首页 > 最新文献

World Competition最新文献

英文 中文
Book Review: Healthcare, Quality Concerns and Competition Law: A Systematic Approach, Theodosia Stavroulaki. Hart Publishing. Oxford, England: 2023 书评:《医疗保健、质量问题和竞争法:一个系统的方法》,Theodosia Stavroulaki著。哈特出版社出版。牛津,英国:2023年
IF 0.4 Q2 LAW Pub Date : 2023-06-01 DOI: 10.54648/woco2023008
Spencer Weber Waller
{"title":"Book Review: Healthcare, Quality Concerns and Competition Law: A Systematic Approach, Theodosia Stavroulaki. Hart Publishing. Oxford, England: 2023","authors":"Spencer Weber Waller","doi":"10.54648/woco2023008","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.54648/woco2023008","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":43861,"journal":{"name":"World Competition","volume":"1985 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.4,"publicationDate":"2023-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"88553785","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Moderating Globalization: Is There a Role for Antitrust Law? A Comparison of the Relevance of Entry, Expansion and Imports in US and EU Merger Proceedings 缓和全球化:反垄断法是否有作用?美国和欧盟并购程序中进入、扩张和进口的相关性比较
IF 0.4 Q2 LAW Pub Date : 2023-06-01 DOI: 10.54648/woco2023010
Paul Friederiszick
This paper attempts to locate the issue of innovation and foreign entry, in particular new entrants from China, in recent US and EU merger decisions. In the first part, the paper examines to what extend US and EU authorities considered foreign entry in recent major merger decisions such as Bayer/Monsanto, Dow/DuPont and ChemChina/Syngenta. The outcome of this short analysis shows that the EU Commission has in recent years begun to accept the argument of foreign entry, in particular from China, as long as the market shares of the merging parties are not too high. The US has not explicitly discussed the question of foreign entry in the above-named decisions. However, in the case Whirlpool/Maytag the US authorities accepted, despite high market shares of the parties, the argument of foreign entry and approved the merger. With regards to innovation, entry into future product markets is not considered favourable to the merging parties by the EU Commission. ‘Innovation competition’ or early ‘pipeline products’ is rather used as an argument to demonstrate that the merging parties hold market power in product markets in the future. Based on the selected case law, the US authorities, by contrast, did recognize entry into future product markets as an argument in favour of the merging parties.In its second part, the paper looks at the pros and cons of forming ‘national champions’ and discusses competition law enforcement in light of the numerous and politically powerful Chinese state-owned enterprises (SOEs).Global competition/antitrust law and policy, foreign entry in merger decisions and China, innovation competition, entry criteria in US/EU mergers, climate change
本文试图找出创新和外国进入的问题,特别是来自中国的新进入者,在最近的美国和欧盟的合并决策。在第一部分中,本文考察了美国和欧盟当局在最近的重大合并决策(如拜耳/孟山都,陶氏/杜邦和中国化工/先正达)中考虑外国进入的程度。这一简短分析的结果表明,欧盟委员会近年来开始接受外资进入的说法,尤其是来自中国的外资,只要并购各方的市场份额不太高。美国没有在上述决定中明确讨论外国进入的问题。然而,在惠而浦/美泰案中,尽管双方的市场份额很高,但美国当局接受了外资进入的论点,并批准了合并。在创新方面,欧盟委员会认为进入未来产品市场对合并方不利。“创新竞争”或早期的“管道产品”被用来证明合并方在未来的产品市场上拥有市场支配力。相比之下,根据选定的判例法,美国当局确实承认,进入未来产品市场是有利于合并各方的一个理由。在第二部分,本文考察了组建“国家冠军企业”的利弊,并讨论了中国国有企业数量众多、政治上强大的竞争执法问题。全球竞争/反垄断法和政策,并购决策和中国的外资进入,创新竞争,美国/欧盟并购的进入标准,气候变化
{"title":"Moderating Globalization: Is There a Role for Antitrust Law? A Comparison of the Relevance of Entry, Expansion and Imports in US and EU Merger Proceedings","authors":"Paul Friederiszick","doi":"10.54648/woco2023010","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.54648/woco2023010","url":null,"abstract":"This paper attempts to locate the issue of innovation and foreign entry, in particular new entrants from China, in recent US and EU merger decisions. In the first part, the paper examines to what extend US and EU authorities considered foreign entry in recent major merger decisions such as Bayer/Monsanto, Dow/DuPont and ChemChina/Syngenta. The outcome of this short analysis shows that the EU Commission has in recent years begun to accept the argument of foreign entry, in particular from China, as long as the market shares of the merging parties are not too high. The US has not explicitly discussed the question of foreign entry in the above-named decisions. However, in the case Whirlpool/Maytag the US authorities accepted, despite high market shares of the parties, the argument of foreign entry and approved the merger. With regards to innovation, entry into future product markets is not considered favourable to the merging parties by the EU Commission. ‘Innovation competition’ or early ‘pipeline products’ is rather used as an argument to demonstrate that the merging parties hold market power in product markets in the future. Based on the selected case law, the US authorities, by contrast, did recognize entry into future product markets as an argument in favour of the merging parties.