首页 > 最新文献

Proceedings of the 23rd ACM Conference on Economics and Computation最新文献

英文 中文
The Derby Game: An Ordering-based Colonel Blotto Game 德比游戏:一个基于订单的上校Blotto游戏
Pub Date : 2022-07-12 DOI: 10.1145/3490486.3538367
Akash Gaonkar, Divya Raghunathan, S. Weinberg
The Colonel Blotto game and its variants are a common approach to study competitive allocation of interchangeable resources (e.g., soldiers, money, or votes). We introduce a new variant of Blotto, which we call the Derby game, to study competitive allocation of non-interchangeable resources, such as campaign surrogates in politics or skilled workers in companies, and analyze its Nash equilibria. While Derby games unsurprisingly admit no pure Nash equilibria, our main results surprisingly show that Nash equilibria generically exist where one player plays a pure strategy, and we give necessary and sufficient conditions for such equilibria.
《Colonel Blotto》游戏及其变体是研究可互换资源(游戏邦注:如士兵、金钱或选票)竞争性分配的常用方法。我们引入了一种新的Blotto变体,我们称之为德比游戏,以研究不可互换资源的竞争性分配,例如政治中的竞选代理人或公司中的熟练工人,并分析其纳什均衡。虽然德比博弈不存在纯粹的纳什均衡,但我们的主要结果令人惊讶地表明,纳什均衡一般存在于一方采取纯粹策略的情况下,我们给出了这种均衡的充分必要条件。
{"title":"The Derby Game: An Ordering-based Colonel Blotto Game","authors":"Akash Gaonkar, Divya Raghunathan, S. Weinberg","doi":"10.1145/3490486.3538367","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1145/3490486.3538367","url":null,"abstract":"The Colonel Blotto game and its variants are a common approach to study competitive allocation of interchangeable resources (e.g., soldiers, money, or votes). We introduce a new variant of Blotto, which we call the Derby game, to study competitive allocation of non-interchangeable resources, such as campaign surrogates in politics or skilled workers in companies, and analyze its Nash equilibria. While Derby games unsurprisingly admit no pure Nash equilibria, our main results surprisingly show that Nash equilibria generically exist where one player plays a pure strategy, and we give necessary and sufficient conditions for such equilibria.","PeriodicalId":209859,"journal":{"name":"Proceedings of the 23rd ACM Conference on Economics and Computation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-07-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"122044023","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Constrained Majorization: Applications in Mechanism Design 约束最大化:在机构设计中的应用
Pub Date : 2022-07-12 DOI: 10.1145/3490486.3538257
Afshin Nikzad
Classical frameworks in mechanism design often specify an objective function and maximize it by choosing allocation. We extend these frameworks by allowing maximizing an objective function (such as expected revenue in an auction) subject to additional constraints (such as lower bounds on efficiency or welfare). The additional complexity arising due to each additional constraint manifests in the reduced form of the optimal mechanism as at most one jump discontinuity in an "ironed" interval. We apply our results to demonstrate the simplicity of optimal mechanisms despite the presence of a side constraint in common economic applications such as contract and auction design. We also introduce a regularity condition under which the general structure of optimal mechanisms bears no additional complexity due to the presence of a side constraint. The analysis builds on the findings of Kleiner et al. (2021) by considering optimal mechanisms as extreme points of function spaces.
经典的机制设计框架通常指定一个目标函数,并通过选择分配来实现目标函数的最大化。我们通过允许在附加约束(如效率或福利的下限)下最大化目标函数(如拍卖中的预期收入)来扩展这些框架。由于每个附加约束而产生的额外复杂性以最优机制的简化形式表现为在“熨平”区间内最多有一个跳跃不连续。我们应用我们的结果来证明最优机制的简单性,尽管在常见的经济应用(如合同和拍卖设计)中存在侧约束。我们还引入了一个正则性条件,在该条件下,由于存在侧约束,最优机构的一般结构不会产生额外的复杂性。该分析基于Kleiner等人(2021)的研究结果,将最优机制视为函数空间的极值点。
{"title":"Constrained Majorization: Applications in Mechanism Design","authors":"Afshin Nikzad","doi":"10.1145/3490486.3538257","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1145/3490486.3538257","url":null,"abstract":"Classical frameworks in mechanism design often specify an objective function and maximize it by choosing allocation. We extend these frameworks by allowing maximizing an objective function (such as expected revenue in an auction) subject to additional constraints (such as lower bounds on efficiency or welfare). The additional complexity arising due to each additional constraint manifests in the reduced form of the optimal mechanism as at most one jump discontinuity in an \"ironed\" interval. We apply our results to demonstrate the simplicity of optimal mechanisms despite the presence of a side constraint in common economic applications such as contract and auction design. We also introduce a regularity condition under which the general structure of optimal mechanisms bears no additional complexity due to the presence of a side constraint. The analysis builds on the findings of Kleiner et al. (2021) by considering optimal mechanisms as extreme points of function spaces.","PeriodicalId":209859,"journal":{"name":"Proceedings of the 23rd ACM Conference on Economics and Computation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-07-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"133263574","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
On Two-sided Matching in Infinite Markets 无限市场中的双面匹配
Pub Date : 2022-07-12 DOI: 10.1145/3490486.3538325
Yunseo Choi
We extend a number of classic results for finite one-to-one matching markets, such as group strategy-proofness, entry comparative statics, and respect for unambiguous improvements, to infinite markets via the compactness theorem of propositional logic. In addition, we show that two versions of the lattice structure of finite one-to-one matching markets carry over to infinite markets. At the same time, we prove that other results, such as weak Pareto optimality and strong stability property, do not extend to infinite markets.
