首页 > 最新文献

Journal of Legal Analysis最新文献

英文 中文
A New Publisher 新发行商
IF 2.2 1区 社会学 Q1 LAW Pub Date : 2011-12-01 DOI: 10.1093/JLA/LAR001
J. Ramseyer, S. Shavell, R. Jackson
{"title":"A New Publisher","authors":"J. Ramseyer, S. Shavell, R. Jackson","doi":"10.1093/JLA/LAR001","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/JLA/LAR001","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":45189,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Legal Analysis","volume":"126 1","pages":"377-377"},"PeriodicalIF":2.2,"publicationDate":"2011-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"90399936","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Tenancy In “Anticommons”? A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis of Co-Ownership “反公有物”中的租赁?共同所有权的理论与实证分析
IF 2.2 1区 社会学 Q1 LAW Pub Date : 2011-09-01 DOI: 10.1093/JLA/LAS011
Yun-chien Chang
This article argues that a resource held in tenancy in common is likely to be underused and underinvested, and is thus better characterized as an anticommons. Nevertheless, tenancy in common does not necessarily create tragedy, as under most legal regimes each co-tenant has a right to petition for partition at any time, and after partition, new owners are likely to utilize the resource more efficiently. Using data from Taiwan, this article finds that cooperation among co-tenants does not fail as often as the literature has suggested. In 2005–2010, at least 82.5% of the co-ownership partitions were conducted through voluntary agreements, while only about 7.5% of the partitions were ordered by the court. In addition, using multinomial logistic regression models, this article finds that the court tends to order, and the plaintiffs tend to petition for, partition by sale when partitioning in kind or partial partition would create excessively small plots.
本文认为,在共有财产中持有的资源很可能未被充分利用和投资,因此最好将其描述为反共有财产。然而,共有财产并不一定会造成悲剧,因为在大多数法律制度下,每个共有人都有权在任何时候申请分割,而且在分割之后,新的所有者可能会更有效地利用资源。本文使用台湾的数据,发现地产共有人之间的合作并不像文献所建议的那样经常失败。在2005-2010年间,至少82.5%的共有产权分割是通过自愿协议进行的,而只有约7.5%的共有产权分割是由法院下令进行的。此外,本文运用多项逻辑回归模型发现,当以实物分割或部分分割会产生过小的地块时,法院倾向于命令以出售分割,原告倾向于请求以出售分割。
{"title":"Tenancy In “Anticommons”? A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis of Co-Ownership","authors":"Yun-chien Chang","doi":"10.1093/JLA/LAS011","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/JLA/LAS011","url":null,"abstract":"This article argues that a resource held in tenancy in common is likely to be underused and underinvested, and is thus better characterized as an anticommons. Nevertheless, tenancy in common does not necessarily create tragedy, as under most legal regimes each co-tenant has a right to petition for partition at any time, and after partition, new owners are likely to utilize the resource more efficiently. Using data from Taiwan, this article finds that cooperation among co-tenants does not fail as often as the literature has suggested. In 2005–2010, at least 82.5% of the co-ownership partitions were conducted through voluntary agreements, while only about 7.5% of the partitions were ordered by the court. In addition, using multinomial logistic regression models, this article finds that the court tends to order, and the plaintiffs tend to petition for, partition by sale when partitioning in kind or partial partition would create excessively small plots.","PeriodicalId":45189,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Legal Analysis","volume":"6 1","pages":"515-553"},"PeriodicalIF":2.2,"publicationDate":"2011-09-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"82494959","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 13
Traynor (Drennan) Versus Hand (Baird) Much Ado About (Almost) Nothing 特雷纳(德伦南)对汉德(贝尔德)无事生
IF 2.2 1区 社会学 Q1 LAW Pub Date : 2011-03-25 DOI: 10.1093/JLA/LAR003
Victor P. Goldberg
Most Contracts casebooks feature either Baird v. Gimbel or (Drennan v. Star Paving to illustrate the limits on revocability of an offer. In this paper an analysis of the case law yields three major conclusions. First, as is generally known, in the contractor-subcontractor cases Drennan has prevailed. However, both it and its spawn, Restatement 2d 87(2), have had almost no impact outside that narrow area. Moreover, almost all the cases involve public construction projects - private projects account for only about ten percent of the cases. This suggests that private parties have managed to resolve the problem contractually. Public contract law is encrusted with regulations, which courts and contracts scholars have ignored. The result is a peculiar phenomenon - a supposedly general contract doctrine that applies only in a specific context, but which ignores the features of that context.