\u0000In its second part, the paper looks at the pros and cons of forming ‘national champions’ and discusses competition law enforcement in light of the numerous and politically powerful Chinese state-owned enterprises (SOEs).\u0000Global competition/antitrust law and policy, foreign entry in merger decisions and China, innovation competition, entry criteria in US/EU mergers, climate change","PeriodicalId":43861,"journal":{"name":"World Competition","volume":"53 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.4,"publicationDate":"2023-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"77205052","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Compulsory v. Voluntary Merger Notification Mechanism: Implications of China’s Enforcement for Young Competition Jurisdictions 强制与自愿合并通知机制:中国对年轻竞争司法管辖区执行的启示
IF 0.4 Q2 LAW Pub Date : 2022-09-01 DOI: 10.54648/woco2022017
Liyang Hou, Jian Li
The internationally dominant compulsory notification mechanism under merger control aims to remedy anti-competitive harm by blocking or conditionally approving mergers ex ante. However, such a mechanism is not free from disadvantages. As an alternative, the voluntary notification mechanism, though superficially producing fewer deterrence effects, is in effect no worse than the compulsory mechanism (CM), given its significantly less implementation costs. In order to examine which mechanism suits a given jurisdiction, it is necessary to evaluate the costs and benefits for the implementation of such a mechanism. The enforcement of the CM in China can be argued to present insufficient benefits and high costs, due to the extreme low proportion of blocked and conditional approved cases, as well as the unsatisfactory deterrence effect, and the significant constraints by implementing resources, in particular human capital. Such a particular situation in China implies that the voluntary mechanism (VM) might be advisable to be a more feasible option for young competition jurisdictions.Merger Control, Compulsory Notification, Voluntary Notification, Cost and Benefit Analysis, Young Antitrust Jurisdictions
国际上占主导地位的并购控制强制通知机制旨在通过事先阻止或有条件地批准并购来弥补反竞争损害。然而,这种机制并非没有缺点。作为替代方案,自愿通知机制虽然表面上产生的威慑效果较小,但实际上并不比强制机制差,因为其实施成本要低得多。为了审查哪一种机制适合某一司法管辖区,有必要评估实施这种机制的成本和效益。在中国,由于被阻止和有条件批准的案件比例极低,以及威慑效果不理想,以及实施资源,特别是人力资本的重大约束,可以认为CM的执行呈现出不足的效益和高成本。中国的这种特殊情况意味着自愿机制(VM)可能是年轻竞争司法管辖区更可行的选择。并购控制,强制通知,自愿通知,成本与收益分析,年轻的反垄断管辖
{"title":"Compulsory v. Voluntary Merger Notification Mechanism: Implications of China’s Enforcement for Young Competition Jurisdictions","authors":"Liyang Hou, Jian Li","doi":"10.54648/woco2022017","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.54648/woco2022017","url":null,"abstract":"The internationally dominant compulsory notification mechanism under merger control aims to remedy anti-competitive harm by blocking or conditionally approving mergers ex ante. However, such a mechanism is not free from disadvantages. As an alternative, the voluntary notification mechanism, though superficially producing fewer deterrence effects, is in effect no worse than the compulsory mechanism (CM), given its significantly less implementation costs. In order to examine which mechanism suits a given jurisdiction, it is necessary to evaluate the costs and benefits for the implementation of such a mechanism. The enforcement of the CM in China can be argued to present insufficient benefits and high costs, due to the extreme low proportion of blocked and conditional approved cases, as well as the unsatisfactory deterrence effect, and the significant constraints by implementing resources, in particular human capital. Such a particular situation in China implies that the voluntary mechanism (VM) might be advisable to be a more feasible option for young competition jurisdictions.\u0000Merger Control, Compulsory Notification, Voluntary Notification, Cost and Benefit Analysis, Young Antitrust Jurisdictions","PeriodicalId":43861,"journal":{"name":"World Competition","volume":"91 2 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.4,"publicationDate":"2022-09-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"90978457","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Book Review: The Patent-Competition Interface In Developing Countries 书评:发展中国家的专利-竞争界面
