首页 > 最新文献

Quarterly Journal of Political Science最新文献

英文 中文
Is Divided Government a Cause of Legislative Delay 政府分裂是立法延迟的原因吗
IF 1.7 3区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2018-05-23 DOI: 10.1561/100.00017041
Patricia A. Kirkland, J. Phillips
Despite the compelling theoretical prediction that divided government decreases legislative performance, the empirical literature has struggled to identify a causal effect. We suspect that a combination of methodological challenges and data limitations are to blame. Here, we revisit this empirical relationship. Rather than relying on traditional measures of legislative productivity, however, we consider whether divided government affects the ability of lawmakers to meet critical deadlines — specifically, the ability of state lawmakers to adopt an on-time budget (as mandated by state law). By focusing on delay instead of productivity we avoid measurement problems, particularly the challenges inherent in measuring the supply of and demand for legislation. To assess the causal effect of divided government, we develop and implement a regression discontinuity design (RDD) that accounts for the multiple elections that produce unified or divided government in separation of powers systems. Our RDD approach yields compelling evidence that divided government is a cause of delay. We also evaluate and find support for a new hypothesis that divided government is more likely to lead to delay when the personal and political costs that stalemate imposes on politicians are low.
尽管有令人信服的理论预测,即政府分裂会降低立法绩效,但实证文献一直难以确定因果效应。我们怀疑,方法上的挑战和数据限制是罪魁祸首。在这里,我们重新审视这种经验关系。然而,我们不依赖于传统的立法生产力衡量标准,而是考虑分裂的政府是否会影响立法者在关键截止日期前完成任务的能力,特别是州立法者按时通过预算(根据州法律的规定)的能力。通过关注延迟而不是生产力,我们避免了衡量问题,特别是衡量立法供求的固有挑战。为了评估分裂政府的因果效应,我们开发并实施了回归不连续设计(RDD),该设计考虑了在分权制度中产生统一或分裂政府的多次选举。我们的RDD方法提供了令人信服的证据,证明分裂的政府是拖延的原因。我们还评估并发现支持一个新的假设,即当僵局给政客带来的个人和政治成本较低时,分裂的政府更有可能导致拖延。
{"title":"Is Divided Government a Cause of Legislative Delay","authors":"Patricia A. Kirkland, J. Phillips","doi":"10.1561/100.00017041","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1561/100.00017041","url":null,"abstract":"Despite the compelling theoretical prediction that divided government decreases legislative performance, the empirical literature has struggled to identify a causal effect. We suspect that a combination of methodological challenges and data limitations are to blame. Here, we revisit this empirical relationship. Rather than relying on traditional measures of legislative productivity, however, we consider whether divided government affects the ability of lawmakers to meet critical deadlines — specifically, the ability of state lawmakers to adopt an on-time budget (as mandated by state law). By focusing on delay instead of productivity we avoid measurement problems, particularly the challenges inherent in measuring the supply of and demand for legislation. To assess the causal effect of divided government, we develop and implement a regression discontinuity design (RDD) that accounts for the multiple elections that produce unified or divided government in separation of powers systems. Our RDD approach yields compelling evidence that divided government is a cause of delay. We also evaluate and find support for a new hypothesis that divided government is more likely to lead to delay when the personal and political costs that stalemate imposes on politicians are low.","PeriodicalId":51622,"journal":{"name":"Quarterly Journal of Political Science","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.7,"publicationDate":"2018-05-23","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1561/100.00017041","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"43035510","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 19
Terrorism, Wealth, and Delegation 恐怖主义、财富和授权
IF 1.7 3区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2018-05-22 DOI: 10.1561/100.00017060
William Spaniel