大多数合同案例都以Baird诉Gimbel案或Drennan诉Star铺路案为特色,以说明要约可撤销性的限制。本文通过对判例法的分析,得出了三个主要结论。首先,众所周知,在承包商-分包商案件中,德雷南占了上风。然而,它和它的衍生品《重述2d 87(2)》在这个狭窄区域之外几乎没有任何影响。此外,几乎所有的案件都涉及公共建设项目,私人项目仅占案件的10%左右。这表明,私人各方已经设法通过合同解决了这个问题。公共合同法有很多规定,而法院和合同学者却忽视了这些规定。其结果是一种奇特的现象——一种被认为是通用的合同原则,只适用于特定的语境,但却忽视了该语境的特点。
{"title":"Traynor (Drennan) Versus Hand (Baird) Much Ado About (Almost) Nothing","authors":"Victor P. Goldberg","doi":"10.1093/JLA/LAR003","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/JLA/LAR003","url":null,"abstract":"Most Contracts casebooks feature either Baird v. Gimbel or (Drennan v. Star Paving to illustrate the limits on revocability of an offer. In this paper an analysis of the case law yields three major conclusions. First, as is generally known, in the contractor-subcontractor cases Drennan has prevailed. However, both it and its spawn, Restatement 2d 87(2), have had almost no impact outside that narrow area. Moreover, almost all the cases involve public construction projects - private projects account for only about ten percent of the cases. This suggests that private parties have managed to resolve the problem contractually. Public contract law is encrusted with regulations, which courts and contracts scholars have ignored. The result is a peculiar phenomenon - a supposedly general contract doctrine that applies only in a specific context, but which ignores the features of that context.","PeriodicalId":45189,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Legal Analysis","volume":"71 1","pages":"539-585"},"PeriodicalIF":2.2,"publicationDate":"2011-03-25","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"85172564","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Should Business Method Inventions be Patentable 商业方法发明应该获得专利吗
IF 2.2 1区 社会学 Q1 LAW Pub Date : 2011-03-20 DOI: 10.1093/JLA/3.1.265
Daniel F. Spulber
In this article, I define business method inventions and provide an economic framework to address the question of patentability raised in Bilski. A business method invention is the discovery of a commercial technique that firms can apply to address market opportunities. The initial implementation of a business method invention by firms is a Schumpeterian innovation. I advance several arguments in favor of business method patentability. Business method inventions are an important foundation for entrepreneurship and a channel for the commercialization of scientific and technological inventions. IP protections for business method inventions are essential for economic efficiency, including incentives for invention, efficient allocation of inventions, and transaction efficiencies in the market for discoveries. Business method inventions are significant because they are the foundation of what I term the ‘‘Business Revolution’’: the augmentation and replacement of human effort in business transactions by computers, communications systems, and the Internet. I conclude that the patent system should continue to provide intellectual property protections for business method inventions just as it does for other types of inventions.