IF 0.4 Q2 LAW Pub Date : 2022-09-01 DOI: 10.54648/woco2022018
{"title":"Book Review: The Patent-Competition Interface In Developing Countries","authors":"","doi":"10.54648/woco2022018","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.54648/woco2022018","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":43861,"journal":{"name":"World Competition","volume":"2 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.4,"publicationDate":"2022-09-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"81646311","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Practical Considerations on the Notion of ‘Advantage’ and the Application of Market Economy Operator Test in the Context of Financial Instruments 金融工具背景下“优势”概念及市场经济经营者检验应用的实践思考
IF 0.4 Q2 LAW Pub Date : 2022-09-01 DOI: 10.54648/woco2022016
F. Dascalescu, M. Houtman
This article focuses on the notion of ‘advantage’, as an element necessary for a national measure to be qualified as state aid. Behaving like a private economic operator implies that the state remains profitoriented and does not grant an advantage to a recipient undertaking (i.e., no aid). In order to determine that economic transactions carried out by public bodies do not confer an advantage on the recipient, the European courts have developed, as of the mid-1980s, a test which implies the comparison between the state and a private economic operator. This article focuses on a number of key issues arising when applying the ‘market economy operator test’ (MEOT) to Member States’ (MSs’) investments, especially in the area of financial instruments, e.g., equity or quasi-equity investments, loans or guarantees. The recent EU soft law indicates the forms that the MEOT may take and clarifies the state’s role in co-investments in financial instruments, together with private investors. The existing EU case-law may be useful for subtracting some principles to assist practitioners with designing financial products in line with the MEOT and avoid the negative effects of illegal aid recovery. We conclude that more proxies may be provided via soft law by the European Commission for designing financial products under the MEOT, in an effort to increase access to finance to European companies.state aid, MEOT, private investor, financial instruments, risk finance measures
本文重点讨论了“优势”的概念,将其作为一项国家措施获得国家援助资格的必要因素。像私营经济经营者那样行事意味着国家仍然以利润为导向,不给予受助企业利益(即不提供援助)。为了确定由公共机构进行的经济交易不会给接受者带来利益,欧洲法院从1980年代中期开始制定了一项测试,将国家和私营经济经营者进行比较。本文重点讨论在将“市场经济运营商测试”(MEOT)应用于成员国(ms)投资时出现的一些关键问题,特别是在金融工具领域,例如股权或准股权投资、贷款或担保。最近的欧盟软法表明了MEOT可能采取的形式,并澄清了国家在与私人投资者共同投资金融工具中的作用。现有的欧盟判例法可能有助于减去一些原则,以帮助从业人员设计符合MEOT的金融产品,并避免非法援助回收的负面影响。我们的结论是,欧盟委员会可以通过软法律提供更多的代理,以设计MEOT下的金融产品,以增加欧洲公司获得融资的机会。国家援助、MEOT、民间投资者、金融工具、风险融资措施
{"title":"Practical Considerations on the Notion of ‘Advantage’ and the Application of Market Economy Operator Test in the Context of Financial Instruments","authors":"F. Dascalescu, M. Houtman","doi":"10.54648/woco2022016","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.54648/woco2022016","url":null,"abstract":"This article focuses on the notion of ‘advantage’, as an element necessary for a national measure to be qualified as state aid. Behaving like a private economic operator implies that the state remains profitoriented and does not grant an advantage to a recipient undertaking (i.e., no aid). In order to determine that economic transactions carried out by public bodies do not confer an advantage on the recipient, the European courts have developed, as of the mid-1980s, a test which implies the comparison between the state and a private economic operator. This article focuses on a number of key issues arising when applying the ‘market economy operator test’ (MEOT) to Member States’ (MSs’) investments, especially