2 ~38% of the stake. Then, we provide a Markov Decision Process formulation to compute the optimal strategy.","PeriodicalId":209859,"journal":{"name":"Proceedings of the 23rd ACM Conference on Economics and Computation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-07-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"123847345","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4
Granular DeGroot Dynamics -- a Model for Robust Naive Learning in Social Networks 颗粒状DeGroot动力学——社会网络中鲁棒朴素学习模型
Pub Date : 2022-07-12 DOI: 10.1145/3490486.3538291
Gideon Amir, Itai Arieli, Galit Ashkenazi-Golan, R. Peretz
We study a model of opinion exchange in social networks where a state of the world is realized and every agent receives a zero-mean noisy signal of the realized state. It is known from Golub and Jackson [6] that under DeGroot [3] dynamics agents reach a consensus that is close to the state of the world when the network is large. The DeGroot dynamics, however, is highly non-robust and the presence of a single "stubborn agent" that does not adhere to the updating rule can sway the public consensus to any other value. We introduce a variant of DeGroot dynamics that we call 1/m-DeGroot. 1/m-DeGroot dynamics approximates standard DeGroot dynamics to the nearest rational number with m as its denominator and like the DeGroot dynamics it is Markovian and stationary. We show that in contrast to standard DeGroot dynamics, 1/m-DeGroot dynamics is highly robust both to the presence of stubborn agents and to certain types of misspecifications.
我们研究了一种社会网络中的意见交换模型,在这种模型中,世界的状态被实现,每个智能体接收到一个零均值的已实现状态的噪声信号。从Golub和Jackson[6]可知,在DeGroot[3]下,动态agent达成的共识接近于网络较大时的世界状态。然而,DeGroot动态是高度非鲁棒性的,并且存在一个不遵守更新规则的“顽固代理”,可以影响公众对任何其他值的共识。我们引入了DeGroot动力学的一个变体,我们称之为1/m-DeGroot。1/m-DeGroot动力学将标准DeGroot动力学近似为最接近的有理数,以m为分母,与DeGroot动力学一样,它是马尔可夫的和平稳的。我们表明,与标准DeGroot动力学相比,1/m-DeGroot动力学对顽固因子的存在和某些类型的错误规范都具有高度鲁棒性。
{"title":"Granular DeGroot Dynamics -- a Model for Robust Naive Learning in Social Networks","authors":"Gideon Amir, Itai Arieli, Galit Ashkenazi-Golan, R. Peretz","doi":"10.1145/3490486.3538291","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1145/3490486.3538291","url":null,"abstract":"We study a model of opinion exchange in social networks where a state of the world is realized and every agent receives a zero-mean noisy signal of the realized state. It is known from Golub and Jackson [6] that under DeGroot [3] dynamics agents reach a consensus that is close to the state of the world when the network is large. The DeGroot dynamics, however, is highly non-robust and the presence of a single \"stubborn agent\" that does not adhere to the updating rule can sway the public consensus to any other value. We introduce a variant of DeGroot dynamics that we call 1/m-DeGroot. 1/m-DeGroot dynamics approximates standard DeGroot dynamics to the nearest rational number with m as its denominator and like the DeGroot dynamics it is Markovian and stationary. We show that in contrast to standard DeGroot dynamics, 1/m-DeGroot dynamics is highly robust both to the presence of stubborn agents and to certain types of misspecifications.","PeriodicalId":209859,"journal":{"name":"Proceedings of the 23rd ACM Conference on Economics and Computation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-07-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"124880329","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Optimal Match Recommendations in Two-sided Marketplaces with Endogenous Prices 具有内生价格的双面市场中的最优匹配推荐
Pub Date : 2022-07-12 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.4034950
Peng Shi
Many two-sided marketplaces rely on match recommendations to help customers find suitable service providers at suitable prices. (Examples include Angi, HomeAdvisor, Thumbtack and To8to.) This paper develops a tractable methodology that a platform can use to optimize its match recommendation policy so as to maximize the total value generated by the platform while accounting for the endogeneity of transaction prices, which are determined by the providers and can depend on the platform's match recommendation policy. Despite the complications due to price endogeneity, an optimal match recommendation policy can be computed efficiently using stochastic subgradient descent. Under additional regularity conditions on the distribution of preferences, an optimal policy has a simple form: for each customer segment and each provider, the platform has a certain target on the rate that the provider is recommended to this segment. Any policy that achieves these targets is optimal. Finally, accounting for the endogeneity of prices is crucial: if the platform were to optimize its match recommendations while erroneously assuming that prices are exogenous, then the market is likely to get stuck at a strictly sub-optimal equilibrium, even if the platform were to continually re-optimize its match recommendation policy after prices re-equilibrate. Link to full paper: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4034950
许多双面市场都依靠匹配推荐来帮助客户以合适的价格找到合适的服务提供商(例如 Angi、HomeAdvisor、Thumbtack 和 To8to)。(本文开发了一种可操作的方法,平台可以用它来优化匹配推荐策略,从而最大化平台产生的总价值,同时考虑到交易价格的内生性,交易价格由供应商决定,并可能取决于平台的匹配推荐策略。尽管价格内生性会带来一些复杂问题,但使用随机亚梯度下降法可以高效地计算出最优匹配推荐策略。在偏好分布的附加规律性条件下,最优政策的形式很简单:对于每个客户群和每个提供商,平台对向该客户群推荐该提供商的比率有一定的目标。任何能实现这些目标的政策都是最优的。最后,考虑价格的内生性至关重要:如果平台在优化其匹配推荐时错误地假设价格是外生的,那么即使平台在价格重新调整后不断重新优化其匹配推荐政策,市场也很可能陷入严格意义上的次优均衡。全文链接:https://ssrn.com/abstract=4034950