在本文中,我定义了商业方法发明,并提供了一个经济框架来解决Bilski案中提出的可专利性问题。商业方法发明是一种商业技术的发现,公司可以应用它来抓住市场机会。企业对商业方法发明的最初实施是熊彼特式创新。我提出了支持商业方法可专利性的几个论点。商业方法发明是创业的重要基础,是科技发明转化的重要渠道。对商业方法发明的知识产权保护对经济效率至关重要,包括对发明的激励、发明的有效分配和发现市场的交易效率。商业方法的发明意义重大,因为它们是我所说的“商业革命”的基础:计算机、通信系统和互联网增强和取代了人类在商业交易中的努力。我的结论是,专利制度应该继续为商业方法发明提供知识产权保护,就像它为其他类型的发明所做的那样。
{"title":"Should Business Method Inventions be Patentable","authors":"Daniel F. Spulber","doi":"10.1093/JLA/3.1.265","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/JLA/3.1.265","url":null,"abstract":"In this article, I define business method inventions and provide an economic framework to address the question of patentability raised in Bilski. A business method invention is the discovery of a commercial technique that firms can apply to address market opportunities. The initial implementation of a business method invention by firms is a Schumpeterian innovation. I advance several arguments in favor of business method patentability. Business method inventions are an important foundation for entrepreneurship and a channel for the commercialization of scientific and technological inventions. IP protections for business method inventions are essential for economic efficiency, including incentives for invention, efficient allocation of inventions, and transaction efficiencies in the market for discoveries. Business method inventions are significant because they are the foundation of what I term the ‘‘Business Revolution’’: the augmentation and replacement of human effort in business transactions by computers, communications systems, and the Internet. I conclude that the patent system should continue to provide intellectual property protections for business method inventions just as it does for other types of inventions.","PeriodicalId":45189,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Legal Analysis","volume":"10 1","pages":"265-340"},"PeriodicalIF":2.2,"publicationDate":"2011-03-20","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"76603301","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 28
Trial by Battle 战斗审判
IF 2.2 1区 社会学 Q1 LAW Pub Date : 2011-03-20 DOI: 10.1093/JLA/3.1.341
P. Leeson
For over a century England’s judicial system decided land disputes by ordering disputants’ legal representatives to bludgeon one another before an arena of spectating citizens. The victor won the property right for his principal. The vanquished lost his cause and, if he were unlucky, his life. People called these combats trials by battle. This paper investigates the law and economics of trial by battle. In a feudal world where high transaction costs confounded the Coase theorem, I argue that trial by battle allocated disputed property rights efficiently. It did this by allocating contested property to the higher bidder in an all-pay auction. Trial by battle’s ‘‘auctions’’ permitted rent seeking. But they encouraged less rent seeking than the obvious alternative: a first-price ascending-bid auction. ‘‘When man is emerging from barbarism, the struggle between the rising powers of reason and the waning forces of credulity, prejudice, and custom, is full of instruction.’’ —Henry C. Lea, Superstition and Force (1866, 73).
一个多世纪以来,英国的司法系统裁决土地纠纷的方式是,命令纠纷双方的法律代表在围观的公民面前互相大棒相向。胜利者为他的委托人赢得了财产权。被征服的人失去了他的事业,如果他不幸的话,还会失去他的生命。人们称这种战斗为逐战试验。本文从法学和经济学的角度考察了战审制度。在一个高交易成本使科斯定理难以成立的封建世界里,我认为通过战斗审判可以有效地分配有争议的产权。它通过在全付费拍卖中将有争议的财产分配给出价更高的竞标者来做到这一点。巴特的“拍卖”制度允许寻租。但与明显的另一种选择相比,它们鼓励的寻租行为更少:首价竞价拍卖。“当人类从野蛮状态中崛起时,崛起的理性力量与衰落的轻信、偏见和习俗力量之间的斗争充满了教益。——亨利·李,《迷信与力量》(1866,73)。
{"title":"Trial by Battle","authors":"P. Leeson","doi":"10.1093/JLA/3.1.341","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/JLA/3.1.341","url":null,"abstract":"For over a century England’s judicial system decided land disputes by ordering disputants’ legal representatives to bludgeon one another before an arena of spectating citizens. The victor won the property right for his principal. The vanquished lost his cause and, if he were unlucky, his life. People called these combats trials by battle. This paper investigates the law and economics of trial by battle. In a feudal world where high transaction costs confounded the Coase theorem, I argue that trial by battle allocated disputed property rights efficiently. It did this by allocating contested property to the higher bidder in an all-pay auction. Trial by battle’s ‘‘auctions’’ permitted rent seeking. But they encouraged less rent seeking than the obvious alternative: a first-price ascending-bid auction. ‘‘When man is emerging from barbarism, the struggle between the rising powers of reason and the waning forces of credulity, prejudice, and custom, is full of instruction.’’ —Henry C. Lea, Superstition and Force (1866, 73).","PeriodicalId":45189,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Legal Analysis","volume":"22 1","pages":"341-375"},"PeriodicalIF":2.2,"publicationDate":"2011-03-20","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"79121962","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 43