in the area of financial instruments, e.g., equity or quasi-equity investments, loans or guarantees. The recent EU soft law indicates the forms that the MEOT may take and clarifies the state’s role in co-investments in financial instruments, together with private investors. The existing EU case-law may be useful for subtracting some principles to assist practitioners with designing financial products in line with the MEOT and avoid the negative effects of illegal aid recovery. We conclude that more proxies may be provided via soft law by the European Commission for designing financial products under the MEOT, in an effort to increase access to finance to European companies.\u0000state aid, MEOT, private investor, financial instruments, risk finance measures","PeriodicalId":43861,"journal":{"name":"World Competition","volume":"203 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.4,"publicationDate":"2022-09-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"77005486","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
A Positive Program for Antitrust? Enforcement in Times of Political Tides 反垄断的积极方案?政治浪潮时代的执法
IF 0.4 Q2 LAW Pub Date : 2022-06-01 DOI: 10.54648/woco2022009
Jan Polański
The rise of Big Tech led to a still ongoing debate over the shape of antitrust enforcement. Many of such discussions take place in the United States and focus on the validity of consumer welfare standard, often leading each party of the discussion to entrench its position. In the European context, however, the success of the consumer welfare standard was never so full as in the United States, making way instead to the adoption of a ‘more economic approach’. This article discusses how the current tension within antitrust could be looked at from the European point of view. It suggests that antitrust might be subject to a perpetual movement between what has already been described in European antitrust as the more economic approach and what could be now termed as a more political approach. The article investigates what elements could be seen as part of such a more political approach. It leaves aside the question of which approach is the ‘correct’ one and attempts instead to look for ways of adjusting enforcement in times of change. The article concludes that while the more economic and more political approach are at odds, there appear to be ways of easing tensions within antitrust when political conditions change.Big Tech, Chicago School, consumer welfare, efficiency, enforcement, more economic approach, neobrandeisianism, ordoliberalism, populism, public goals
大型科技公司的崛起引发了一场关于反垄断执法形式的辩论,这场辩论至今仍在进行。许多这样的讨论发生在美国,关注消费者福利标准的有效性,往往导致讨论的每一方都巩固自己的立场。然而,在欧洲,消费者福利标准的成功从来没有像美国那样充分,取而代之的是采用一种“更经济的方法”。本文讨论了如何从欧洲的角度看待当前反垄断内部的紧张局势。它表明,反垄断可能会在欧洲反垄断中已经被描述为更经济的方法和现在可以被称为更政治的方法之间不断变化。这篇文章调查了哪些因素可以被视为这种更具政治性的方法的一部分。它把哪种方法是“正确”的问题放在一边,而是试图寻找在变化时期调整执行的方法。这篇文章的结论是,尽管更经济和更政治的方法存在分歧,但当政治条件发生变化时,似乎有办法缓解反垄断内部的紧张关系。大科技、芝加哥学派、消费者福利、效率、执法、更经济的方法、新品牌主义、世界自由主义、民粹主义、公共目标
{"title":"A Positive Program for Antitrust? Enforcement in Times of Political Tides","authors":"Jan Polański","doi":"10.54648/woco2022009","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.54648/woco2022009","url":null,"abstract":"The rise of Big Tech led to a still ongoing debate over the shape of antitrust enforcement. Many of such discussions take place in the United States and focus on the validity of consumer welfare standard, often leading each party of the discussion to entrench its position. In the European context, however, the success of the consumer welfare standard was never so full as in the United States, making way instead to the adoption of a ‘more economic approach’. This article discusses how the current tension within antitrust could be looked at from the European point of view. It suggests that antitrust might be subject to a perpetual movement between what has already been described in European antitrust as the more economic approach and what could be now termed as a more political approach. The article investigates what elements could be seen as part of such a more political approach. It leaves aside the question of which approach is the ‘correct’ one and attempts instead to look for ways of adjusting enforcement in times of change. The article concludes that while the more economic and more political approach are at odds, there appear to be ways of easing tensions within antitrust when political conditions change.