I develop a model in which a terrorist organization delegates tasks to recruits. The organization wants to assign sensitive tasks to the most reliable recruits but cannot perfectly identify commitment to the cause. In equilibrium, the organization interprets the desirability of a recruit’s opportunities in the civilian sector as a credible signal. When the recruit has attractive options available, the organization infers his commitment and gives him a sensitive task; when it is low, the organization conservatively assigns him a non-sensitive task. I then extend the model to allow for a third-party to endogenously improve economic conditions among the civilian population. Despite raising the opportunity cost of terrorism, such subsidies can increase violence because they help the organization identify committed types. ∗Assistant Professor, Department of Political Science, University of Pittsburgh. (williamspaniel@gmail.com, http://williamspaniel.com). I thank Mia Bloom, Bruce Bueno de Mesquita, Martha Crenshaw, Mark Fey, Ben Graham, Connor Huff, Bethany Lacina, Alex Lee, Melia Pfannenstiel, Jack Paine, Branislav Slantchev, Andy Summer, and the participants of the 2016 FMIR conference for their comments. Compared to other types of political violence producers, terrorists have considerable autonomy over day-to-day operations (Shapiro and Siegel 2007; Shapiro 2013). For individuals selected to commit attacks, frequent communication with other agents risks exposing the operation or the network. Although operatives may receive orders from their commanders, they have substantial control over how to carry out those tasks. Lazy or sloppy execution can break an organization’s back. Similarly, terrorist organizations must fear defection. Whereas rebel groups can persist after losing a few comrades, a single defector can force the entire terrorist organization to restructure, change drop points, alter existing attack plans, and remain in stasis until the leaked information ceases to be useful. Consequently, in searching for the ideal recruit, organizations need to find individuals who will not defect at the first bribe offered. Generalizing, because terrorist organizations face monitoring issues (Chai 1993, 103), they have great incentive to separate reliable recruits from security risks. This is no simple task. Organizations may want to delegate tasks to ideologically extreme individuals. However, ideology is an inherently internal attribute, forcing organizations to instead select on observable characteristics. Consider forgone economic opportunities, for example. Only the most radical individuals would sacrifice a wealthy lifestyle to join a terrorist cause. In contrast, giving up a life of poverty sends little useful information to the organization. Scholars have noted that groups pay poverty wages (Bahney et al 2013), perhaps to discourage less motivated individuals from joining, but the literature has yet to fully address the ramifications of such a si
我开发了一个恐怖组织将任务委托给新兵的模型。该组织希望将敏感任务分配给最可靠的新兵,但无法完全确定对事业的承诺。在平衡状态下,该组织将招聘人员在文职部门的机会的可取性解释为一个可信的信号。当招聘人员有吸引人的选择时,组织会推断他的承诺,并给他一项敏感的任务;当它很低时,组织会保守地给他分配一项非敏感的任务。然后,我扩展了该模型,允许第三方内生地改善平民人口的经济状况。尽管增加了恐怖主义的机会成本,但这种补贴可能会增加暴力,因为它们有助于该组织确定犯罪类型。*匹兹堡大学政治学系助理教授。(williamspaniel@gmail.com,http://williamspaniel.com)。我感谢Mia Bloom、Bruce Bueno de Mesquita、Martha Crenshaw、Mark Fey、Ben Graham、Connor Huff、Bethany Lacina、Alex Lee、Melia Pfannenstiel、Jack Paine、Branislav Slantchev、Andy Summer以及2016 FMIR会议的与会者的评论。与其他类型的政治暴力制造者相比,恐怖分子在日常行动中拥有相当大的自主权(Shapiro和Siegel,2007年;Shapiro,2013年)。对于被选择实施攻击的个人来说,与其他代理的频繁通信有暴露操作或网络的风险。尽管特工可能会收到指挥官的命令,但他们对如何执行这些任务有很大的控制权。懒惰或草率的执行可能会让一个组织崩溃。同样,恐怖组织也必须害怕叛逃。反叛组织可以在失去几个战友后继续存在,而一个叛逃者就可以迫使整个恐怖组织重组、改变下降点、改变现有的袭击计划,并保持停滞状态,直到泄露的信息不再有用。因此,在寻找理想的招聘对象时,组织需要找到不会在第一次行贿时叛逃的人。一般来说,由于恐怖组织面临监控问题(Chai 1993103),他们有很大的动机将可靠的招募人员与安全风险区分开来。这不是一项简单的任务。组织可能希望将任务委托给意识形态极端的个人。然而,意识形态是一种内在的属性,迫使组织选择可观察的特征。例如,考虑一下放弃的经济机会。只有最激进的人才会牺牲富裕的生活方式加入恐怖事业。相比之下,放弃贫穷的生活给组织带来的有用信息很少。学者们注意到,群体支付贫困工资(Bahney等人,2013年),也许是为了阻止动机较低的个人加入,但文献尚未完全解决这种信号机制的后果。为了更好地理解财富与恐怖主义之间的关系,我开发了一个模型,在该模型中,组织将敏感和非敏感任务委托给新兵,而第三方则试图通过经济援助安抚公民。如果个人加入组织,他们通常更喜欢敏感的任务。相比之下,尽管该组织认为,对事业的承诺对于非敏感任务来说并不重要,但如果被分配敏感任务的新兵表现出的努力平平,就会受到影响。因此,游戏在2013年,阿拉伯半岛基地组织的副领导人赛义德·阿里·希赫里停止了对电话使用标准安全措施。相应地,美国情报部门开始追踪他。同年晚些时候,一次无人机袭击导致他死亡,使该组织的官僚结构更加脆弱。Berman(2009,14)认为,尽管进入的经济壁垒相对较低,但叛逃的毁灭性后果将运作中的恐怖组织数量限制在40个左右。