Whence Comes Section One? The Abolitionist Origins of the Fourteenth Amendment 第一部分从何而来?第十四修正案的废奴主义起源
IF 2.2 1区 社会学 Q1 LAW Pub Date : 2011-03-20 DOI: 10.1093/JLA/3.1.165
Randy E. Barnett
The contribution of abolitionist constitutionalism to the original public meaning of Section One of the Fourteenth Amendment was long obscured by a revisionist history that disparaged abolitionism, the “radical” Republicans, and their effort to establish democracy over Southern terrorism during Reconstruction. As a result, more Americans know about “carpetbaggers” than they do the framers of the Fourteenth Amendment. Despite a brief revival of interest stimulated by the writings of Howard Jay Graham and Jacobus tenBroek, in the 1970s and 1980s abolitionist constitutionalism remains obscure to law professors and even to historians of abolitionism. This study provides important evidence of the original public meaning of Section One. All the components of Section One were employed by a wide variety abolitionist lawyers and activists throughout the North, many of whom were instrumental in the formation of the Liberty, Free Soil, and Republican parties. To advance their case against slavery, they needed to appeal to the then-extant public meaning of the terms already in the Constitution. Moreover, their widely-circulated invocations of national citizenship, privileges and immunities, the due process of law, and equal protection made their own contribution to the public meaning in 1866 of the language that became Section One. The more one reads the forgotten writings of these “constitutional abolitionists,” the better their arguments look when compared with the opinions of the antebellum Supreme Court. But even if the Taney Court was right and the abolitionists wrong about the original meaning of the Constitution, the Thirteenth and Fourteenth Amendments were enacted to reverse the Court’s rulings. To appreciate fully the public meaning of these Amendments, therefore, we need to know whence they came. The Fourteenth Amendment is universally presumed to be the outcome of the organized antislavery movement in the United States, yet its modern history continues to be written without reference to the abolitionists. Judges and historians seek an understanding of phrases admittedly designed to secure the ‘‘freedom of the slave race’’ without first examining the tenets of the group which fought longest and hardest to establish that freedom. [T]he fight for liberty in this land was begun by the Radical Abolitionists long before the final battle..They were followed, however, by a class known as Constitutional Abolitionists; equally bold and brave, but more practical. It was the labor of the latter that accomplished glorious results; fought the good battle to a finish and destroyed the slave power. They were among the organizers of the Republican Party.
废奴主义宪政对第十四条修正案第一款最初的公共意义的贡献长期被修正主义历史所掩盖,这些修正主义历史贬低废奴主义、“激进的”共和党人,以及他们在重建期间为建立民主而对抗南方恐怖主义所做的努力。结果,更多的美国人知道“地毯冒险家”,而不是第十四条修正案的制定者。尽管在霍华德·杰伊·格雷厄姆和雅各布斯·滕布鲁克的著作刺激下,人们对废奴主义宪政的兴趣短暂复苏,但在20世纪70年代和80年代,废奴主义宪政对法学教授甚至废奴主义历史学家来说仍然是模糊的。本研究为第一节的原始公共意义提供了重要证据。第一分部的所有成员都为北方各地的废奴主义律师和活动家所雇用,其中许多人在自由、自由土地和共和党的形成中发挥了重要作用。为了推进他们反对奴隶制的案件,他们需要诉诸宪法中已经存在的术语的公共含义。此外,他们广泛流传的对国家公民权、特权和豁免、正当法律程序和平等保护的呼吁,对1866年成为第一部分的语言的公共意义作出了自己的贡献。人们越是阅读这些被遗忘的“宪法废奴主义者”的著作,他们的论点就越能与南北战争前最高法院的观点相比较。但是,即使特尼法院是正确的,废奴主义者对宪法原意的理解是错误的,第十三和第十四修正案的颁布也是为了推翻最高法院的裁决。因此,为了充分理解这些修正案对公众的意义,我们需要知道它们从何而来。第十四修正案被普遍认为是美国有组织的反奴隶制运动的结果,但其现代史仍然没有提到废奴主义者。法官和历史学家在寻求理解那些公认是为了确保“奴隶种族的自由”而设计的词句时,却没有首先考察为建立这种自由而进行了最长时间和最艰苦斗争的群体的信条。在这片土地上为自由而战的斗争早在最后一战之前就由激进的废奴主义者开始了,然而,紧随他们之后的是一个被称为宪法废奴主义者的阶级;同样大胆和勇敢,但更实际。正是后者的劳动取得了辉煌的成果;完成了这场美好的战斗,摧毁了奴隶的力量。他们是共和党的组织者之一。