\u0000Big Tech, Chicago School, consumer welfare, efficiency, enforcement, more economic approach, neobrandeisianism, ordoliberalism, populism, public goals","PeriodicalId":43861,"journal":{"name":"World Competition","volume":"69 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.4,"publicationDate":"2022-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"89350645","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Why Does Regulation (EC) No 1/2003 Provide for the Imposition of Penalties Only on Undertakings?: A Historical Perspective 为什么法规(EC) No 1/2003只规定对承诺实施处罚?历史的视角
IF 0.4 Q2 LAW Pub Date : 2022-06-01 DOI: 10.54648/woco2022008
Walter Mölls
According to Article 23(2)(a) of Regulation (EC) No 1/2003, the Commission may impose any fines for the breach of substantive competition rules only on ‘undertakings’. The provision does not contemplate the imposition of fines on individuals considered responsible for the conduct of the undertaking concerned, even though, as explained in this article, this position is not imposed by the relevant legal basis (Article 83 EC [the Treaty establishing the European Community in the version following the Treaty of Amsterdam], corresponding to Article 87 EEC Treaty [the Treaty establishing the European Economic Community in its version of 1957] and the present Article 103 TFEU [the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union]) That legal basis would indeed allow such liability to be established. From a policy point of view, however, it is often argued that sanctions should also be imposed on such individuals. This raises the question as to why the Union legislator chose not to provide for corresponding powers on the Commission’s part. From the relevant legislative history exposed in this article, it emerges that the approach of Article 23(2)(a) ultimately originates from the ECSC Treaty [theTreaty establishing the European Coal and Steel Community]. In this latter context, it reflected the particular limits placed by its authors on that Treaty. It did not reflect the contemporary orientations at national level regarding punitive sanctions. The approach gradually found its way into Regulation (EC) No 1/2003 without any further specific discussion on the way, despite the different context offered by the relevant provisions of the EEC/EC Treaty. It was first transplanted into Regulation No 11, based on Article 79 EEC Treaty (today Article 95 TFEU) and concerning the abolition of discrimination in transport rates and conditions. The negotiations preceding the adoption of this Regulation brought to light strong reserves regarding the conferral of sanctioning powers upon the (then) EEC, and it was no doubt unrealistic to expect that it would have been granted powers more far-reaching than those available under the ECSC Treaty. When Regulation No 17 (and specifically Article 15) was elaborated, the drafters were aware of the scheme established by Regulation No 11, which served as a reference. No genuine discussion regarding possible powers to punish the persons considered responsible for the conduct of the ‘undertaking’ took place. It is likely that any such innovation would not have been realistic at that point. Lastly, the reform brought about by Regulation (EC) No 1/2003 focused on other aspects regarding the implementation of competition law, and the scheme of Article 15(2) of Regulation No 17 has been taken over into Article 23(2) of Regulation (EC) No 1/2013 without major changes. No consideration was given to the possible imposition of penalties on natural persons implicated in the commission of breaches of competition law.EU antitrust sanctions, Eu
根据法规(EC) No 1/2003第23(2)(a)条,委员会只能对“承诺”处以违反实质性竞争规则的罚款。这项规定并不打算对被认为对有关事业的行为负有责任的个人处以罚款,尽管如本条所解释的,这种立场并不是由有关的法律依据所规定的(欧共体第83条[《阿姆斯特丹条约》之后的《建立欧洲共同体条约》],对应于《欧洲经济共同体条约》第87条[1957年版建立欧洲经济共同体的条约]和现行的《欧洲联盟运作条约》第103条],该法律基础确实允许建立这种责任。然而,从政策的角度来看,经常有人认为也应该对这些个人实施制裁。这就提出了一个问题,即为什么联盟立法者选择不规定委员会的相应权力。从本文所揭示的相关立法历史中可以看出,第23(2)(a)条的方法最终源于ECSC条约[建立欧洲煤钢共同体条约]。在后一种情况下,它反映了其作者对该《条约》所作的特殊限制。它没有反映当前国家一级关于惩罚性制裁的方针。尽管EEC/EC条约的相关条款提供了不同的背景,但这种方法在没有进一步具体讨论的情况下逐渐进入了(EC) No 1/2003法规。它首先被移植到第11号条例中,该条例基于《欧洲经济共同体条约》第79条(今天的《欧洲经济共同体条约》第95条),涉及取消运输费率和条件方面的歧视。本条例通过之前的谈判表明,在授予(当时的)欧共体制裁权力方面存在强烈的保留意见,期望欧共体获得比《欧共体条约》所赋予的更广泛的权力无疑是不现实的。在阐述第17号条例(特别是第15条)时,起草者知道第11号条例所建立的方案,这可以作为参考。关于惩罚被认为对“承诺”行为负有责任的人的可能权力,没有进行真正的讨论。在那个时候,任何这样的创新都可能是不现实的。最后,第(EC) 1/2003号条例带来的改革侧重于竞争法实施的其他方面,第17号条例第15(2)条的方案已被接管为第(EC) 1/2013号条例第23(2)条,没有重大变化。没有考虑到可能对涉嫌违反竞争法的自然人施加惩罚。欧盟反垄断制裁,欧盟委员会,个别制裁,第1/ 2003号条例,第17号条例,第11号条例,ECSC条约,历史