{"title":"Terrorism, Wealth, and Delegation","authors":"William Spaniel","doi":"10.1561/100.00017060","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1561/100.00017060","url":null,"abstract":"I develop a model in which a terrorist organization delegates tasks to recruits. The organization wants to assign sensitive tasks to the most reliable recruits but cannot perfectly identify commitment to the cause. In equilibrium, the organization interprets the desirability of a recruit’s opportunities in the civilian sector as a credible signal. When the recruit has attractive options available, the organization infers his commitment and gives him a sensitive task; when it is low, the organization conservatively assigns him a non-sensitive task. I then extend the model to allow for a third-party to endogenously improve economic conditions among the civilian population. Despite raising the opportunity cost of terrorism, such subsidies can increase violence because they help the organization identify committed types. ∗Assistant Professor, Department of Political Science, University of Pittsburgh. (williamspaniel@gmail.com, http://williamspaniel.com). I thank Mia Bloom, Bruce Bueno de Mesquita, Martha Crenshaw, Mark Fey, Ben Graham, Connor Huff, Bethany Lacina, Alex Lee, Melia Pfannenstiel, Jack Paine, Branislav Slantchev, Andy Summer, and the participants of the 2016 FMIR conference for their comments. Compared to other types of political violence producers, terrorists have considerable autonomy over day-to-day operations (Shapiro and Siegel 2007; Shapiro 2013). For individuals selected to commit attacks, frequent communication with other agents risks exposing the operation or the network. Although operatives may receive orders from their commanders, they have substantial control over how to carry out those tasks. Lazy or sloppy execution can break an organization’s back. Similarly, terrorist organizations must fear defection. Whereas rebel groups can persist after losing a few comrades, a single defector can force the entire terrorist organization to restructure, change drop points, alter existing attack plans, and remain in stasis until the leaked information ceases to be useful. Consequently, in searching for the ideal recruit, organizations need to find individuals who will not defect at the first bribe offered. Generalizing, because terrorist organizations face monitoring issues (Chai 1993, 103), they have great incentive to separate reliable recruits from security risks. This is no simple task. Organizations may want to delegate tasks to ideologically extreme individuals. However, ideology is an inherently internal attribute, forcing organizations to instead select on observable characteristics. Consider forgone economic opportunities, for example. Only the most radical individuals would sacrifice a wealthy lifestyle to join a terrorist cause. In contrast, giving up a life of poverty sends little useful information to the organization. Scholars have noted that groups pay poverty wages (Bahney et al 2013), perhaps to discourage less motivated individuals from joining, but the literature has yet to fully address the ramifications of such a si","PeriodicalId":51622,"journal":{"name":"Quarterly Journal of Political Science","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.7,"publicationDate":"2018-05-22","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1561/100.00017060","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"49637260","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Something for Something: How and Why Direct Democracy Impacts Service Quality 物有所值:直接民主如何以及为什么影响服务质量
IF 1.7 3区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2018-03-29 DOI: 10.1561/100.00017004
Michael W. Sances
Does direct democracy affect the quality of government services? Numerous studies find that direct democracy reduces government revenues, but whether this reflects lower quality services, or simply reduced waste, is unknown. I use a local government reform to estimate the effect of mandatory tax referendums on both revenues and service quality, here measured using fire department response times. The introduction of referendums reduces revenue growth by 1.8%, while also increasing response times by half a minute. An analysis of precinct-level service utilization and electoral behavior suggests that this effect is driven not by voter myopia, but by selfinterest. Poor precincts, which are six times as likely to experience a structure fire, are also six times as likely to vote to increase taxes. Consistent with the precinct-level results, the effects of referendums are smallest in the poorest districts, and are largest in the wealthiest districts.
