首页 > 最新文献

Journal of Global History最新文献

英文 中文
JGH volume 16 issue 2 Cover and Back matter JGH第16卷第2期封面和封底
IF 1.9 1区 历史学 Q1 HISTORY Pub Date : 2021-07-01 DOI: 10.1017/s174002282100022x
{"title":"JGH volume 16 issue 2 Cover and Back matter","authors":"","doi":"10.1017/s174002282100022x","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1017/s174002282100022x","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":46192,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Global History","volume":"16 1","pages":"b1 - b6"},"PeriodicalIF":1.9,"publicationDate":"2021-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1017/s174002282100022x","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"46234541","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"历史学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Past growths: pre-modern and modern 过去的增长:前现代和现代
IF 1.9 1区 历史学 Q1 HISTORY Pub Date : 2021-07-01 DOI: 10.1017/S1740022820000418
P. Malanima
The article by Jack Goldstone, Dating the Great Divergence, has the merit of discussing both the wide panorama of recent global history and the conclusions stemming from specific northEuropean long-term series of GDP.1 The article’s main target is the deeply rooted idea that Modern Growth was the continuation of previous trends of GDP growth. Goldstone’s opinion is that the rise of the West, in the frame of global history, occurred only from the late-eighteenth century or the beginning of the Nineteenth, not earlier. At the time, a true divergence among World economies did not exist. Modern Growth is different from previous periods of expansion not merely in the degree but also in the nature. Pre-modern examples of growth were episodic and not sustained; they represented temporary ‘efflorescences’ rather than long upward rises.2 It is apparent that, in such an approach to growth, problems of definition are crucial. Since the modern rise is deemed to be different from past ‘efflorescences’ of sporadic growth, what is, according to Goldstone, the primary feature of “modern” in comparison with ‘pre-modern’? The definition of Modern Growth adopted by Goldstone is the classical one put forward in economics and historical research primarily by Simon Kuznets:3 it is characterised both by strong increases in population and production; growth in production is, however, higher than in population. The result is then a rise in per capita product or intensive4 growth. This rise is sustained for long periods of time and primarily derives from modern technological growth. This definition of Modern Growth, rapidly recalled by Goldstone in his present article, had been more widely discussed in his previous article on efflorescences and economic growth in World history.5 In the following, I will deal with the differences between modern and pre-modern growth and later with the concept of technological progress in relation to the rise of the West. I will focus primarily on Europe and the Mediterranean and will include extra-European macroareas at the end.
杰克·戈德斯通(Jack Goldstone)的《追溯大分歧》(Dating The Great Divergence)一文的优点在于,既讨论了近代全球历史的全景,也讨论了源自特定北欧长期GDP序列的结论。1这篇文章的主要目标是根深蒂固的观点,即现代增长是GDP增长先前趋势的延续。戈德斯通的观点是,在全球历史的框架内,西方的崛起只发生在18世纪末或19世纪初,而不是更早。当时,世界经济体之间并不存在真正的分歧。现代增长与以往的扩张时期不同,不仅在程度上,而且在性质上。前现代增长的例子是偶发的,而不是持续的;它们代表了暂时的“风化”,而不是长期的上升。2很明显,在这种增长方式中,定义问题至关重要。由于现代的崛起被认为与过去零星增长的“风化”不同,戈德斯通认为,与“前现代”相比,“现代”的主要特征是什么?戈德斯通对现代增长的定义是西蒙·库兹涅茨在经济学和历史研究中提出的经典定义:3现代增长的特点是人口和生产的强劲增长;然而,生产的增长高于人口的增长。其结果是人均生产总值的增长或密集增长。这种增长持续了很长一段时间,主要源于现代技术的增长。戈德斯通在他的这篇文章中迅速回忆起了对现代增长的定义,在他上一篇关于世界历史上的繁荣与经济增长的文章中,他对这一定义进行了更广泛的讨论。5在下文中,我将讨论现代增长与前现代增长之间的差异,以及后来与西方崛起相关的技术进步概念。我将主要关注欧洲和地中海,最后将包括欧洲以外的宏观地区。