{"title":"Why Does Regulation (EC) No 1/2003 Provide for the Imposition of Penalties Only on Undertakings?: A Historical Perspective","authors":"Walter Mölls","doi":"10.54648/woco2022008","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.54648/woco2022008","url":null,"abstract":"According to Article 23(2)(a) of Regulation (EC) No 1/2003, the Commission may impose any fines for the breach of substantive competition rules only on ‘undertakings’. The provision does not contemplate the imposition of fines on individuals considered responsible for the conduct of the undertaking concerned, even though, as explained in this article, this position is not imposed by the relevant legal basis (Article 83 EC [the Treaty establishing the European Community in the version following the Treaty of Amsterdam], corresponding to Article 87 EEC Treaty [the Treaty establishing the European Economic Community in its version of 1957] and the present Article 103 TFEU [the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union]) That legal basis would indeed allow such liability to be established. From a policy point of view, however, it is often argued that sanctions should also be imposed on such individuals. This raises the question as to why the Union legislator chose not to provide for corresponding powers on the Commission’s part. From the relevant legislative history exposed in this article, it emerges that the approach of Article 23(2)(a) ultimately originates from the ECSC Treaty [theTreaty establishing the European Coal and Steel Community]. In this latter context, it reflected the particular limits placed by its authors on that Treaty. It did not reflect the contemporary orientations at national level regarding punitive sanctions. The approach gradually found its way into Regulation (EC) No 1/2003 without any further specific discussion on the way, despite the different context offered by the relevant provisions of the EEC/EC Treaty. It was first transplanted into Regulation No 11, based on Article 79 EEC Treaty (today Article 95 TFEU) and concerning the abolition of discrimination in transport rates and conditions. The negotiations preceding the adoption of this Regulation brought to light strong reserves regarding the conferral of sanctioning powers upon the (then) EEC, and it was no doubt unrealistic to expect that it would have been granted powers more far-reaching than those available under the ECSC Treaty. When Regulation No 17 (and specifically Article 15) was elaborated, the drafters were aware of the scheme established by Regulation No 11, which served as a reference. No genuine discussion regarding possible powers to punish the persons considered responsible for the conduct of the ‘undertaking’ took place. It is likely that any such innovation would not have been realistic at that point. Lastly, the reform brought about by Regulation (EC) No 1/2003 focused on other aspects regarding the implementation of competition law, and the scheme of Article 15(2) of Regulation No 17 has been taken over into Article 23(2) of Regulation (EC) No 1/2013 without major changes. No consideration was given to the possible imposition of penalties on natural persons implicated in the commission of breaches of competition law.\u0000EU antitrust sanctions, Eu","PeriodicalId":43861,"journal":{"name":"World Competition","volume":"32 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.4,"publicationDate":"2022-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"88126888","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Book Review: Alexandr Svetlicinii, Chinese State Owned Enterprises and EU Merger Control, Routledge. 2021 书评:alexander Svetlicinii:《中国国有企业与欧盟并购控制》,劳特利奇出版社,2021
IF 0.4 Q2 LAW Pub Date : 2022-06-01 DOI: 10.54648/woco2022012
Anna Panarella