直接民主会影响政府服务的质量吗?许多研究发现,直接民主减少了政府收入,但这是否反映了服务质量下降,或者仅仅是减少了浪费,还不得而知。我使用地方政府改革来估计强制性税收公投对收入和服务质量的影响,这里使用消防部门的响应时间来衡量。公投的引入使财政收入增长减少了1.8%,同时也使反应时间增加了半分钟。一项对选区级服务利用和选举行为的分析表明,这种影响不是由选民的短视造成的,而是由自身利益造成的。贫穷的选区发生建筑火灾的可能性是普通选区的六倍,投票赞成增税的可能性也是普通选区的六倍。与选区一级的结果一致,公民投票的影响在最贫穷的地区最小,而在最富裕的地区最大。
{"title":"Something for Something: How and Why Direct Democracy Impacts Service Quality","authors":"Michael W. Sances","doi":"10.1561/100.00017004","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1561/100.00017004","url":null,"abstract":"Does direct democracy affect the quality of government services? Numerous studies find that direct democracy reduces government revenues, but whether this reflects lower quality services, or simply reduced waste, is unknown. I use a local government reform to estimate the effect of mandatory tax referendums on both revenues and service quality, here measured using fire department response times. The introduction of referendums reduces revenue growth by 1.8%, while also increasing response times by half a minute. An analysis of precinct-level service utilization and electoral behavior suggests that this effect is driven not by voter myopia, but by selfinterest. Poor precincts, which are six times as likely to experience a structure fire, are also six times as likely to vote to increase taxes. Consistent with the precinct-level results, the effects of referendums are smallest in the poorest districts, and are largest in the wealthiest districts.","PeriodicalId":51622,"journal":{"name":"Quarterly Journal of Political Science","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.7,"publicationDate":"2018-03-29","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1561/100.00017004","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"43452742","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4
The Long-lasting Effects of Newspaper Op-Eds on Public Opinion 报纸评论对公众舆论的长期影响
IF 1.7 3区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2018-03-29 DOI: 10.1561/100.00016112
A. Coppock, Emily E. Ekins, D. Kirby
Do newspaper opinion pieces change the minds of those who read them? We conduct two randomized panel survey experiments on elite and mass convenience samples to estimate the effects of five op-eds on policy attitudes. We find very large average treatment effects on target issues, equivalent to shifts of approximately 0.5 scale points on a 7-point scale, that persist for at least one month. We find very small and insignificant average treatment effects on non-target issues, suggesting that our subjects read, understood, and were persuaded by the arguments presented in these op-eds. We find limited evidence of treatment effect heterogeneity by party identification: Democrats, Republicans, and independents all appear to move in the predicted direction by similar magnitudes. We conduct this study on both a sample of Amazon Mechanical Turk workers and a sample of elites. Despite large differences in demographics and initial political beliefs, we find that op-eds were persuasive to both the mass public and elites, but marginally more persuasive among the mass public. Our findings add to the growing body of evidence of the everyday nature of persuasion.
报纸上的评论文章会改变读者的想法吗?我们对精英和大众便利样本进行了两次随机小组调查实验,以估计五篇专栏文章对政策态度的影响。我们发现对目标问题的平均治疗效果非常大,相当于在7分制中大约0.5分的变化,持续至少一个月。我们发现对非目标问题的平均治疗效果非常小且不显著,这表明我们的受试者阅读、理解并被这些专栏文章中的论点所说服。我们发现,在政党认同方面,治疗效果异质性的证据有限:民主党人、共和党人和无党派人士似乎都以相似的幅度向预测的方向移动。我们对亚马逊土耳其机械公司的员工和精英进行了这项研究。尽管人口统计和最初的政治信仰存在巨大差异,但我们发现,专栏文章对大众和精英都有说服力,但在大众中更具说服力。我们的发现增加了越来越多的关于说服的日常性质的证据。
{"title":"The Long-lasting Effects of Newspaper Op-Eds on Public Opinion","authors":"A. Coppock, Emily E. Ekins, D. Kirby","doi":"10.1561/100.00016112","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1561/100.00016112","url":null,"abstract":"Do newspaper opinion pieces change the minds of those who read them? We conduct two randomized panel survey experiments on elite and mass convenience samples to estimate the effects of five op-eds on policy attitudes. We find very large average treatment effects on target issues, equivalent to shifts of approximately 0.5 scale points on a 7-point scale, that persist for at least one month. We find very small and insignificant average treatment effects on non-target issues, suggesting that our subjects read, understood, and were persuaded by the arguments presented in these op-eds. We find limited evidence of treatment effect heterogeneity by party identification: Democrats, Republicans, and independents all appear to move in the predicted direction by similar magnitudes. We conduct this study on both a sample of Amazon Mechanical Turk workers and a sample of elites. Despite large differences in demographics and initial political beliefs, we find that op-eds were persuasive to both the mass public and elites, but marginally more persuasive among the mass public. Our findings add to the growing body of evidence of the everyday nature of persuasion.","PeriodicalId":51622,"journal":{"name":"Quarterly Journal of Political Science","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.7,"publicationDate":"2018-03-29","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1561/100.00016112","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"43504042","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 70
Can You Hear Me Now? How Communication Technology Affects Protest and Repression. 你现在能听到我吗?通讯技术如何影响抗议和镇压。
IF 1.7 3区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2018-01-01 Epub Date: 2018-03-29 DOI: 10.1561/100.00016129
Darin Christensen, Francisco Garfias

Commentators covering recent social movements, such as the Arab Spring, commonly claim that cell phones enable protests. Yet, existing empirical work does not conclusively support this contention: some studies find that these technologies actually reduce collective action; many others struggle to overcome the selection problems that dog observational research. We propose two mechanisms through which cell phones affect protests: (1) by enabling communication among would-be protesters, cell phones lower coordination costs; and (2) these technologies broadcast information about whether a protest is repressed. Knowing that a larger audience now witnesses and may be angered by repression, governments refrain from squashing demonstrations, further lowering the cost of protesting. We evaluate these mechanisms using high-resolution global data on the expansion of cell phone coverage and incidence of protest from 2007 to 2014. Our difference-in-differences estimates indicate that cell phone coverage increases the probability of protest by over half the mean. Consistent with our second mechanism, we also find that gaining coverage has a larger effect when it connects a locality to a large proportion of other citizens.