{"title":"Past growths: pre-modern and modern","authors":"P. Malanima","doi":"10.1017/S1740022820000418","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1017/S1740022820000418","url":null,"abstract":"The article by Jack Goldstone, Dating the Great Divergence, has the merit of discussing both the wide panorama of recent global history and the conclusions stemming from specific northEuropean long-term series of GDP.1 The article’s main target is the deeply rooted idea that Modern Growth was the continuation of previous trends of GDP growth. Goldstone’s opinion is that the rise of the West, in the frame of global history, occurred only from the late-eighteenth century or the beginning of the Nineteenth, not earlier. At the time, a true divergence among World economies did not exist. Modern Growth is different from previous periods of expansion not merely in the degree but also in the nature. Pre-modern examples of growth were episodic and not sustained; they represented temporary ‘efflorescences’ rather than long upward rises.2 It is apparent that, in such an approach to growth, problems of definition are crucial. Since the modern rise is deemed to be different from past ‘efflorescences’ of sporadic growth, what is, according to Goldstone, the primary feature of “modern” in comparison with ‘pre-modern’? The definition of Modern Growth adopted by Goldstone is the classical one put forward in economics and historical research primarily by Simon Kuznets:3 it is characterised both by strong increases in population and production; growth in production is, however, higher than in population. The result is then a rise in per capita product or intensive4 growth. This rise is sustained for long periods of time and primarily derives from modern technological growth. This definition of Modern Growth, rapidly recalled by Goldstone in his present article, had been more widely discussed in his previous article on efflorescences and economic growth in World history.5 In the following, I will deal with the differences between modern and pre-modern growth and later with the concept of technological progress in relation to the rise of the West. I will focus primarily on Europe and the Mediterranean and will include extra-European macroareas at the end.","PeriodicalId":46192,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Global History","volume":"16 1","pages":"301 - 308"},"PeriodicalIF":1.9,"publicationDate":"2021-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1017/S1740022820000418","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"47398762","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"历史学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Historical national accounting and dating the Great Divergence 历史国民核算与大分流断代
IF 1.9 1区 历史学 Q1 HISTORY Pub Date : 2021-07-01 DOI: 10.1017/S1740022820000388
S. Broadberry
Abstract By offering a particular interpretation of the new evidence on historical national accounting, Goldstone argues for a return to the Pomeranz (2000) version of the Great Divergence, beginning only after 1800. However, he fails to distinguish between two very different patterns of pre-industrial growth: (1) alternating episodes of growing and shrinking without any long-term trend in per capita income and (2) episodes of growing interspersed by per capita incomes remaining on a plateau, so that per capita GDP trends upwards over the long run. The latter dynamic pattern occurred in Britain and Holland from the mid-fourteenth century, so that Northwest Europe first edged ahead of the Yangzi delta region of China in the eighteenth century.
通过对历史国民核算新证据的特殊解释,戈德斯通主张回到1800年后才开始的彭慕兰(2000)版本的大分歧。然而,他未能区分工业化前两种截然不同的增长模式:(1)在人均收入没有任何长期趋势的情况下,增长和萎缩交替出现;(2)在人均收入保持稳定的情况下,增长穿插出现,因此人均GDP在长期内呈上升趋势。后一种动态模式从14世纪中期开始出现在英国和荷兰,因此西北欧在18世纪首先领先于中国的长江三角洲地区。
{"title":"Historical national accounting and dating the Great Divergence","authors":"S. Broadberry","doi":"10.1017/S1740022820000388","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1017/S1740022820000388","url":null,"abstract":"Abstract By offering a particular interpretation of the new evidence on historical national accounting, Goldstone argues for a return to the Pomeranz (2000) version of the Great Divergence, beginning only after 1800. However, he fails to distinguish between two very different patterns of pre-industrial growth: (1) alternating episodes of growing and shrinking without any long-term trend in per capita income and (2) episodes of growing interspersed by per capita incomes remaining on a plateau, so that per capita GDP trends upwards over the long run. The latter dynamic pattern occurred in Britain and Holland from the mid-fourteenth century, so that Northwest Europe first edged ahead of the Yangzi delta region of China in the eighteenth century.","PeriodicalId":46192,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Global History","volume":"16 1","pages":"286 - 293"},"PeriodicalIF":1.9,"publicationDate":"2021-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1017/S1740022820000388","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"47004777","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"历史学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