{"title":"Whence Comes Section One? The Abolitionist Origins of the Fourteenth Amendment","authors":"Randy E. Barnett","doi":"10.1093/JLA/3.1.165","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/JLA/3.1.165","url":null,"abstract":"The contribution of abolitionist constitutionalism to the original public meaning of Section One of the Fourteenth Amendment was long obscured by a revisionist history that disparaged abolitionism, the “radical” Republicans, and their effort to establish democracy over Southern terrorism during Reconstruction. As a result, more Americans know about “carpetbaggers” than they do the framers of the Fourteenth Amendment. Despite a brief revival of interest stimulated by the writings of Howard Jay Graham and Jacobus tenBroek, in the 1970s and 1980s abolitionist constitutionalism remains obscure to law professors and even to historians of abolitionism. This study provides important evidence of the original public meaning of Section One. All the components of Section One were employed by a wide variety abolitionist lawyers and activists throughout the North, many of whom were instrumental in the formation of the Liberty, Free Soil, and Republican parties. To advance their case against slavery, they needed to appeal to the then-extant public meaning of the terms already in the Constitution. Moreover, their widely-circulated invocations of national citizenship, privileges and immunities, the due process of law, and equal protection made their own contribution to the public meaning in 1866 of the language that became Section One. The more one reads the forgotten writings of these “constitutional abolitionists,” the better their arguments look when compared with the opinions of the antebellum Supreme Court. But even if the Taney Court was right and the abolitionists wrong about the original meaning of the Constitution, the Thirteenth and Fourteenth Amendments were enacted to reverse the Court’s rulings. To appreciate fully the public meaning of these Amendments, therefore, we need to know whence they came. The Fourteenth Amendment is universally presumed to be the outcome of the organized antislavery movement in the United States, yet its modern history continues to be written without reference to the abolitionists. Judges and historians seek an understanding of phrases admittedly designed to secure the ‘‘freedom of the slave race’’ without first examining the tenets of the group which fought longest and hardest to establish that freedom. [T]he fight for liberty in this land was begun by the Radical Abolitionists long before the final battle..They were followed, however, by a class known as Constitutional Abolitionists; equally bold and brave, but more practical. It was the labor of the latter that accomplished glorious results; fought the good battle to a finish and destroyed the slave power. They were among the organizers of the Republican Party.","PeriodicalId":45189,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Legal Analysis","volume":"292 1","pages":"165-263"},"PeriodicalIF":2.2,"publicationDate":"2011-03-20","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"90332075","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 9
The Decision to Award Punitive Damages: An Empirical Study 惩罚性损害赔偿判决的实证研究
IF 2.2 1区 社会学 Q1 LAW Pub Date : 2010-09-21 DOI: 10.1093/JLA/2.2.577
T. Eisenberg, Michael Heise, Nicole L. Waters, M. Wells
Empirical studies have consistently shown that punitive damages are rarely awarded, with rates of about three to five percent of plaintiff trial wins. Using the 2005 data from the Bureau of Justice Statistics Civil Justice Survey, this article shows that knowing in which cases plaintiffs sought punitive damages transforms the picture of punitive damages. Not accounting for whether punitive damages were sought obscures the meaningful punitive damages rate, the rate of awards in cases in which they were sought, by a factor of nearly 10, and obfuscates a more explicable pattern of awards than has been reported. Punitive damages were surprisingly infrequently sought, with requests found in about 10% of tried cases that plaintiffs won. Punitive damages were awarded in about 30% these trials. Awards were most frequent in cases of intentional tort, with a punitive award rate of over 60%. Greater harm corresponded to a greater probability of an award: the size of the compensatory award was significantly associated with whether punitive damages were awarded, with a rate of approximately 60% for cases with compensatory awards of $1 million or more. Regression models correctly classify about 70% or more of the punitive award request outcomes, Judge-jury differences in the rate of awards exist, with judges awarding punitive damages at a higher rate in personal injury cases and juries awarding them at a higher rate in nonpersonal injury cases. These puzzling adjudicator differences may be a consequence of the routing of different cases to judges and juries.