报道近期社会运动(如阿拉伯之春)的评论员通常声称,手机使抗议成为可能。然而,现有的实证工作并没有最终支持这一论点:一些研究发现,这些技术实际上减少了集体行动;还有许多人在努力克服困扰观察性研究的选择问题。我们提出了手机影响抗议的两种机制:(1)通过使潜在抗议者之间的沟通成为可能,手机降低了协调成本;(2)这些技术传播抗议是否被压制的信息。政府知道现在有更多的观众目睹并可能对镇压感到愤怒,因此避免镇压示威活动,进一步降低了抗议的成本。我们使用2007年至2014年手机覆盖范围扩大和抗议事件发生率的高分辨率全球数据来评估这些机制。我们的差异中差异估计表明,手机覆盖使抗议的可能性增加了平均值的一半以上。与我们的第二种机制一致,我们还发现,当一个地方与其他大部分公民联系起来时,获得覆盖的效果更大。
{"title":"Can You Hear Me Now? How Communication Technology Affects Protest and Repression.","authors":"Darin Christensen,&nbsp;Francisco Garfias","doi":"10.1561/100.00016129","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1561/100.00016129","url":null,"abstract":"<p><p>Commentators covering recent social movements, such as the Arab Spring, commonly claim that cell phones enable protests. Yet, existing empirical work does not conclusively support this contention: some studies find that these technologies actually reduce collective action; many others struggle to overcome the selection problems that dog observational research. We propose two mechanisms through which cell phones affect protests: (1) by enabling communication among would-be protesters, cell phones lower coordination costs; and (2) these technologies broadcast information about whether a protest is repressed. Knowing that a larger audience now witnesses and may be angered by repression, governments refrain from squashing demonstrations, further lowering the cost of protesting. We evaluate these mechanisms using high-resolution global data on the expansion of cell phone coverage and incidence of protest from 2007 to 2014. Our difference-in-differences estimates indicate that cell phone coverage increases the probability of protest by over half the mean. Consistent with our second mechanism, we also find that gaining coverage has a larger effect when it connects a locality to a large proportion of other citizens.</p>","PeriodicalId":51622,"journal":{"name":"Quarterly Journal of Political Science","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.7,"publicationDate":"2018-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1561/100.00016129","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"37151608","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Choice vs. Action: Candidate Ambiguity and Voter Decision Making 选择与行动:候选人歧义与选民决策
IF 1.7 3区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2017-12-06 DOI: 10.1561/100.00016051
Yanna Krupnikov, J. Ryan
A rich literature argues that electoral incentives lead candidates to take ambiguous positions on issues. Furthermore, empirical research suggests that ambiguity does not repel — and may actually attract — voters. This work, however, equates choosing a candidate with paying the costs of voting for that candidate. We reconsider the relationship between candidate ambiguity and candidate preference moving beyond candidate choice and considering turnout as well. Integrating political science with research on consumer decision-making and psychology, we argue that many who select an ambiguous candidate do not translate that choice into an actual vote for that candidate. We test this argument using three experiments which incorporate costly voting and other electoral conditions heretofore absent from research on ambiguity.