JGH volume 16 issue 2 Cover and Front matter JGH第16卷第2期封面和封面
IF 1.9 1区 历史学 Q1 HISTORY Pub Date : 2021-07-01 DOI: 10.1017/s1740022821000218
{"title":"JGH volume 16 issue 2 Cover and Front matter","authors":"","doi":"10.1017/s1740022821000218","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1017/s1740022821000218","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":46192,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Global History","volume":"16 1","pages":"f1 - f2"},"PeriodicalIF":1.9,"publicationDate":"2021-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1017/s1740022821000218","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"42335377","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"历史学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Why understanding the timing of divergence matters 为什么理解分化的时机很重要
IF 1.9 1区 历史学 Q1 HISTORY Pub Date : 2021-07-01 DOI: 10.1017/S174002282000042X
J. Goldstone
What is divergence and why does it matter? The question motivating all of us is to understand what led up to modern economic growth. Malanima is correct that I follow Kuznets and describe this as rapid and sustained growth in both population and output per head, but I would now add a third qualifier, to levels beyond the pre-industrial peak. All three qualifiers are necessary because history has many examples of sustained growth in population and output per head: as van Zanden and Bolt show in their comment, both Britain and Holland had positive trend growth in real GDP/capita all the way from the late Middle Ages to the eighteenth century. It seems clear that classical Greece and Rome each had at least three centuries of sustained growth in population and GDP/cap as well, and China likely did also before achieving the heights reached in the Northern Song.1 But all of these sustained growth episodes were very slow, as van Zanden and Bolt show in their regressions for Holland and England, where real income growth averaged not more than 0.2% per year. There were shorter periods of much more rapid growth, which I have labelled ‘efflorescences.’ In these cases, a combination of technical innovations in farming or transport or other production allows higher output that supports urbanisation and more extensive trade, which in turn leads to greater specialisation, greater monetary circulation and profits that feed further investment to boost productivity, in a virtuous cycle.2 In post-classical Europe, the High Middle Ages in the north, Renaissance Italy and Golden Age Holland are examples; outside Europe, the peaks of the Song and Qing dynasties in China, the early Baghdad Caliphate and perhaps the Mughal Empire under Akbar are likely others. But over time, population continues to grow, trade patterns change, climate shifts, administrative inefficiency, wars and diseases take their toll and after a century or less, rapid growth in GDP/cap comes to an end. Finally, past episodes of rapid and/or sustained growth, as beautifully shown by Broadberry’s Figure 5 above, showing GDP/cap in the leading regions of China and Europe, often approached but never reached beyond an apparent limit in GDP/cap of about $1800.3 Instead, from classical times up to 1750, as Malanima makes clear, GDP/cap fluctuated in a relatively narrow band under
什么是散度,为什么它很重要?激励我们所有人的问题是理解是什么导致了现代经济增长。Malanima是正确的,我遵循库兹涅茨将其描述为人口和人均产出的快速和持续增长,但我现在要添加第三个限定词,即超过工业化前峰值的水平。这三个限定条件都是必要的,因为历史上有许多人口和人均产出持续增长的例子:正如范·赞登和博尔特在他们的评论中所表明的那样,从中世纪晚期到18世纪,英国和荷兰的实际人均GDP都有正趋势增长。很明显,古典希腊和罗马在人口和GDP/cap方面都有至少三个世纪的持续增长,中国在达到北宋的高度之前也可能这样做。但所有这些持续增长的时期都非常缓慢,正如范·赞登和博尔特在他们对荷兰和英国的回归中所显示的那样,这两个国家的实际收入增长平均每年不超过0.2%。有一段较短的时期生长得更快,我称之为“花期”。“在这些情况下,农业、运输或其他生产领域的技术创新结合起来,可以提高产出,从而支持城市化和更广泛的贸易,这反过来又会带来更大的专业化、更大的货币流通和利润,从而促进进一步的投资,从而提高生产率,形成良性循环。在后古典时代的欧洲,北部的中世纪盛期、文艺复兴时期的意大利和黄金时代的荷兰都是例子;在欧洲以外,中国宋朝和清朝的鼎盛时期,早期的巴格达哈里发,也许还有阿克巴领导下的莫卧儿帝国,都是可能的例子。但随着时间的推移,人口继续增长,贸易模式改变,气候变化,行政效率低下,战争和疾病造成了损失,一个世纪或更短的时间后,GDP/cap的快速增长结束了。最后,过去快速和/或持续增长的时期,如Broadberry上面的图5所示,显示了中国和欧洲主要地区的GDP/上限,经常接近但从未超过GDP/上限的明显限制,约为1800.3美元。相反,从古典时期到1750年,Malanima明确表示,GDP/上限在相对狭窄的范围内波动