通过命题逻辑的紧性定理,我们将有限一对一匹配市场的一些经典结果,如群体策略的证明性、进入比较静力学和对无歧义改进的尊重,推广到无限市场。此外,我们还证明了有限一对一匹配市场的晶格结构的两个版本可以延续到无限市场。同时,证明了弱Pareto最优性和强稳定性等其他结果在无限市场上不成立。
{"title":"On Two-sided Matching in Infinite Markets","authors":"Yunseo Choi","doi":"10.1145/3490486.3538325","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1145/3490486.3538325","url":null,"abstract":"We extend a number of classic results for finite one-to-one matching markets, such as group strategy-proofness, entry comparative statics, and respect for unambiguous improvements, to infinite markets via the compactness theorem of propositional logic. In addition, we show that two versions of the lattice structure of finite one-to-one matching markets carry over to infinite markets. At the same time, we prove that other results, such as weak Pareto optimality and strong stability property, do not extend to infinite markets.","PeriodicalId":209859,"journal":{"name":"Proceedings of the 23rd ACM Conference on Economics and Computation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-07-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"115042759","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Fair Allocations for Smoothed Utilities 平滑公用事业的公平分配
Pub Date : 2022-07-12 DOI: 10.1145/3490486.3538285
Yushi Bai, U. Feige, Paul Gölz, A. Procaccia
When allocating indivisible items across agents, it is desirable for the allocation to be envy-free, which means that each agent prefers their own bundle over every other bundle. Even though envy-free allocations are not guaranteed to exist for worst-case utilities, they frequently exist in practice. To explain this phenomenon, prior work has shown that, if utilities are drawn from certain probability distributions, then envy-free allocations exist with high probability (as long as the number of items is sufficiently large relative to the number of agents). In this paper, we study a more general setting, a smoothed model of utilities, in which utility profiles are mainly worst-case, but are slightly perturbed at random to avoid brittle counter-examples. Specifically, we start from a worst-case profile of utilities and, with some small probability, increase an agent's value for an item by adding a random amount, where the probability of perturbation and the distribution of perturbations are parameters of the model. If the probability of such perturbations is sufficiently large relative to the number of agents and items, we show that envy-free allocations exist with high probability and can be found efficiently. This analysis is tight up to constant factors. We also give an efficient algorithm for finding allocations that are simultaneously proportional and Pareto-optimal, which succeeds with high probability in the smoothed model.
当在代理之间分配不可分割的物品时,希望分配是无嫉妒的,这意味着每个代理更喜欢自己的捆绑包而不是其他捆绑包。尽管无嫉妒分配不能保证在最坏情况下存在,但它们在实践中经常存在。为了解释这一现象,先前的研究表明,如果效用是从一定的概率分布中提取的,那么无嫉妒分配就有很高的概率存在(只要项目的数量相对于代理的数量足够大)。在本文中,我们研究了一个更一般的设置,一个平滑的效用模型,其中效用曲线主要是最坏情况,但在随机情况下略有扰动,以避免脆弱的反例。具体来说,我们从效用的最坏情况概况开始,并以较小的概率通过添加随机数量来增加代理对项目的价值,其中扰动的概率和扰动的分布是模型的参数。如果这种扰动的概率相对于代理和项目的数量足够大,我们证明了无嫉妒分配存在的高概率,并且可以有效地找到。这一分析受到常数因素的限制。我们还给出了一种寻找同时是比例和帕累托最优分配的有效算法,该算法在平滑模型中成功率很高。
{"title":"Fair Allocations for Smoothed Utilities","authors":"Yushi Bai, U. Feige, Paul Gölz, A. Procaccia","doi":"10.1145/3490486.3538285","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1145/3490486.3538285","url":null,"abstract":"When allocating indivisible items across agents, it is desirable for the allocation to be envy-free, which means that each agent prefers their own bundle over every other bundle. Even though envy-free allocations are not guaranteed to exist for worst-case utilities, they frequently exist in practice. To explain this phenomenon, prior work has shown that, if utilities are drawn from certain probability distributions, then envy-free allocations exist with high probability (as long as the number of items is sufficiently large relative to the number of agents). In this paper, we study a more general setting, a smoothed model of utilities, in which utility profiles are mainly worst-case, but are slightly perturbed at random to avoid brittle counter-examples. Specifically, we start from a worst-case profile of utilities and, with some small probability, increase an agent's value for an item by adding a random amount, where the probability of perturbation and the distribution of perturbations are parameters of the model. If the probability of such perturbations is sufficiently large relative to the number of agents and items, we show that envy-free allocations exist with high probability and can be found efficiently. This analysis is tight up to constant factors. We also give an efficient algorithm for finding allocations that are simultaneously proportional and Pareto-optimal, which succeeds with high probability in the smoothed model.","PeriodicalId":209859,"journal":{"name":"Proceedings of the 23rd ACM Conference on Economics and Computation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-07-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"128668553","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 11