大量文献认为,选举激励会导致候选人在问题上采取模棱两可的立场。此外,实证研究表明,模棱两可并不会排斥——实际上可能会吸引——选民。然而,这项工作将选择候选人等同于为该候选人支付投票费用。我们重新考虑了候选人模糊性和候选人偏好之间的关系,超越了候选人选择,也考虑了投票率。将政治学与消费者决策和心理学研究相结合,我们认为,许多选择模糊候选人的人并没有将这种选择转化为对该候选人的实际投票。我们使用三个实验来检验这一论点,这些实验结合了迄今为止对模糊性的研究中没有的昂贵的投票和其他选举条件。
{"title":"Choice vs. Action: Candidate Ambiguity and Voter Decision Making","authors":"Yanna Krupnikov, J. Ryan","doi":"10.1561/100.00016051","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1561/100.00016051","url":null,"abstract":"A rich literature argues that electoral incentives lead candidates to take ambiguous positions on issues. Furthermore, empirical research suggests that ambiguity does not repel — and may actually attract — voters. This work, however, equates choosing a candidate with paying the costs of voting for that candidate. We reconsider the relationship between candidate ambiguity and candidate preference moving beyond candidate choice and considering turnout as well. Integrating political science with research on consumer decision-making and psychology, we argue that many who select an ambiguous candidate do not translate that choice into an actual vote for that candidate. We test this argument using three experiments which incorporate costly voting and other electoral conditions heretofore absent from research on ambiguity.","PeriodicalId":51622,"journal":{"name":"Quarterly Journal of Political Science","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.7,"publicationDate":"2017-12-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1561/100.00016051","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"43762415","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 24
Order, Distance, and Local Development over the Long-Run 秩序、距离与地方长期发展
IF 1.7 3区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2017-12-06 DOI: 10.1561/100.00016020
Jan H Pierskalla, Anna Schultz, Erik Wibbels
We argue that local, long-term exposure to a centralized political authority determines sub-national patterns of contemporary economic development. Older research on economic development has focused on cross-national income accounts, often ignoring the large sub-national variation in income differences. Likewise, research on the effects of political institutions on development has mostly neglected sub-national variation in the institutional environment. Yet a growing body of work shows that the geographic reach of states within countries and their ability to foster economic exchange have varied dramatically through history. We contribute to recent research on sub-national development by creating a new measure of local historical exposure to state institutions that codes geographic distance to historical capital cities and use highly spatially disaggregated data on economic development, based on satellite data, to test their relationship. We find clear evidence, using fixed-effects estimations for both European and global data, that local historical proximity to capital cities is associated with higher levels of economic development. This finding is further substantiated through a number of robustness checks covering alternative measures, specifications, and sensitivity analyses.
我们认为,地方、长期暴露于中央集权的政治权威决定了当代经济发展的次国家模式。较早的经济发展研究侧重于跨国民收入账户,往往忽略了收入差异的巨大亚国民差异。同样,关于政治制度对发展影响的研究大多忽略了制度环境中的次国家差异。然而,越来越多的研究表明,国家在国家内部的地理范围及其促进经济交流的能力在历史上发生了巨大变化。我们为最近关于次国家发展的研究做出了贡献,创建了一个新的衡量地方历史对国家机构的影响的指标,该指标对与历史首都的地理距离进行编码,并使用基于卫星数据的高度空间分类的经济发展数据来测试它们之间的关系。使用欧洲和全球数据的固定效应估计,我们发现了明确的证据,表明当地历史上与首都的接近程度与较高的经济发展水平有关。这一发现通过包括替代措施、规范和灵敏度分析在内的一系列稳健性检查得到了进一步证实。
{"title":"Order, Distance, and Local Development over the Long-Run","authors":"Jan H Pierskalla, Anna Schultz, Erik Wibbels","doi":"10.1561/100.00016020","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1561/100.00016020","url":null,"abstract":"We argue that local, long-term exposure to a centralized political authority determines sub-national patterns of contemporary economic development. Older research on economic development has focused on cross-national income accounts, often ignoring the large sub-national variation in income differences. Likewise, research on the effects of political institutions on development has mostly neglected sub-national variation in the institutional environment. Yet a growing body of work shows that the geographic reach of states within countries and their ability to foster economic exchange have varied dramatically through history. We contribute to recent research on sub-national development by creating a new measure of local historical exposure to state institutions that codes geographic distance to historical capital cities and use highly spatially disaggregated data on economic development, based on satellite data, to test their relationship. We find clear evidence, using fixed-effects estimations for both European and global data, that local historical proximity to capital cities is associated with higher levels of economic development. This finding is further substantiated through a number of robustness checks covering alternative measures, specifications, and sensitivity analyses.","PeriodicalId":51622,"journal":{"name":"Quarterly Journal of Political Science","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.7,"publicationDate":"2017-12-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1561/100.00016020","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"43239776","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 15
Sovereignty, Law, and Finance: Evidence from American Indian Reservations 主权、法律和财政:来自美国印第安保留地的证据
IF 1.7 3区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2017-12-06 DOI: 10.1561/100.00016131
R. Wellhausen
In 1953, Congress supplanted the tribal civil law on some American-Indian reservations with the civil law of the US state in which they are located. In the vein of cross-national literature on law and finance, I demonstrate that Congress's action reduced external financial actors' uncertainty over the enforcement of contracts on some reservations. Using novel data on 20,000 home loans to tribal members guaranteed by a US Housing and Urban Development program (1996–2013), I find a causal effect at the individual level: mortgage holders governed by US state civil law pay consistently lower interest rates. Thus, externally imposed law generates long-term benefits for tribal members. Nonetheless, qualitative extensions suggest that neither the presence nor the magnitude of the effect offsets many tribes' prioritization of their sovereignty, rather than the individual-level economic benefits that can result from compromising it.