{"title":"Why understanding the timing of divergence matters","authors":"J. Goldstone","doi":"10.1017/S174002282000042X","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1017/S174002282000042X","url":null,"abstract":"What is divergence and why does it matter? The question motivating all of us is to understand what led up to modern economic growth. Malanima is correct that I follow Kuznets and describe this as rapid and sustained growth in both population and output per head, but I would now add a third qualifier, to levels beyond the pre-industrial peak. All three qualifiers are necessary because history has many examples of sustained growth in population and output per head: as van Zanden and Bolt show in their comment, both Britain and Holland had positive trend growth in real GDP/capita all the way from the late Middle Ages to the eighteenth century. It seems clear that classical Greece and Rome each had at least three centuries of sustained growth in population and GDP/cap as well, and China likely did also before achieving the heights reached in the Northern Song.1 But all of these sustained growth episodes were very slow, as van Zanden and Bolt show in their regressions for Holland and England, where real income growth averaged not more than 0.2% per year. There were shorter periods of much more rapid growth, which I have labelled ‘efflorescences.’ In these cases, a combination of technical innovations in farming or transport or other production allows higher output that supports urbanisation and more extensive trade, which in turn leads to greater specialisation, greater monetary circulation and profits that feed further investment to boost productivity, in a virtuous cycle.2 In post-classical Europe, the High Middle Ages in the north, Renaissance Italy and Golden Age Holland are examples; outside Europe, the peaks of the Song and Qing dynasties in China, the early Baghdad Caliphate and perhaps the Mughal Empire under Akbar are likely others. But over time, population continues to grow, trade patterns change, climate shifts, administrative inefficiency, wars and diseases take their toll and after a century or less, rapid growth in GDP/cap comes to an end. Finally, past episodes of rapid and/or sustained growth, as beautifully shown by Broadberry’s Figure 5 above, showing GDP/cap in the leading regions of China and Europe, often approached but never reached beyond an apparent limit in GDP/cap of about $1800.3 Instead, from classical times up to 1750, as Malanima makes clear, GDP/cap fluctuated in a relatively narrow band under","PeriodicalId":46192,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Global History","volume":"16 1","pages":"309 - 314"},"PeriodicalIF":1.9,"publicationDate":"2021-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"43057951","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"历史学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
A great convergence: The American frontier and the origins of Japanese migration to Brazil 一个伟大的交汇点:美国边境和日本移民巴西的起源
IF 1.9 1区 历史学 Q1 HISTORY Pub Date : 2021-06-28 DOI: 10.1017/S1740022821000231
S. Lu
Abstract This article explains how the US westward expansion influenced and stimulated Japanese migration to Brazil. Emerging in the nineteenth century as expanding powers in East Asia and Latin America, respectively, both Meiji Japan and post-independence Brazil looked to the US westward expansion as a central reference for their own processes of settler colonialism. The convergence of Japan and Brazil in their imitation of US settler colonialism eventually brought the two sides together at the turn of the twentieth century to negotiate for the start of Japanese migration to Brazil. This article challenges the current understanding of Japanese migration to Brazil, conventionally regarded as a topic of Latin American ethnic studies, by placing it in the context of settler colonialism in both Japanese and Brazilian histories. The study also explores the shared experiences of East Asia and Latin America as they felt the global impact of the American westward expansion.