Crowd Prediction Systems: Markets, Polls, and Elite Forecasters 人群预测系统:市场、民意调查和精英预测者
Pub Date : 2022-07-12 DOI: 10.1145/3490486.3538265
P. Atanasov, Jens Witkowski, B. Mellers, P. Tetlock
Crowd prediction systems, such as prediction markets, provide the infrastructure to elicit and combine the predictions from a group (“crowd”) of forecasters. In contrast to data-driven approaches, crowd predictions are especially useful in settings with little historical data, such as in new product development, vaccine trials, pandemics, or geopolitical events. Our contributions in this area are threefold. First, we provide an experimental evaluation of two popular types of prediction market architectures: continuous double auction (CDA) markets and logarithmic market scoring rules (LMSR) markets. To the best of our knowledge, we are the first to study these methods in a large, randomized experiment. Prior research reporting on CDA and LMSR market performance did not compare the two designs directly but had separate sets of questions for each [2]. Using data from over 1300 forecasters and 147 forecasting questions, we find that the LMSR market achieves higher accuracy than the CDA market. The LMSR market achieves 14% lower Brier scores (MCDA = 0.245, SDCDA = 0.327 versus MLMSR = 0.211, SDLMSR = 0.280; t(146) = 2.28, p = 0.024). In exploratory analyses, we find that the better performance of the LMSR market appears particularly pronounced for questions that attracted few traders as well as early in a question when only few traders had placed orders on the question. Relative to LMSR, the CDA market underperformed in thin-market settings, consistent with Robin Hanson’s motivation for the LMSR market mechanism. Second, we quantify the impact of prediction system architecture and individual forecaster track record on aggregate performance. Previous research studied how the performance of CDA prediction markets and prediction polls compares when populated by sub-elite forecasters [1] while most previous work on elite forecasters has only examined their individual performance [3]. We are the first to compare the aggregate performance of small, elite forecaster crowds across two prediction systems: LMSR prediction markets and team prediction polls. Moreover, we compare the aggregate accuracy of elite forecaster crowds to larger, sub-elite crowds using the same prediction
人群预测系统,如预测市场,提供了从一群预测者(“人群”)中引出和组合预测的基础设施。与数据驱动的方法相比,人群预测在历史数据很少的情况下特别有用,例如在新产品开发、疫苗试验、流行病或地缘政治事件中。我们在这方面的贡献有三方面。首先,我们对两种流行的预测市场架构进行了实验评估:连续双拍卖(CDA)市场和对数市场评分规则(LMSR)市场。据我们所知,我们是第一个在大型随机实验中研究这些方法的人。先前关于CDA和LMSR市场表现的研究报告并没有直接比较两种设计,而是为每个bbb单独设置了一组问题。使用来自1300多名预测者和147个预测问题的数据,我们发现LMSR市场比CDA市场具有更高的准确性。LMSR市场Brier评分低14% (MCDA = 0.245, SDCDA = 0.327, MLMSR = 0.211, SDLMSR = 0.280;T (146) = 2.28, p = 0.024)。在探索性分析中,我们发现LMSR市场的良好表现对于那些吸引了很少交易者的问题以及在只有很少交易者对该问题下订单的问题的早期表现尤为明显。相对于LMSR, CDA市场在薄市场环境下表现不佳,这与Robin Hanson关于LMSR市场机制的动机一致。其次,我们量化了预测系统架构和个体预测者跟踪记录对总体性能的影响。先前的研究研究了在由次精英预测者组成的情况下,CDA预测市场和预测民意调查的表现如何比较,而之前大多数关于精英预测者的工作只研究了他们的个人表现[3]。我们首先比较了两种预测系统(LMSR预测市场和团队预测民意调查)中小型精英预测人群的总体表现。此外,我们比较了精英预测者群体与使用相同预测的更大的、次精英群体的总准确性
{"title":"Crowd Prediction Systems: Markets, Polls, and Elite Forecasters","authors":"P. Atanasov, Jens Witkowski, B. Mellers, P. Tetlock","doi":"10.1145/3490486.3538265","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1145/3490486.3538265","url":null,"abstract":"Crowd prediction systems, such as prediction markets, provide the infrastructure to elicit and combine the predictions from a group (“crowd”) of forecasters. In contrast to data-driven approaches, crowd predictions are especially useful in settings with little historical data, such as in new product development, vaccine trials, pandemics, or geopolitical events. Our contributions in this area are threefold. First, we provide an experimental evaluation of two popular types of prediction market architectures: continuous double auction (CDA) markets and logarithmic market scoring rules (LMSR) markets. To the best of our knowledge, we are the first to study these methods in a large, randomized experiment. Prior research reporting on CDA and LMSR