1953年,国会用美国印第安人保留地所在州的民法取代了一些印第安人保留地的部落民法。根据有关法律和金融的跨国文献,我证明,国会的行动减少了外部金融行为者在执行某些保留合同方面的不确定性。利用美国住房和城市发展计划(1996-2013)为部落成员提供的20000笔住房贷款的新数据,我发现了个人层面的因果效应:受美国州民法管辖的抵押贷款持有人支付的利率一直较低。因此,外部强加的法律为部落成员带来了长期利益。尽管如此,定性的扩展表明,无论是存在还是影响的程度,都不能抵消许多部落对其主权的优先考虑,而不是损害主权可能带来的个人层面的经济利益。
{"title":"Sovereignty, Law, and Finance: Evidence from American Indian Reservations","authors":"R. Wellhausen","doi":"10.1561/100.00016131","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1561/100.00016131","url":null,"abstract":"In 1953, Congress supplanted the tribal civil law on some American-Indian reservations with the civil law of the US state in which they are located. In the vein of cross-national literature on law and finance, I demonstrate that Congress's action reduced external financial actors' uncertainty over the enforcement of contracts on some reservations. Using novel data on 20,000 home loans to tribal members guaranteed by a US Housing and Urban Development program (1996–2013), I find a causal effect at the individual level: mortgage holders governed by US state civil law pay consistently lower interest rates. Thus, externally imposed law generates long-term benefits for tribal members. Nonetheless, qualitative extensions suggest that neither the presence nor the magnitude of the effect offsets many tribes' prioritization of their sovereignty, rather than the individual-level economic benefits that can result from compromising it.","PeriodicalId":51622,"journal":{"name":"Quarterly Journal of Political Science","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.7,"publicationDate":"2017-12-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1561/100.00016131","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"46404894","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 12
Reducing or reinforcing in-group preferences? An experiment on information and ethnic voting 减少还是强化群体偏好?信息与种族投票实验
IF 1.7 3区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2017-12-06 DOI: 10.1561/100.00017018
Claire L. Adida, J. Gottlieb, Eric Kramon, Gwyneth H. McClendon
Social scientists often characterize identity politics as a threat to democracy and growth, and recent scholarship investigates factors that could exacerbate or alleviate it. A dominant view — that shared social identity acts as a heuristic in low-information contexts — implies that information access could reduce social identity voting. But this view contrasts with evidence that identity often conditions information processing, potentially in ways that amplify in-group preferences. We test these expectations with a field experiment around Benin's 2015 legislative elections. Behavioral and attitudinal data reveal that voters reward good-performing incumbents only if they are coethnics, and punish bad performers only if they are noncoethnics. Coethnics are also more (less) likely to accurately recall performance information if it is positive (negative). These results are consistent with a theory of motivated reasoning whereby voters act on new information only when it allows them to reaffirm their social identity. These findings improve our understanding of comparative ethnic politics, identity and information processing, and information and accountability.