摘要本文阐述了美国向西扩张对日本移民巴西的影响和刺激。19世纪,作为东亚和拉丁美洲的扩张大国,明治日本和独立后的巴西都将美国的向西扩张视为其定居者殖民主义进程的中心参考。日本和巴西模仿美国定居者殖民主义的趋同最终使双方在20世纪之交走到一起,就日本人开始移民巴西进行谈判。这篇文章将日本移民巴西置于日本和巴西历史上的定居者殖民主义背景下,挑战了目前对日本移民巴西的理解。该研究还探讨了东亚和拉丁美洲在感受到美国向西扩张的全球影响时的共同经历。
{"title":"A great convergence: The American frontier and the origins of Japanese migration to Brazil","authors":"S. Lu","doi":"10.1017/S1740022821000231","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1017/S1740022821000231","url":null,"abstract":"Abstract This article explains how the US westward expansion influenced and stimulated Japanese migration to Brazil. Emerging in the nineteenth century as expanding powers in East Asia and Latin America, respectively, both Meiji Japan and post-independence Brazil looked to the US westward expansion as a central reference for their own processes of settler colonialism. The convergence of Japan and Brazil in their imitation of US settler colonialism eventually brought the two sides together at the turn of the twentieth century to negotiate for the start of Japanese migration to Brazil. This article challenges the current understanding of Japanese migration to Brazil, conventionally regarded as a topic of Latin American ethnic studies, by placing it in the context of settler colonialism in both Japanese and Brazilian histories. The study also explores the shared experiences of East Asia and Latin America as they felt the global impact of the American westward expansion.","PeriodicalId":46192,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Global History","volume":"203 1","pages":"109 - 127"},"PeriodicalIF":1.9,"publicationDate":"2021-06-28","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1017/S1740022821000231","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"41258921","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"历史学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Dating the Great Divergence 大分化的年代
IF 1.9 1区 历史学 Q1 HISTORY Pub Date : 2021-06-23 DOI: 10.1017/S1740022820000406
J. Goldstone
Abstract New data on Dutch and British GDP/capita show that at no time prior to 1750, perhaps not before 1800, did the leading countries of northwestern Europe enjoy sustained strong growth in GDP/capita. Such growth in income per head as did occur was highly episodic, concentrated in a few decades and then followed by long periods of stagnation of income per head. Moreover, at no time before 1800 did the leading economies of northwestern Europe reach levels of income per capita much different from peak levels achieved hundreds of years earlier in the most developed regions of Italy and China. When the Industrial Revolution began in Britain, it was not preceded by patterns of pre-modern income growth that were in any way remarkable, neither by sustained prior growth in real incomes nor exceptional levels of income per head. The Great Divergence, seen as the onset of sustained increases in income per head despite strong population growth, and achievement of incomes beyond pre-modern peaks, was a late occurrence, arising only from 1800.
关于荷兰和英国人均GDP的最新数据显示,在1750年之前,也许在1800年之前,西北欧的主要国家从未享受过人均GDP的持续强劲增长。人均收入的这种增长确实是极不稳定的,集中在几十年内,随后是人均收入的长期停滞。此外,在1800年之前,西北欧主要经济体的人均收入水平与意大利和中国等最发达地区几百年前达到的峰值水平没有太大差别。当工业革命在英国开始时,它之前并没有出现任何显著的前现代收入增长模式,既没有实际收入的持续增长,也没有人均收入的异常水平。“大分化”被视为在人口强劲增长的情况下,人均收入持续增长的开端,以及收入超过前现代时期峰值的成就,这一现象发生得很晚,仅从1800年开始出现。
{"title":"Dating the Great Divergence","authors":"J. Goldstone","doi":"10.1017/S1740022820000406","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1017/S1740022820000406","url":null,"abstract":"Abstract New data on Dutch and British GDP/capita show that at no time prior to 1750, perhaps not before 1800, did the leading countries of northwestern Europe enjoy sustained strong growth in GDP/capita. Such growth in income per head as did occur was highly episodic, concentrated in a few decades and then followed by long periods of stagnation of income per head. Moreover, at no time before 1800 did the leading economies of northwestern Europe reach levels of income per capita much different from peak levels achieved hundreds of years earlier in the most developed regions of Italy and China. When the Industrial Revolution began in Britain, it was not preceded by patterns of pre-modern income growth that were in any way remarkable, neither by sustained prior growth in real incomes nor exceptional levels of income per head. The Great Divergence, seen as the onset of sustained increases in income per head despite strong population growth, and achievement of incomes beyond pre-modern peaks, was a late occurrence, arising only from 1800.","PeriodicalId":46192,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Global History","volume":"16 1","pages":"266 - 285"},"PeriodicalIF":1.9,"publicationDate":"2021-06-23","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1017/S1740022820000406","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"46712321","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"历史学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
Comments on time, space and method for the study of commodity frontiers and the transformation of the global countryside 商品前沿与全球农村转型研究的时间、空间与方法评析
IF 1.9 1区 历史学 Q1 HISTORY Pub Date : 2021-06-10 DOI: 10.1017/S1740022820000443
Ruth Mostern
[...]they offer a research agenda about the incorporation of land, labour and resources into the capitalist world economy. According to Raymond Williams’ classic work of Marxist literary theory, the ideological work that the concept of the countryside performs is simply to be a discursive counterpoint to the city. [...]I emphasise the urgency of centring the brutal history of conquest and the resistance of colonised peoples. [...]I explain how an approach focused on frontiers as locales on the geospatial earth would bring to life the digital research methods that the authors propound in their conclusion.