{"title":"Book Review: Alexandr Svetlicinii, Chinese State Owned Enterprises and EU Merger Control, Routledge. 2021","authors":"Anna Panarella","doi":"10.54648/woco2022012","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.54648/woco2022012","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":43861,"journal":{"name":"World Competition","volume":"59 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.4,"publicationDate":"2022-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"81360916","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Cultural Capture of Competition Policy: Exploring the Risk in the US and the EU 竞争政策的文化俘获:探讨美国和欧盟的风险
IF 0.4 Q2 LAW Pub Date : 2022-06-01 DOI: 10.54648/woco2022007
J. Broulík
This article explores whether there is a risk that competition policy on both sides of the Atlantic could be distorted by cultural capture. This type of capture differs from traditional regulatory capture operating through self-interest of public officials. It instead arises when policy-relevant views of the officials are subject to disproportionate social influence exerted by representatives of the private sector. The question here is hence whether social interactions enabling this influence take place between competition officials and practitioners. The article answers in the affirmative, finding that many competition officials seem to self-identify with a community dominated by competition practitioners, hold the practitioners in high regard, and have interpersonal relationships with the practitioners. These risk factors are especially pronounced in the United States. There is thus a possibility that competition policy could be designed and enforced in a way that furthers interests of big business to the detriment of consumers and small businesses. The article also discusses preventive measures to limit cultural capture of competition policy such as promotion of diversity and reduction of revolving door, cautioning nevertheless that difficult trade-offs may need to be made in their implementation.agency independence, anti-interventionism, competition community, competition policy, cultural capture, Antitrust Division, DG Competition, Bureau of Competition, regulatory capture, revolving door, social influence
本文探讨了大西洋两岸的竞争政策是否存在被文化俘获扭曲的风险。这种类型的捕获不同于传统的通过公共官员自身利益运作的监管捕获。相反,当官员的政策相关观点受到私营部门代表施加的不成比例的社会影响时,就会出现这种情况。因此,这里的问题是,促成这种影响的社会互动是否发生在竞赛官员和从业者之间。文章的答案是肯定的,发现许多竞赛官员似乎自我认同一个以竞赛从业者为主导的社区,并高度重视从业者,并与从业者建立了人际关系。这些风险因素在美国尤为明显。因此,有一种可能性是,竞争政策的设计和执行方式可能会促进大企业的利益,损害消费者和小企业的利益。文章还讨论了限制文化俘获竞争政策的预防措施,如促进多样性和减少旋转门,但警告说,在实施过程中可能需要做出艰难的权衡。机构独立、反干预主义、竞争共同体、竞争政策、文化俘获、反垄断司、竞争总局、监管俘获、旋转门、社会影响
{"title":"Cultural Capture of Competition Policy: Exploring the Risk in the US and the EU","authors":"J. Broulík","doi":"10.54648/woco2022007","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.54648/woco2022007","url":null,"abstract":"This article explores whether there is a risk that competition policy on both sides of the Atlantic could be distorted by cultural capture. This type of capture differs from traditional regulatory capture operating through self-interest of public officials. It instead arises when policy-relevant views of the officials are subject to disproportionate social influence exerted by representatives of the private sector. The question here is hence whether social interactions enabling this influence take place between competition officials and practitioners. The article answers in the affirmative, finding that many competition officials seem to self-identify with a community dominated by competition practitioners, hold the practitioners in high regard, and have interpersonal relationships with the practitioners. These risk factors are especially pronounced in the United States. There is thus a possibility that competition policy could be designed and enforced in a way that furthers interests of big business to the detriment of consumers and small businesses. The article also discusses preventive measures to limit cultural capture of competition policy such as promotion of diversity and reduction of revolving door, cautioning nevertheless that difficult trade-offs may need to be made in their implementation.\u0000agency independence, anti-interventionism, competition community, competition policy, cultural capture, Antitrust Division, DG Competition, Bureau of Competition, regulatory capture, revolving door, social influence","PeriodicalId":43861,"journal":{"name":"World Competition","volume":"100 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.4,"publicationDate":"2022-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"89760347","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