实证研究一致表明,惩罚性赔偿很少被判,原告胜诉的比例约为3%至5%。本文利用2005年司法统计局民事司法调查的数据表明,了解原告在哪些案件中寻求惩罚性赔偿改变了惩罚性赔偿的图景。不考虑是否寻求惩罚性损害赔偿模糊了有意义的惩罚性损害赔偿率,即在寻求惩罚性损害赔偿的案件中获得裁决的比率,几乎是10倍,并且模糊了比报道中更可解释的裁决模式。令人惊讶的是,寻求惩罚性赔偿的情况很少,在原告胜诉的审判案件中,只有10%的案件提出了要求。在这些案件中,大约30%的案件判给了惩罚性赔偿。赔偿在故意侵权案件中最为常见,惩罚性赔偿率超过60%。损害越大,获得赔偿的可能性越大:补偿性赔偿的数额与是否获得惩罚性赔偿显著相关,在补偿性赔偿金额为100万美元或以上的案件中,这一比例约为60%。回归模型正确分类了大约70%或更多的惩罚性赔偿请求结果,法官和陪审团在裁决率上存在差异,法官在人身伤害案件中给予惩罚性赔偿的比例更高,而陪审团在非人身伤害案件中给予惩罚性赔偿的比例更高。这些令人费解的裁决差异可能是不同案件被分配给法官和陪审团的结果。
{"title":"The Decision to Award Punitive Damages: An Empirical Study","authors":"T. Eisenberg, Michael Heise, Nicole L. Waters, M. Wells","doi":"10.1093/JLA/2.2.577","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/JLA/2.2.577","url":null,"abstract":"Empirical studies have consistently shown that punitive damages are rarely awarded, with rates of about three to five percent of plaintiff trial wins. Using the 2005 data from the Bureau of Justice Statistics Civil Justice Survey, this article shows that knowing in which cases plaintiffs sought punitive damages transforms the picture of punitive damages. Not accounting for whether punitive damages were sought obscures the meaningful punitive damages rate, the rate of awards in cases in which they were sought, by a factor of nearly 10, and obfuscates a more explicable pattern of awards than has been reported. Punitive damages were surprisingly infrequently sought, with requests found in about 10% of tried cases that plaintiffs won. Punitive damages were awarded in about 30% these trials. Awards were most frequent in cases of intentional tort, with a punitive award rate of over 60%. Greater harm corresponded to a greater probability of an award: the size of the compensatory award was significantly associated with whether punitive damages were awarded, with a rate of approximately 60% for cases with compensatory awards of $1 million or more. Regression models correctly classify about 70% or more of the punitive award request outcomes, Judge-jury differences in the rate of awards exist, with judges awarding punitive damages at a higher rate in personal injury cases and juries awarding them at a higher rate in nonpersonal injury cases. These puzzling adjudicator differences may be a consequence of the routing of different cases to judges and juries.","PeriodicalId":45189,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Legal Analysis","volume":"3 1","pages":"577-620"},"PeriodicalIF":2.2,"publicationDate":"2010-09-21","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"80283330","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 17
Costly Screens and Patent Examination 昂贵的屏幕和专利审查
IF 2.2 1区 社会学 Q1 LAW Pub Date : 2010-09-21 DOI: 10.1093/JLA/2.2.687
J. Masur
The United States Patent and Trademark Office has acquired a well-deserved reputation for inefficacy and inefficiency. Proposals for reforming the patent office have thus focused on improving the quality of patent review while decreasing its cost. Yet this view overlooks the valuable function performed by the high costs associated with obtaining a patent: these costs serve as an effective screen against low-value patents. Moreover, due to asymmetries in patent values, the costly screen is likely to select against socially harmful patents in disproportionate numbers. Although the patent office is the most prominent forum in which this type of costly screening operates, it is not the only one. In a variety of other contexts, the private costs of navigating an administrative process may complement the process itself in screening out unwanted participants.