[…]他们提出了一项关于将土地、劳动力和资源纳入资本主义世界经济的研究议程。根据威廉姆斯的马克思主义文艺理论经典著作,乡村概念所进行的意识形态工作,只是对城市的一种话语对位。[…]我强调了以殖民地人民的残酷征服和抵抗历史为中心的紧迫性。[…]我解释了一种专注于地理空间地球上的前沿地区的方法将如何使作者在结论中提出的数字研究方法栩栩如生。
{"title":"Comments on time, space and method for the study of commodity frontiers and the transformation of the global countryside","authors":"Ruth Mostern","doi":"10.1017/S1740022820000443","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1017/S1740022820000443","url":null,"abstract":"[...]they offer a research agenda about the incorporation of land, labour and resources into the capitalist world economy. According to Raymond Williams’ classic work of Marxist literary theory, the ideological work that the concept of the countryside performs is simply to be a discursive counterpoint to the city. [...]I emphasise the urgency of centring the brutal history of conquest and the resistance of colonised peoples. [...]I explain how an approach focused on frontiers as locales on the geospatial earth would bring to life the digital research methods that the authors propound in their conclusion.","PeriodicalId":46192,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Global History","volume":"16 1","pages":"456 - 461"},"PeriodicalIF":1.9,"publicationDate":"2021-06-10","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1017/S1740022820000443","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"41360330","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"历史学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Commodity frontiers and global histories: the tasks ahead 商品前沿和全球历史:未来的任务
IF 1.9 1区 历史学 Q1 HISTORY Pub Date : 2021-06-10 DOI: 10.1017/S1740022820000431
S. Beckert, U. Bosma, Mindi Schneider, E. Vanhaute
Given the alarming pace of climate change, global environmental destruction, and associated social dislocations and inequalities, a global history that also speaks to the present is more important now than ever. We started our article with a pointed argument that ‘[t]he history of the making of the modern world is a history of the expansion of commodity frontiers, a historical conundrum so spatially, socially, and structurally all-encompassing that it still awaits its persuasive analysis’. This deep historical perspective, we argued, is crucial to understanding how we arrived at our current socioecological predicament. What is more, we proposed that transdisciplinary research among historians and social, ecological, and computational scientists is essential to engage such questions. To that end, we have developed our research agenda around an analytical framework that lets us trace the long history and present of capitalism. We look at the countryside through the lens of the history of commodity frontiers, using commodity regimes as an analytical framework to make sense of the vast amount of data we hope to uncover. The commodity frontier – the empirical core of our investigations – is not simply a place. It is a relational concept that grasps the flows of materials and energy between nature and society, between different societies and within them. These flows connect regions of extraction with the sites of production that organize capitalist modernity on a world scale. The commodity frontier stands for an inductive historical approach that starts from the far edges of global expansion. It includes agents other than the global hegemonic powers, spaces other than the metropole and relations that encompass more than the economic. Indeed, as we emphasized in our paper, ‘[m]uch of the writing on the history of capitalism privileges the perspective from the city and industry to the detriment of processes in the household, agriculture, and the countryside where the vast majority of humanity has lived until very recently and where many of the revolutions of capitalism have taken place’. Urban merchants, state bureaucrats, soldiers and lawmakers, of course, helped produce these commodity frontiers as much as commodity frontiers co-created them – yet the distinguishing feature of our work is that it thinks of these processes from the fringes. We welcome Maxine Berg’s observation that ‘histories of natural resources and of the countryside and its peoples have not been sufficiently addressed by global historians’. This lacuna stands in contrast to a growing number of scholars from other disciplines who have come to see ‘commodity frontiers’ as a promising approach to historical processes. As Ronald Findlay and Kevin O’Rourke conclude, such an approach is both exciting and necessary to avoid mono-causal explanations of historical change. The research agenda we propose, as Ruth Mostern observes, attempts to bridge the gulf between the conceptual focus of soci