The European Commission’s Handling of Non-priority Antitrust Complaints: An Empirical Assessment 欧盟委员会对非优先反垄断投诉的处理:一项实证评估
IF 0.4 Q2 LAW Pub Date : 2022-06-01 DOI: 10.54648/woco2022010
B. Van Rompuy
The Union legislature and courts leave the European Commission a wide discretion in dealing with antitrust complaints submitted to it. The principal external constraint is that if the Commission chooses not to pursue a formal complaint, it must reject it by means of a reasoned decision, which may be subject to judicial review. But the Commission’s administrative discretion is primarily structured and confined by self-imposed rules and principles. Most of these were introduced or formalized when Regulation 1/2003 was adopted and were intended to incentivize complainants to inform the Commission about potential infringements of the EU antitrust rules.This article maps the precise boundaries of the Commission’s discretion to shelve non-priority antitrust complaints and subsequently examines how the Commission operates within that discretionary space. The empirical analysis is based on a unique dataset of all the rejection decisions the Commission adopted between 2009 and 2021, many of which were uncovered and obtained through access to documents requests. It reveals certain discrepancies between the stated rules and principles governing its treatment of complaints and their implementation in practice, which have the clear potential to undermine the incentives the current complaint handling system sought to create for the filing of formal complaints.antitrust, European Commission, complaints, complainant, prioritization, rejection, enforcement, discretion, priority setting
欧盟立法机构和法院在处理提交给欧盟委员会的反垄断投诉时给予了它广泛的自由裁量权。主要的外部限制是,如果委员会选择不追究正式申诉,它必须以合理的决定予以驳回,这一决定可能受到司法审查。但是,委员会的行政裁量权主要是由自我强加的规则和原则构成和限制的。其中大多数是在第1/2003号法规通过时引入或正式确定的,旨在激励投诉人向欧盟委员会通报可能违反欧盟反垄断规则的行为。本文绘制了委员会搁置非优先反垄断投诉的自由裁量权的精确边界,并随后研究了委员会如何在该自由裁量权范围内运作。实证分析基于一个独特的数据集,该数据集包含了委员会在2009年至2021年期间通过的所有拒绝决定,其中许多决定是通过查阅文件请求获得的。它揭示了规定的处理申诉的规则和原则与实际执行情况之间的某些差异,这显然有可能破坏目前的申诉处理制度为提出正式申诉而设法建立的奖励机制。反垄断,欧盟委员会,投诉,投诉者,优先排序,拒绝,执行,自由裁量权,优先设置
{"title":"The European Commission’s Handling of Non-priority Antitrust Complaints: An Empirical Assessment","authors":"B. Van Rompuy","doi":"10.54648/woco2022010","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.54648/woco2022010","url":null,"abstract":"The Union legislature and courts leave the European Commission a wide discretion in dealing with antitrust complaints submitted to it. The principal external constraint is that if the Commission chooses not to pursue a formal complaint, it must reject it by means of a reasoned decision, which may be subject to judicial review. But the Commission’s administrative discretion is primarily structured and confined by self-imposed rules and principles. Most of these were introduced or formalized when Regulation 1/2003 was adopted and were intended to incentivize complainants to inform the Commission about potential infringements of the EU antitrust rules.\u0000This article maps the precise boundaries of the Commission’s discretion to shelve non-priority antitrust complaints and subsequently examines how the Commission operates within that discretionary space. The empirical analysis is based on a unique dataset of all the rejection decisions the Commission adopted between 2009 and 2021, many of which were uncovered and obtained through access to documents requests. It reveals certain discrepancies between the stated rules and principles governing its treatment of complaints and their implementation in practice, which have the clear potential to undermine the incentives the current complaint handling system sought to create for the filing of formal complaints.\u0000antitrust, European Commission, complaints, complainant, prioritization, rejection, enforcement, discretion, priority setting","PeriodicalId":43861,"journal":{"name":"World Competition","volume":"9 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.4,"publicationDate":"2022-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"91244676","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
World Competition
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1