market performance did not compare the two designs directly but had separate sets of questions for each [2]. Using data from over 1300 forecasters and 147 forecasting questions, we find that the LMSR market achieves higher accuracy than the CDA market. The LMSR market achieves 14% lower Brier scores (MCDA = 0.245, SDCDA = 0.327 versus MLMSR = 0.211, SDLMSR = 0.280; t(146) = 2.28, p = 0.024). In exploratory analyses, we find that the better performance of the LMSR market appears particularly pronounced for questions that attracted few traders as well as early in a question when only few traders had placed orders on the question. Relative to LMSR, the CDA market underperformed in thin-market settings, consistent with Robin Hanson’s motivation for the LMSR market mechanism. Second, we quantify the impact of prediction system architecture and individual forecaster track record on aggregate performance. Previous research studied how the performance of CDA prediction markets and prediction polls compares when populated by sub-elite forecasters [1] while most previous work on elite forecasters has only examined their individual performance [3]. We are the first to compare the aggregate performance of small, elite forecaster crowds across two prediction systems: LMSR prediction markets and team prediction polls. Moreover, we compare the aggregate accuracy of elite forecaster crowds to larger, sub-elite crowds using the same prediction","PeriodicalId":209859,"journal":{"name":"Proceedings of the 23rd ACM Conference on Economics and Computation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-07-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"134423537","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
Adjustment of Bidding Strategies After a Switch to First-Price Rules 转向首价规则后投标策略的调整
Pub Date : 2022-07-12 DOI: 10.1145/3490486.3538236
Miguel Alcobendas, Robert Zeithammer
We document the response of bidders to a change in auction pricing rules by a platform selling online advertising impressions. The platform switched from a second-price auction to a first-price auction in 2019. We analyze the transition and ask three questions: Did the bids by the same bidder bidding to show the same creative in the same location on the same webpage fall? If yes, did the bids fall enough? And if the bids fell enough, how long did the transition take? To answer our questions, we study 11 long-running creatives with sufficient volume of bids for a month before the switch and three months after the switch. We find that bids on these long-running creatives indeed declined after the switch, but this decline was not sufficient. To detect insufficient shading, we propose a simple nonparametric estimator of the lower bound on advertiser valuations in first-price sealed-bid auctions. Unlike standard econometric approaches to first-price auctions, our bound estimator does not assume equilibrium and it can accommodate affiliated private values. The identifying assumption is that each bidder prefers his actual bid to an even lower bid given the hyper-local competition the bidder is facing at the moment. This assumption implies a lower bound on a rationalizable valuation of the bidder in a first-price auction. Comparing the post-switch valuation lower bounds to the pre-switch valuation magnitudes allows us to detect insufficient adjustment whenever the former exceeds the latter. And we indeed find that the bid shading was insufficient for a vast majority of bidders and creatives included in our study: observed bids on the median creative imply that the bidder bid as if the switch from second-price to first-price rules increased his valuation of an impression at least 30 percent. We also find evidence of an incomplete and slow downward adjustment in bid magnitude over the period of months, whereby bids remain insufficiently shaded for about half of the creatives even three months after the switch. The full paper is available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4036006
我们记录了竞标者对拍卖定价规则变化的反应,通过销售在线广告印象的平台。2019年,该平台从第二价格拍卖转为第一价格拍卖。我们分析了这种转变,并提出了三个问题:同一投标人在同一网页的同一位置展示相同创意的出价是否下降?如果是,出价是否足够低?如果出价足够低,过渡需要多长时间?为了回答我们的问题,我们研究了11个长期存在的创意,这些创意在转换前一个月和转换后三个月都有足够的投标量。我们发现,这些长期存在的创意的出价确实在转换后下降了,但这种下降还不够。为了检测不充分的阴影,我们提出了一个简单的非参数估计的下界的广告商估值在第一价格密封投标拍卖。与第一价格拍卖的标准计量经济学方法不同,我们的界估计器不假设均衡,它可以容纳附属的私人价值。确定的假设是,每个竞标者更喜欢他的实际出价甚至更低的出价,鉴于竞标者目前面临的超本地化竞争。这一假设暗示了首价拍卖中竞标者合理估价的下限。将转换后的估值下限与转换前的估值幅度进行比较,使我们能够在前者超过后者时检测到调整不足。我们确实发现,对于我们研究中的绝大多数竞标者和创意人员来说,投标阴影是不够的:观察到的中位数创意的投标表明,竞标者的投标似乎从第二价格规则转换为第一价格规则使他对印象的估值至少增加了30%。我们还发现,在几个月的时间里,投标幅度出现了不完全和缓慢的向下调整,即使在转换后的三个月里,大约一半的创意人员的投标仍然没有得到充分的保护。全文可在https://ssrn.com/abstract=4036006上找到