考虑到气候变化、全球环境破坏以及相关的社会混乱和不平等的惊人速度,一部反映当下的全球历史比以往任何时候都更加重要。我们在文章的开头提出了一个尖锐的论点:“现代世界的形成史是一部商品边界扩张的历史,这是一个在空间、社会和结构上无所不有的历史难题,它仍在等待有说服力的分析。”我们认为,这种深刻的历史视角对于理解我们是如何陷入当前的社会生态困境至关重要。更重要的是,我们建议历史学家和社会、生态和计算科学家之间的跨学科研究对于解决这些问题至关重要。为此,我们围绕一个分析框架制定了我们的研究议程,使我们能够追溯资本主义的悠久历史和现状。我们通过商品边界的历史镜头来观察农村,使用商品制度作为分析框架来理解我们希望揭示的大量数据。商品前沿——我们研究的经验核心——不仅仅是一个地方。它是一个关系概念,掌握了自然与社会之间、不同社会之间以及社会内部的物质和能量流动。这些流动将抽取地区与在世界范围内组织资本主义现代性的生产地点联系起来。商品前沿代表了一种从全球扩张的边缘出发的归纳历史方法。它包括全球霸权国家以外的代理人,大都市以外的空间,以及超越经济范围的关系。事实上,正如我们在论文中强调的那样,“许多关于资本主义历史的著作都从城市和工业的角度出发,而忽略了家庭、农业和农村的过程,而直到最近,绝大多数人类都生活在农村,也发生了许多资本主义革命。”当然,城市商人、国家官僚、士兵和立法者帮助创造了这些商品边界,就像商品边界共同创造了它们一样——然而,我们工作的显著特点是,它从边缘思考这些过程。我们欢迎玛克辛·伯格(Maxine Berg)的观察,即“全球历史学家对自然资源、农村及其人民的历史没有进行充分的研究”。这一空白与越来越多其他学科的学者形成鲜明对比,他们将“商品边界”视为研究历史进程的一种有前途的方法。正如Ronald Findlay和Kevin O 'Rourke总结的那样,这种方法既令人兴奋,又必要,以避免对历史变化的单一因果解释。正如露丝·莫斯顿(Ruth Mostern)所观察到的,我们提出的研究议程试图弥合社会科学概念焦点之间的鸿沟
{"title":"Commodity frontiers and global histories: the tasks ahead","authors":"S. Beckert, U. Bosma, Mindi Schneider, E. Vanhaute","doi":"10.1017/S1740022820000431","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1017/S1740022820000431","url":null,"abstract":"Given the alarming pace of climate change, global environmental destruction, and associated social dislocations and inequalities, a global history that also speaks to the present is more important now than ever. We started our article with a pointed argument that ‘[t]he history of the making of the modern world is a history of the expansion of commodity frontiers, a historical conundrum so spatially, socially, and structurally all-encompassing that it still awaits its persuasive analysis’. This deep historical perspective, we argued, is crucial to understanding how we arrived at our current socioecological predicament. What is more, we proposed that transdisciplinary research among historians and social, ecological, and computational scientists is essential to engage such questions. To that end, we have developed our research agenda around an analytical framework that lets us trace the long history and present of capitalism. We look at the countryside through the lens of the history of commodity frontiers, using commodity regimes as an analytical framework to make sense of the vast amount of data we hope to uncover. The commodity frontier – the empirical core of our investigations – is not simply a place. It is a relational concept that grasps the flows of materials and energy between nature and society, between different societies and within them. These flows connect regions of extraction with the sites of production that organize capitalist modernity on a world scale. The commodity frontier stands for an inductive historical approach that starts from the far edges of global expansion. It includes agents other than the global hegemonic powers, spaces other than the metropole and relations that encompass more than the economic. Indeed, as we emphasized in our paper, ‘[m]uch of the writing on the history of capitalism privileges the perspective from the city and industry to the detriment of processes in the household, agriculture, and the countryside where the vast majority of humanity has lived until very recently and where many of the revolutions of capitalism have taken place’. Urban merchants, state bureaucrats, soldiers and lawmakers, of course, helped produce these commodity frontiers as much as commodity frontiers co-created them – yet the distinguishing feature of our work is that it thinks of these processes from the fringes. We welcome Maxine Berg’s observation that ‘histories of natural resources and of the countryside and its peoples have not been sufficiently addressed by global historians’. This lacuna stands in contrast to a growing number of scholars from other disciplines who have come to see ‘commodity frontiers’ as a promising approach to historical processes. As Ronald Findlay and Kevin O’Rourke conclude, such an approach is both exciting and necessary to avoid mono-causal explanations of historical change. The research agenda we propose, as Ruth Mostern observes, attempts to bridge the gulf between the conceptual focus of soci","PeriodicalId":46192,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Global History","volume":"16 1","pages":"466 - 469"},"PeriodicalIF":1.9,"publicationDate":"2021-06-10","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1017/S1740022820000431","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"43222699","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"历史学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Commodity frontiers: concepts and history 商品前沿:概念与历史