美国专利商标局因效率低下和效率低下而获得了当之无愧的声誉。因此,改革专利局的建议集中在提高专利审查质量的同时降低其成本。然而,这种观点忽视了与获得专利相关的高成本所发挥的有价值的作用:这些成本是对抗低价值专利的有效屏障。此外,由于专利价值的不对称,昂贵的屏幕可能会以不成比例的数量选择对社会有害的专利。尽管专利局是进行这种昂贵筛选的最重要的机构,但它并不是唯一的机构。在其他各种情况下,管理流程的私人成本可能会补充流程本身,以筛选不需要的参与者。
{"title":"Costly Screens and Patent Examination","authors":"J. Masur","doi":"10.1093/JLA/2.2.687","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/JLA/2.2.687","url":null,"abstract":"The United States Patent and Trademark Office has acquired a well-deserved reputation for inefficacy and inefficiency. Proposals for reforming the patent office have thus focused on improving the quality of patent review while decreasing its cost. Yet this view overlooks the valuable function performed by the high costs associated with obtaining a patent: these costs serve as an effective screen against low-value patents. Moreover, due to asymmetries in patent values, the costly screen is likely to select against socially harmful patents in disproportionate numbers. Although the patent office is the most prominent forum in which this type of costly screening operates, it is not the only one. In a variety of other contexts, the private costs of navigating an administrative process may complement the process itself in screening out unwanted participants.","PeriodicalId":45189,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Legal Analysis","volume":"16 2 1","pages":"687-734"},"PeriodicalIF":2.2,"publicationDate":"2010-09-21","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"82091777","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 9
Why the Google Books Settlement is Procompetitive 为什么b谷歌图书和解有利于竞争
IF 2.2 1区 社会学 Q1 LAW Pub Date : 2010-05-20 DOI: 10.1093/JLA/2.1.1
E. Elhauge
Although the Google Books Settlement has been criticized as anticompetitive, I conclude that this critique is mistaken. For out-of-copyright books, the settlement procompetitively expands output by clarifying which books are in the public domain and making them digitally available for free. For claimed in-copyright books, the settlement procompetitively expands output by clarifying who holds their rights, making them digitally searchable, allowing individual digital display and sales at competitive prices each rightsholder can set, and creating a new subscription product that provides digital access to a near-universal library at free or competitive rates. For unclaimed in-copyright books, the settlement procompetitively expands output by helping to identify rightsholders and making their books saleable at competitive rates when they cannot be found. The settlement does not raise rival barriers to offering any of these books, but to the contrary lowers them. The output expansion is particularly dramatic for commercially unavailable books, which by definition would otherwise have no new output.
尽管谷歌图书的和解协议被批评为反竞争,但我认为这种批评是错误的。对于版权过期的图书,和解协议明确了哪些图书属于公共领域,并提供免费的数字版本,从而有利于扩大图书的产出。对于声称拥有版权的图书,和解协议通过澄清谁拥有版权,使它们可以进行数字搜索,允许个人数字展示和以每个版权所有者设定的有竞争力的价格销售,以及创建一种新的订阅产品,以免费或有竞争力的价格提供接近全球图书馆的数字访问,从而有利于扩大产出。对于无人认领的有版权的图书,和解协议有助于识别版权所有者,并使他们的图书在找不到时以具有竞争力的价格出售,从而有利于扩大产出。和解协议并没有提高竞争对手提供这些书籍的门槛,相反,反而降低了门槛。对于商业上不可获得的书籍来说,输出的扩大尤其引人注目,否则这些书籍就不会有新的输出。
{"title":"Why the Google Books Settlement is Procompetitive","authors":"E. Elhauge","doi":"10.1093/JLA/2.1.1","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/JLA/2.1.1","url":null,"abstract":"Although the Google Books Settlement has been criticized as anticompetitive, I conclude that this critique is mistaken. For out-of-copyright books, the settlement procompetitively expands output by clarifying which books are in the public domain and making them digitally available for free. For claimed in-copyright books, the settlement procompetitively expands output by clarifying who holds their rights, making them digitally searchable, allowing individual digital display and sales at competitive prices each rightsholder can set, and creating a new subscription product that provides digital access to a near-universal library at free or competitive rates. For unclaimed in-copyright books, the settlement procompetitively expands output by helping to identify rightsholders and making their books saleable at competitive rates when they cannot be found. The settlement does not raise rival barriers to offering any of these books, but to the contrary lowers them. The output expansion is particularly dramatic for commercially unavailable books, which by definition would otherwise have no new output.","PeriodicalId":45189,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Legal Analysis","volume":"1 1","pages":"1-68"},"PeriodicalIF":2.2,"publicationDate":"2010-05-20","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"80421028","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