{"title":"Adjustment of Bidding Strategies After a Switch to First-Price Rules","authors":"Miguel Alcobendas, Robert Zeithammer","doi":"10.1145/3490486.3538236","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1145/3490486.3538236","url":null,"abstract":"We document the response of bidders to a change in auction pricing rules by a platform selling online advertising impressions. The platform switched from a second-price auction to a first-price auction in 2019. We analyze the transition and ask three questions: Did the bids by the same bidder bidding to show the same creative in the same location on the same webpage fall? If yes, did the bids fall enough? And if the bids fell enough, how long did the transition take? To answer our questions, we study 11 long-running creatives with sufficient volume of bids for a month before the switch and three months after the switch. We find that bids on these long-running creatives indeed declined after the switch, but this decline was not sufficient. To detect insufficient shading, we propose a simple nonparametric estimator of the lower bound on advertiser valuations in first-price sealed-bid auctions. Unlike standard econometric approaches to first-price auctions, our bound estimator does not assume equilibrium and it can accommodate affiliated private values. The identifying assumption is that each bidder prefers his actual bid to an even lower bid given the hyper-local competition the bidder is facing at the moment. This assumption implies a lower bound on a rationalizable valuation of the bidder in a first-price auction. Comparing the post-switch valuation lower bounds to the pre-switch valuation magnitudes allows us to detect insufficient adjustment whenever the former exceeds the latter. And we indeed find that the bid shading was insufficient for a vast majority of bidders and creatives included in our study: observed bids on the median creative imply that the bidder bid as if the switch from second-price to first-price rules increased his valuation of an impression at least 30 percent. We also find evidence of an incomplete and slow downward adjustment in bid magnitude over the period of months, whereby bids remain insufficiently shaded for about half of the creatives even three months after the switch. The full paper is available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4036006","PeriodicalId":209859,"journal":{"name":"Proceedings of the 23rd ACM Conference on Economics and Computation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-07-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"134257929","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4
Designing School Choice for Diversity in the San Francisco Unified School District 在旧金山联合学区设计多元化的学校选择
Pub Date : 2022-07-12 DOI: 10.1145/3490486.3538271
Maxwell Allman, I. Ashlagi, Irene Lo, J. Love, Katherine Mentzer, Lulabel Ruiz-Setz, Henry O'Connell
More than 65 years after the "Brown v. Board of Education" ruling that school segregation is unconstitutional, public schools across the U.S. are resegregating. In attempts to disentangle school segregation from neighborhood segregation, many cities have adopted policies for district-wide choice. However, these policies have largely not improved patterns of segregation. From 2018-2020, we worked with the San Francisco Unified School District (SFUSD) to design a new policy for student assignment system that meets the district's goals of diversity, predictability, and proximity. To develop potential policies, we used optimization techniques to augment and operationalize the district's proposal of restricting choice to zones. We compared these to approaches typically suggested by the school choice literature. Using predictive choice models developed using historical choice data, we find that appropriately-designed zones with minority reserves can achieve all the district's goals, at the expense of choice, and choice can resegregate diverse zones. A zone-based policy can decrease the percentage of racial minorities in high-poverty schools from 29% to 11%, decrease the average travel distance from 1.39 miles to 1.29 miles, and improve predictability, but reduce the percentage of students assigned to one of their top 3 programs from 80% to 59%. Existing approaches in the school choice literature can improve diversity at lesser expense to choice, and present a trade-off between diversity, proximity, distributional effects, and ease of understanding and implementation. Our work informed the design and approval of a zone-based policy for use starting the 2024-25 school year.