社会科学家经常将身份政治描述为对民主和增长的威胁,最近的学术研究调查了可能加剧或缓解这种威胁的因素。一种主流观点认为,共享社会身份在低信息环境中起到启发作用,这意味着信息获取可能会减少社会身份投票。但这一观点与身份通常会影响信息处理的证据形成了鲜明对比,可能会放大群体内的偏好。我们通过围绕贝宁2015年立法选举的实地实验来检验这些期望。行为和态度数据显示,选民只有在表现良好的现任者是异性恋时才会奖励他们,只有在表现不佳的现任者不是异性恋时才惩罚他们。如果绩效信息是正面的(负面的),同事们也更有可能(更少)准确地回忆起绩效信息。这些结果与动机推理理论一致,即选民只有在新信息允许他们重申自己的社会身份时才会对其采取行动。这些发现提高了我们对比较种族政治、身份和信息处理以及信息和问责制的理解。
{"title":"Reducing or reinforcing in-group preferences? An experiment on information and ethnic voting","authors":"Claire L. Adida, J. Gottlieb, Eric Kramon, Gwyneth H. McClendon","doi":"10.1561/100.00017018","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1561/100.00017018","url":null,"abstract":"Social scientists often characterize identity politics as a threat to democracy and growth, and recent scholarship investigates factors that could exacerbate or alleviate it. A dominant view — that shared social identity acts as a heuristic in low-information contexts — implies that information access could reduce social identity voting. But this view contrasts with evidence that identity often conditions information processing, potentially in ways that amplify in-group preferences. We test these expectations with a field experiment around Benin's 2015 legislative elections. Behavioral and attitudinal data reveal that voters reward good-performing incumbents only if they are coethnics, and punish bad performers only if they are noncoethnics. Coethnics are also more (less) likely to accurately recall performance information if it is positive (negative). These results are consistent with a theory of motivated reasoning whereby voters act on new information only when it allows them to reaffirm their social identity. These findings improve our understanding of comparative ethnic politics, identity and information processing, and information and accountability.","PeriodicalId":51622,"journal":{"name":"Quarterly Journal of Political Science","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.7,"publicationDate":"2017-12-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1561/100.00017018","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"49599691","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 74
The Majority-Party Disadvantage: Revising Theories of Legislative Organization 多数党的劣势:立法组织理论的修正
IF 1.7 3区 社会学 Q1 Social Sciences Pub Date : 2017-10-24 DOI: 10.1561/100.00015112
J. Feigenbaum, Alexander Fouirnaies, Andrew B. Hall
Dominant theories of legislative organization in the U.S. rest on the notion that the majority party arranges legislative matters to enhance its electoral fortunes. Yet, we find little evidence for a short-term electoral advantage for the majority party in U.S. state legislatures. Furthermore, there appears to be a pronounced downstream majority-party disadvantage . To establish these findings, we propose a technique for aggregating the results of close elections to obtain as-if random variation in majority-party status. We argue that the results from this approach are consistent with a phenomenon of inter-temporal balancing, which we link to other forms of partisan balancing in U.S. elections. The article thus necessitates revisions to our theories of legislative organization, offers new arguments for balancing theories, and lays out an empirical technique for studying the effects of majority-party status in legislative contexts.
美国立法组织的主流理论基于这样一种观念,即多数党安排立法事务以增加其在选举中的胜算。然而,我们发现很少有证据表明美国州立法机构的多数党在短期内具有选举优势。此外,似乎存在明显的下游多数党劣势。为了建立这些发现,我们提出了一种技术,用于汇总势均力敌的选举结果,以获得多数党地位的随机变化。我们认为,这种方法的结果与跨期平衡现象是一致的,我们将其与美国选举中其他形式的党派平衡联系起来。因此,本文有必要修正我们的立法组织理论,为平衡理论提供新的论据,并为研究多数党地位在立法背景下的影响提供一种实证技术。
{"title":"The Majority-Party Disadvantage: Revising Theories of Legislative Organization","authors":"J. Feigenbaum, Alexander Fouirnaies, Andrew B. Hall","doi":"10.1561/100.00015112","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1561/100.00015112","url":null,"abstract":"Dominant theories of legislative organization in the U.S. rest on the notion that the majority party arranges legislative matters to enhance its electoral fortunes. Yet, we find little evidence for a short-term electoral advantage for the majority party in U.S. state legislatures. Furthermore, there appears to be a pronounced downstream majority-party disadvantage . To establish these findings, we propose a technique for aggregating the results of close elections to obtain as-if random variation in majority-party status. We argue that the results from this approach are consistent with a phenomenon of inter-temporal balancing, which we link to other forms of partisan balancing in U.S. elections. The article thus necessitates revisions to our theories of legislative organization, offers new arguments for balancing theories, and lays out an empirical technique for studying the effects of majority-party status in legislative contexts.","PeriodicalId":51622,"journal":{"name":"Quarterly Journal of Political Science","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.7,"publicationDate":"2017-10-24","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1561/100.00015112","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"44276512","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 40
期刊
Quarterly Journal of Political Science
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1