The Easy Core Case for Judicial Review 司法审查的简单核心案例
IF 2.2 1区 社会学 Q1 LAW Pub Date : 2010-03-31 DOI: 10.1093/JLA/2.1.227
Alon Harel, T. Kahana
This paper defends judicial review on the grounds that judicial review is necessary for protecting “a right to a hearing.” Judicial review is praised by its advocates on the basis of instrumentalist reasons, i.e., because of its desirable contingent consequences such as protecting rights, romoting democracy, maintaining stability, etc. We argue that instrumentalist easons for judicial review are bound to fail and that an adequate defense of udicial review requires justifying judicial review on non-instrumentalist grounds. A non-instrumentalist justification grounds judicial review in essential attributes of he judicial process. In searching for a non-instrumental justification we establish that judicial review is designed to protect the right to a hearing. The right to a hearing consists of hree components: the opportunity to voice a grievance, the opportunity to be rovided with a justification for a decision that impinges (or may have impinged) on one’s rights and, last, the duty to reconsider the initial decision giving rise to the grievance. The right to a hearing is valued independently of the merit of the decisions generated by the judicial process. We also argue that the recent proposals to reinforce popular or democratic participation in shaping the Constitution are wrong because they are detrimental to the right to a hearing.
本文以司法审查对于保护“听证权”是必要的为理由为司法审查辩护。司法审查的提倡者基于工具主义的理由而称赞它,即因为它具有保护权利、促进民主、维护稳定等理想的偶然结果。我们认为,司法审查的工具主义理由注定会失败,而司法审查的充分辩护需要以非工具主义理由为司法审查辩护。非工具主义的正当性为司法审查的本质属性提供了依据。在寻找非工具性理由的过程中,我们确定司法审查的目的是保护听证的权利。听证权由三部分组成:表达不满的机会,为侵犯(或可能已经侵犯)个人权利的决定提供理由的机会,最后,重新考虑引起不满的最初决定的义务。听审权的价值与司法程序所作出的决定的优劣无关。我们还认为,最近提出的加强民众或民主参与宪法制定的建议是错误的,因为它们不利于听证的权利。
{"title":"The Easy Core Case for Judicial Review","authors":"Alon Harel, T. Kahana","doi":"10.1093/JLA/2.1.227","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1093/JLA/2.1.227","url":null,"abstract":"This paper defends judicial review on the grounds that judicial review is necessary for protecting “a right to a hearing.” Judicial review is praised by its advocates on the basis of instrumentalist reasons, i.e., because of its desirable contingent consequences such as protecting rights, romoting democracy, maintaining stability, etc. We argue that instrumentalist easons for judicial review are bound to fail and that an adequate defense of udicial review requires justifying judicial review on non-instrumentalist grounds. A non-instrumentalist justification grounds judicial review in essential attributes of he judicial process. In searching for a non-instrumental justification we establish that judicial review is designed to protect the right to a hearing. The right to a hearing consists of hree components: the opportunity to voice a grievance, the opportunity to be rovided with a justification for a decision that impinges (or may have impinged) on one’s rights and, last, the duty to reconsider the initial decision giving rise to the grievance. The right to a hearing is valued independently of the merit of the decisions generated by the judicial process. We also argue that the recent proposals to reinforce popular or democratic participation in shaping the Constitution are wrong because they are detrimental to the right to a hearing.","PeriodicalId":45189,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Legal Analysis","volume":"1310 1","pages":"227-256"},"PeriodicalIF":2.2,"publicationDate":"2010-03-31","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"86488985","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 25
期刊
Journal of Legal Analysis
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1