在“布朗诉教育委员会案”裁定学校种族隔离违宪65年后,美国各地的公立学校正在重新实行种族隔离。为了将学校隔离与社区隔离分离开来,许多城市都采取了学区范围内的选择政策。然而,这些政策在很大程度上并没有改善种族隔离的模式。从2018年到2020年,我们与旧金山联合学区(SFUSD)合作,为学生分配系统设计了一个新的政策,以满足该学区多样性、可预测性和邻近性的目标。为了制定潜在的政策,我们使用优化技术来增加和实施限制区域选择的区域建议。我们将这些方法与择校文献中通常建议的方法进行了比较。通过使用历史选择数据开发的预测选择模型,我们发现,以牺牲选择为代价,适当设计具有少数民族储备的区域可以实现所有区域的目标,而选择可以重新隔离不同的区域。以区域为基础的政策可以将高贫困学校中少数种族的比例从29%降低到11%,将平均旅行距离从1.39英里减少到1.29英里,并提高可预测性,但将分配到前3个项目之一的学生比例从80%降低到59%。学校选择文献中的现有方法可以在较少的选择代价下改善多样性,并在多样性、邻近性、分配效应以及易于理解和实施之间进行权衡。我们的工作为2024-25学年开始使用的基于区域的政策的设计和批准提供了信息。
{"title":"Designing School Choice for Diversity in the San Francisco Unified School District","authors":"Maxwell Allman, I. Ashlagi, Irene Lo, J. Love, Katherine Mentzer, Lulabel Ruiz-Setz, Henry O'Connell","doi":"10.1145/3490486.3538271","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1145/3490486.3538271","url":null,"abstract":"More than 65 years after the \"Brown v. Board of Education\" ruling that school segregation is unconstitutional, public schools across the U.S. are resegregating. In attempts to disentangle school segregation from neighborhood segregation, many cities have adopted policies for district-wide choice. However, these policies have largely not improved patterns of segregation. From 2018-2020, we worked with the San Francisco Unified School District (SFUSD) to design a new policy for student assignment system that meets the district's goals of diversity, predictability, and proximity. To develop potential policies, we used optimization techniques to augment and operationalize the district's proposal of restricting choice to zones. We compared these to approaches typically suggested by the school choice literature. Using predictive choice models developed using historical choice data, we find that appropriately-designed zones with minority reserves can achieve all the district's goals, at the expense of choice, and choice can resegregate diverse zones. A zone-based policy can decrease the percentage of racial minorities in high-poverty schools from 29% to 11%, decrease the average travel distance from 1.39 miles to 1.29 miles, and improve predictability, but reduce the percentage of students assigned to one of their top 3 programs from 80% to 59%. Existing approaches in the school choice literature can improve diversity at lesser expense to choice, and present a trade-off between diversity, proximity, distributional effects, and ease of understanding and implementation. Our work informed the design and approval of a zone-based policy for use starting the 2024-25 school year.","PeriodicalId":209859,"journal":{"name":"Proceedings of the 23rd ACM Conference on Economics and Computation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-07-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"130566202","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 10
Computationally Tractable Choice 计算可处理的选择
Pub Date : 2022-07-12 DOI: 10.1145/3490486.3538256
Modibo K. Camara
I incorporate computational constraints into decision theory in order to capture how cognitive limitations affect behavior. I impose an axiom of computational tractability that only rules out behaviors that are thought to be fundamentally hard. I use this framework to better understand common behavioral heuristics: if choices are tractable and consistent with the expected utility axioms, then they are observationally equivalent to forms of choice bracketing. Then I show that a computationally-constrained decisionmaker can be objectively better off if she is willing to use heuristics that would not appear rational to an outside observer. The full paper is available at https://mkcamara.github.io/ctc.pdf.
我将计算约束纳入决策理论,以捕捉认知限制如何影响行为。我强加了一个计算可追溯性的公理,它只排除那些被认为从根本上是困难的行为。我使用这个框架是为了更好地理解常见的行为启发式:如果选择是可处理的,并且与预期效用公理一致,那么它们在观察上等同于选择括号的形式。然后,我证明,如果一个受计算约束的决策者愿意使用在外部观察者看来不合理的启发式方法,那么她在客观上可能会更好。全文可在https://mkcamara.github.io/ctc.pdf上找到。
{"title":"Computationally Tractable Choice","authors":"Modibo K. Camara","doi":"10.1145/3490486.3538256","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1145/3490486.3538256","url":null,"abstract":"I incorporate computational constraints into decision theory in order to capture how cognitive limitations affect behavior. I impose an axiom of computational tractability that only rules out behaviors that are thought to be fundamentally hard. I use this framework to better understand common behavioral heuristics: if choices are tractable and consistent with the expected utility axioms, then they are observationally equivalent to forms of choice bracketing. Then I show that a computationally-constrained decisionmaker can be objectively better off if she is willing to use heuristics that would not appear rational to an outside observer. The full paper is available at https://mkcamara.github.io/ctc.pdf.","PeriodicalId":209859,"journal":{"name":"Proceedings of the 23rd ACM Conference on Economics and Computation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-07-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"120916325","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 10
Optimal Credit Scores Under Adverse Selection 逆向选择下的最优信用评分
Pub Date : 2022-07-12 DOI: 10.1145/3490486.3538331
Nicole Immorlica, Andre Sztutman, R. Townsend
The increasing availability of data in credit markets may appear to make adverse selection concerns less relevant. However, when there is adverse selection, more information does not necessarily increase welfare. We provide tools for making better use of the data that is collected from potential borrowers, formulating and solving the optimal disclosure problem of an intermediary with commitment that seeks to maximize the probability of successful transactions, weighted by the size of the gains of these transactions. We show that any optimal disclosure policy needs to satisfy some simple conditions in terms of local sufficient statistics. These conditions relate prices to the price elasticities of the expected value of the loans for the investors. Empirically, we apply our method to the data from the Townsend Thai Project, which is a long panel dataset with rich information on credit histories, balance sheets, and income statements, to evaluate whether it can help develop the particularly thin formal rural credit markets in Thailand, finding economically meaningful gains from adopting optimal information disclosure policies.