{"title":"Optimal Match Recommendations in Two-sided Marketplaces with Endogenous Prices","authors":"Peng Shi","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.4034950","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.4034950","url":null,"abstract":"Many two-sided marketplaces rely on match recommendations to help customers find suitable service providers at suitable prices. (Examples include Angi, HomeAdvisor, Thumbtack and To8to.) This paper develops a tractable methodology that a platform can use to optimize its match recommendation policy so as to maximize the total value generated by the platform while accounting for the endogeneity of transaction prices, which are determined by the providers and can depend on the platform's match recommendation policy. Despite the complications due to price endogeneity, an optimal match recommendation policy can be computed efficiently using stochastic subgradient descent. Under additional regularity conditions on the distribution of preferences, an optimal policy has a simple form: for each customer segment and each provider, the platform has a certain target on the rate that the provider is recommended to this segment. Any policy that achieves these targets is optimal. Finally, accounting for the endogeneity of prices is crucial: if the platform were to optimize its match recommendations while erroneously assuming that prices are exogenous, then the market is likely to get stuck at a strictly sub-optimal equilibrium, even if the platform were to continually re-optimize its match recommendation policy after prices re-equilibrate. Link to full paper: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4034950","PeriodicalId":209859,"journal":{"name":"Proceedings of the 23rd ACM Conference on Economics and Computation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-07-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"131222297","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
Equity in Resident Crowdsourcing: Measuring Under-reporting without Ground Truth Data 居民众包的公平性:在没有真实数据的情况下衡量漏报
Pub Date : 2022-07-12 DOI: 10.1145/3490486.3538283
Zhi Liu, Nikhil Garg
Modern city governance relies heavily on crowdsourcing (or "co-production") to identify problems such as downed trees and power-lines. A major concern in these systems is that residents do not report problems at the same rates, leading to an inequitable allocation of government resources. However, measuring such under-reporting is a difficult statistical task, as, almost by definition, we do not observe incidents that are not reported. Thus, distinguishing between low reporting rates and low ground-truth incident rates is challenging. We develop a method to identify (heterogeneous) reporting rates, without using external (proxy) ground truth data. Our insight is that rates on duplicate reports about the same incident can be leveraged, to turn the question into a standard Poisson rate estimation task---even though the full incident reporting interval is also unobserved. We apply our method to over 100,000 resident reports made to the New York City Department of Parks and Recreation, finding that there are substantial spatial and socio-economic disparities in reporting rates, even after controlling for incident characteristics.
现代城市治理在很大程度上依赖于众包(或“联合生产”)来识别倒下的树木和电线等问题。这些系统的一个主要问题是,居民没有以相同的比率报告问题,导致政府资源分配不公平。然而,衡量这种漏报是一项困难的统计任务,因为几乎根据定义,我们不会观察到未报告的事件。因此,区分低报告率和低真实事件发生率是具有挑战性的。我们开发了一种方法来识别(异构)报告率,而不使用外部(代理)真实数据。我们的见解是,可以利用关于同一事件的重复报告的比率,将问题转化为标准泊松率估计任务——即使完整的事件报告间隔也未被观察到。我们将我们的方法应用于向纽约市公园和娱乐部门提交的10万多份居民报告中,发现即使在控制了事件特征之后,报告率也存在巨大的空间和社会经济差异。
{"title":"Equity in Resident Crowdsourcing: Measuring Under-reporting without Ground Truth Data","authors":"Zhi Liu, Nikhil Garg","doi":"10.1145/3490486.3538283","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1145/3490486.3538283","url":null,"abstract":"Modern city governance relies heavily on crowdsourcing (or \"co-production\") to identify problems such as downed trees and power-lines. A major concern in these systems is that residents do not report problems at the same rates, leading to an inequitable allocation of government resources. However, measuring such under-reporting is a difficult statistical task, as, almost by definition, we do not observe incidents that are not reported. Thus, distinguishing between low reporting rates and low ground-truth incident rates is challenging. We develop a method to identify (heterogeneous) reporting rates, without using external (proxy) ground truth data. Our insight is that rates on duplicate reports about the same incident can be leveraged, to turn the question into a standard Poisson rate estimation task---even though the full incident reporting interval is also unobserved. We apply our method to over 100,000 resident reports made to the New York City Department of Parks and Recreation, finding that there are substantial spatial and socio-economic disparities in reporting rates, even after controlling for incident characteristics.","PeriodicalId":209859,"journal":{"name":"Proceedings of the 23rd ACM Conference on Economics and Computation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-07-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"132642362","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4
期刊
Proceedings of the 23rd ACM Conference on Economics and Computation
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1