IF 1.9 1区 历史学 Q1 HISTORY Pub Date : 2021-06-10 DOI: 10.1017/S1740022821000036
M. Berg
‘COMMODITY FRONTIERS AND THE TRANSFORMATION OF THE GLOBAL COUNTRYSIDE: A RESEARCH AGENDA’ provides an opportunity to connect recent topics in global history, environmental history and the new history of capitalism. I will first summarize the key points of the paper and the way it engages in particular with global economic history. I go on to discuss key concepts of commodity frontiers and frontier zones, and set out and critically assess the historical phases delineated in the article. I welcome the position of the authors on aspects of the research strategy they offer to global historians; histories of natural resources and of the countryside and its peoples have not been sufficiently addressed by global historians. I argue, however, that the large-scale theory of commodity frontiers conflates too many concepts, leaving confusion rather than clarity of analysis. There is a great need for new histories of the natural world, rural and forest communities, of common lands and agriculture and of natural resources. Commodity frontiers, as defined and used in this article, unless carefully refined, cannot, I fear, open the deep historical analysis and comparative and connective history I identify with global history. Commodity frontiers as a concept has been defined as the processes and sites of the incorporation of resources into the expanding capitalist world economy. To quote the authors
“商品前沿与全球国家的转型:一个研究机构”提供了一个机会,将全球历史、环境史和资本主义新历史的最新主题联系起来。我将首先总结论文的要点,以及它与全球经济史的联系方式。我接着讨论了商品边界和边疆区的关键概念,并阐述和批判性地评估了文章中描绘的历史阶段。我欢迎作者对他们向全球历史学家提供的研究策略的各个方面的立场;自然资源和乡村及其人民的历史没有得到全球历史学家的充分论述。然而,我认为,大规模的商品边界理论混淆了太多的概念,留下了混乱,而不是清晰的分析。非常需要关于自然世界、农村和森林社区、共同土地和农业以及自然资源的新历史。本文中定义和使用的商品边界,除非经过仔细提炼,否则我担心无法打开我与全球历史认同的深层历史分析以及比较和联系历史。商品边界作为一个概念被定义为将资源纳入不断扩张的资本主义世界经济的过程和地点。引用作者的话
{"title":"Commodity frontiers: concepts and history","authors":"M. Berg","doi":"10.1017/S1740022821000036","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1017/S1740022821000036","url":null,"abstract":"‘COMMODITY FRONTIERS AND THE TRANSFORMATION OF THE GLOBAL COUNTRYSIDE: A RESEARCH AGENDA’ provides an opportunity to connect recent topics in global history, environmental history and the new history of capitalism. I will first summarize the key points of the paper and the way it engages in particular with global economic history. I go on to discuss key concepts of commodity frontiers and frontier zones, and set out and critically assess the historical phases delineated in the article. I welcome the position of the authors on aspects of the research strategy they offer to global historians; histories of natural resources and of the countryside and its peoples have not been sufficiently addressed by global historians. I argue, however, that the large-scale theory of commodity frontiers conflates too many concepts, leaving confusion rather than clarity of analysis. There is a great need for new histories of the natural world, rural and forest communities, of common lands and agriculture and of natural resources. Commodity frontiers, as defined and used in this article, unless carefully refined, cannot, I fear, open the deep historical analysis and comparative and connective history I identify with global history. Commodity frontiers as a concept has been defined as the processes and sites of the incorporation of resources into the expanding capitalist world economy. To quote the authors","PeriodicalId":46192,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Global History","volume":"16 1","pages":"451 - 455"},"PeriodicalIF":1.9,"publicationDate":"2021-06-10","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1017/S1740022821000036","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"43653014","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"历史学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Journal of Global History
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1