信贷市场上数据的日益可得性似乎使逆向选择的担忧变得不那么重要了。然而,当存在逆向选择时,更多的信息并不一定会增加福利。我们提供工具,以便更好地利用从潜在借款人那里收集的数据,制定并解决中介机构的最佳披露问题,这些中介机构致力于通过这些交易的收益规模来最大化成功交易的可能性。从局部充分统计量的角度证明了任何最优公开策略都需要满足一些简单的条件。这些条件将价格与投资者预期贷款价值的价格弹性联系起来。经验上,我们将我们的方法应用于汤森泰国项目(Townsend Thai Project)的数据,该项目是一个长面板数据集,具有丰富的信贷历史、资产负债表和损益表信息),以评估它是否有助于发展泰国特别薄弱的正规农村信贷市场,并通过采用最佳信息披露政策找到经济上有意义的收益。
{"title":"Optimal Credit Scores Under Adverse Selection","authors":"Nicole Immorlica, Andre Sztutman, R. Townsend","doi":"10.1145/3490486.3538331","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1145/3490486.3538331","url":null,"abstract":"The increasing availability of data in credit markets may appear to make adverse selection concerns less relevant. However, when there is adverse selection, more information does not necessarily increase welfare. We provide tools for making better use of the data that is collected from potential borrowers, formulating and solving the optimal disclosure problem of an intermediary with commitment that seeks to maximize the probability of successful transactions, weighted by the size of the gains of these transactions. We show that any optimal disclosure policy needs to satisfy some simple conditions in terms of local sufficient statistics. These conditions relate prices to the price elasticities of the expected value of the loans for the investors. Empirically, we apply our method to the data from the Townsend Thai Project, which is a long panel dataset with rich information on credit histories, balance sheets, and income statements, to evaluate whether it can help develop the particularly thin formal rural credit markets in Thailand, finding economically meaningful gains from adopting optimal information disclosure policies.","PeriodicalId":209859,"journal":{"name":"Proceedings of the 23rd ACM Conference on Economics and Computation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-07-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"131479479","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Statistical Discrimination in Stable Matchings 稳定匹配中的统计歧视
Pub Date : 2022-07-12 DOI: 10.1145/3490486.3538364
Rémi Castera, P. Loiseau, Bary S. R. Pradelski
Statistical discrimination results when a decision-maker observes an imperfect estimate of the quality of each candidate dependent on which demographic group they belong to [1,8]. Imperfect estimates have been modelled via noise, where the variance depends on the candidate's group ([4,6,7]). Prior literature, however, is limited to simple selection problems, where a single decision-maker tries to choose the best candidates among the applications they received. In this paper, we initiate the study of statistical discrimination in matching, where multiple decision-makers are simultaneously facing selection problems from the same pool of candidates. We consider the college admission problem as first introduced in [5] and recently extended to a model with a continuum of students [3]. We propose a model where two colleges A and B observe noisy estimates of each candidate's quality, where Ws, the vector of estimates for student s, is assumed to be a bivariate normal random variable. In this setting, the estimation noise controls a new key feature of the problem, namely correlation, ρ, between the estimates of the two colleges: if the noise is high, the correlation is low and if the noise is low the correlation is high. We assume that the population of students is divided into two groups G1 and G2, and that members of these two groups are subject to different correlation levels between their grades at colleges A and B. Concretely, for each student s, their grade vector (WAs, WBs) is drawn according to a centered bivariate normal distribution with variance 1 and covariance ρGs, where Gs is the group student s belongs to. We consider the stable matching induced by this distribution and characterize how key outcome characteristics vary with the parameters, in particular with the group-dependent correlation coefficient. Our results summarize as follows: We show that the probability that a student is assigned to their first choice is independent of the student's group, but that it decreases when the correlation of either group decreases. This means that higher measurement noise (inducing lower correlation) on one group hurts not only the students of that group, but the students of all groups. We show that the probability that a student is assigned to their second choice and the probability that they remain unassigned both depend on the student's group, which reveals the presence of statistical discrimination coming from the correlation effect alone. Specifically, we find that the probability that a student remains unmatched is decreasing when the correlation of their group decreases (higher measurement noise) and when the correlation of the other group increases. In other words, the higher the measurement noise of their own group, the better off students are with regard to getting assigned a college at all. This is somewhat counter-intuitive, but is explained by the observation that with high noise (i.e., low correlation) the fact that a student is rejected
当决策者观察到每个候选人的素质取决于他们属于哪个人口群体时,统计歧视就会产生[1,8]。不完美的估计已经通过噪声建模,其中方差取决于候选人的群体([4,6,7])。然而,先前的文献仅限于简单的选择问题,即单个决策者试图从他们收到的申请中选择最佳候选人。在本文中,我们开始研究匹配中的统计歧视,其中多个决策者同时面临从同一候选人池中选择问题。我们认为大学录取问题在b[5]中首次引入,最近扩展到一个具有连续学生b[3]的模型。我们提出了一个模型,其中两个学院a和B观察每个候选人质量的噪声估计,其中Ws,学生s的估计向量,被假设为一个二元正态随机变量。在这种情况下,估计噪声控制了问题的一个新的关键特征,即两个学院的估计之间的相关性ρ:如果噪声高,相关性就低,如果噪声低,相关性就高。我们假设学生总体分为G1和G2两组,这两组的成员在A和b大学的成绩具有不同的相关水平。具体来说,对于每个学生s,他们的成绩向量(WAs, WBs)根据方差为1,协方差为ρGs的中心二元正态分布绘制,其中g为学生s所属的组。我们考虑了由这种分布引起的稳定匹配,并描述了关键结果特征如何随参数变化,特别是随组相关系数变化。我们的结果总结如下:我们表明,学生被分配到第一选择的概率与学生所在的组无关,但当任何一组的相关性降低时,它就会降低。这意味着对一个组较高的测量噪声(导致较低的相关性)不仅伤害了该组的学生,而且伤害了所有组的学生。我们表明,学生被分配到第二选择的概率和他们未被分配的概率都取决于学生的群体,这揭示了仅来自相关效应的统计歧视的存在。具体来说,我们发现,当一个学生所在组的相关性降低(测量噪声较高),而另一个组的相关性增加时,这个学生保持不匹配的概率就会降低。换句话说,他们所在群体的测量噪声越高,学生被分配到大学的可能性就越大。这有点违反直觉,但可以通过观察来解释,即在高噪声(即低相关性)的情况下,学生被一所大学拒绝的事实只能提供很少关于另一所大学结果的信息。也就是说,学生有独立的第二次入学机会。这两个比较静态结果揭示了相关性对不同人口群体稳定匹配结果的影响,表明统计歧视确实是理解匹配问题中歧视的重要理论。我们还分析了我们模型的一些特殊情况,特别是单个组的情况,以表明即使在这种情况下,相关性也会影响结果。有趣的是,在我们的模型中,相关性对获得第一选择的学生数量的影响与[2]中相同,即相关性越高,获得第一选择的学生越多。我们的工作是第一个调查匹配背景下的统计歧视。总体而言,我们发现候选人质量的群体依赖测量噪声-以及由此产生的大学估计之间的群体依赖相关性-在导致不同人口群体的不平等结果方面发挥了重要作用,特别是其中一个群体的代表性不足。当然,我们并不认为统计上的歧视是造成歧视的唯一可能原因。特别是,如果对一个群体的质量估计存在偏差,那么它自然也会损害该群体的代表性。我们没有建立偏差模型,因为我们的主要目的是隔离统计歧视的影响。在整篇论文中,我们做了一些其他的简化假设(例如,专注于两所大学),其目的也是为了简化我们的结果并隔离相关性的影响。然而,我们的分析扩展到更一般的情况。
{"title":"Statistical Discrimination in Stable Matchings","authors":"Rémi Castera, P. Loiseau, Bary S. R. Pradelski","doi":"10.1145/3490486.3538364","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1145/3490486.3538364","url":null,"abstract":"Statistical discrimination results when a decision-maker observes an imperfect estimate of the quality of each candidate dependent on which demographic group they belong to [1,8]. Imperfect estimates have been modelled via noise, where the variance depends on the candidate's group ([4,6,7]). Prior literature, however, is limited to simple selection problems, where a single decision-maker tries to choose the best candidates among the applications they received. In this paper, we initiate the study of statistical discrimination in matching, where multiple decision-makers are simultaneously facing selection problems from the same pool of candidates. We consider the college admission problem as first introduced in [5] and recently extended to a model with a continuum of students [3]. We propose a model where two colleges A and B observe noisy estimates of each candidate's quality, where Ws, the vector of estimates for student s, is assumed to be a bivariate normal random variable. In this setting, the estimation noise controls a new key feature of the problem, namely correlation, ρ, between the estimates of the two colleges: if the noise is high, the correlation is low and if the noise is low the correlation is high. We assume that the population of students is divided into two groups G1 and G2, and that members of these two groups are subject to different correlation levels between their grades at colleges A and B. Concretely, for each student s, their grade vector (WAs, WBs) is drawn according to a centered bivariate normal distribution with variance 1 and covariance ρGs, where Gs is the group student s belongs to. We consider the stable matching induced by this distribution and characterize how key outcome characteristics vary with the parameters, in particular with the group-dependent correlation coefficient. Our results summarize as follows: We show that the probability that a student is assigned to their first choice is independent of the student's group, but that it decreases when the correlation of either group decreases. This means that higher measurement noise (inducing lower correlation) on one group hurts not only the students of that group, but the students of all groups. We show that the probability that a student is assigned to their second choice and the probability that they remain unassigned both depend on the student's group, which reveals the presence of statistical discrimination coming from the correlation effect alone. Specifically, we find that the probability that a student remains unmatched is decreasing when the correlation of their group decreases (higher measurement noise) and when the correlation of the other group increases. In other words, the higher the measurement noise of their own group, the better off students are with regard to getting assigned a college at all. This is somewhat counter-intuitive, but is explained by the observation that with high noise (i.e., low correlation) the fact that a student is rejected ","PeriodicalId":209859,"journal":{"name":"Proceedings of the 23rd ACM Conference on Economics and Computation","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2022-07-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"131675392","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 3
期刊
Proceedings of the 23rd ACM Conference on Economics and Computation
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1