首页 > 最新文献

William and Mary law review最新文献

英文 中文
An Outcomes Analysis of Scope of Review Standards 评审标准范围的结果分析
Pub Date : 2003-01-30 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.373561
Paul R. Verkuil
This article raises a question that is rarely asked: Do outcomes (reversal/affirmance/remand rates) on appeal from administrative decisions bear a predictable relationship to the relevant scope of review standard? It turns out that the answer is both yes and no and that in two very active review systems (district court review over Social Security disability and FOIA decisions) the results run counter to what one might surmise based on the relative intensity of the review standards. While conclusions are carefully and necessarily hedged, the subject yields hypotheses worthy of further analysis.
这篇文章提出了一个很少被问到的问题:行政决定上诉的结果(撤销/确认/发回率)是否与相关的审查标准范围具有可预测的关系?事实证明,答案是肯定的和否定的,而且在两个非常活跃的审查系统(地方法院对社会保障残疾的审查和《信息自由法》的决定)中,结果与人们根据审查标准的相对强度所推测的结果背道而驰。虽然结论是谨慎而必要的,但这个主题产生了值得进一步分析的假设。
{"title":"An Outcomes Analysis of Scope of Review Standards","authors":"Paul R. Verkuil","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.373561","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.373561","url":null,"abstract":"This article raises a question that is rarely asked: Do outcomes (reversal/affirmance/remand rates) on appeal from administrative decisions bear a predictable relationship to the relevant scope of review standard? It turns out that the answer is both yes and no and that in two very active review systems (district court review over Social Security disability and FOIA decisions) the results run counter to what one might surmise based on the relative intensity of the review standards. While conclusions are carefully and necessarily hedged, the subject yields hypotheses worthy of further analysis.","PeriodicalId":75324,"journal":{"name":"William and Mary law review","volume":"44 1","pages":"679"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2003-01-30","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68632327","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 8
Disability, Reciprocity, and "Real Efficiency": A Unified Approach 残疾、互惠和“真正的效率”:一个统一的方法
Pub Date : 2002-12-05 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.358621
Amy Wax
The Americans with Disabilities Act (ADA) requires private employers to offer reasonable accommodation to disabled persons capable of performing the core elements of a job. Some economists have attacked the statute as ill-advised and inefficient. In examining the efficiency of the ADA, this article analyzes its cost-effectiveness against the following social and legal background conditions: First, society will honor a minimum commitment to provide basic support to persons - including the medically disabled - who, through no fault of their own, cannot earn enough to maintain a minimally decent standard of living. Second, legal and pragmatic factors, including "sticky" or rigid compensation schedules and job classifications, sometimes prevent employers from paying wages that perfectly reflect workers' marginal productivity. Because disabilities sometimes compromise productivity or require costly accommodations, employers may find it difficult to avoid overpaying some disabled employees who "otherwise qualify" for particular jobs. The article argues that effective enforcement of the ADA under these conditions will often be efficient for society as a whole, but may not be for all employers. That is, the ADA will sometimes create a divergence between private and social benefits. Because the ADA mandates that employers hire and accommodate workers they otherwise would shun as too expensive, the statute avoids the dead-weight loss, generated by imperfections in labor markets, of keeping potentially productive disabled persons in idleness. But because many disabled workers hired under the ADA's commands are likely to be paid "too much," the statute effectively shifts from the public at large to employers the expense of subsidizing disabled workers - including, most notably, those workers whose earnings, if truly reflective of net productivity, would otherwise be too meager to sustain a decent standard of living. In short, the ADA, although good for potentially productive disabled persons and for taxpayers, is potentially unfair to employers. The article examines some implications of these observations for reforming and restructuring the ADA. It also explores the suggestion, which arguably follows from its analysis, that many disabled persons - like other persons who, for reasons unrelated to medical disability, are not productive enough to achieve full economic self-sufficiency - should be regarded as having an obligation, as well as a right, to contribute something to their own support through work.
《美国残疾人法案》(ADA)要求私人雇主为有能力履行工作核心要素的残疾人提供合理的便利。一些经济学家抨击该法规是不明智的,效率低下的。在审查《美国残疾人法》的效率时,本文分析了它在以下社会和法律背景条件下的成本效益:首先,社会将履行最低限度的承诺,向包括身体残疾的人在内的人提供基本支助,这些人不是因为自己的过错而无法赚取足够的收入来维持最起码的体面生活水平。其次,法律和实际因素,包括“粘性”或僵化的薪酬计划和工作分类,有时会阻止雇主支付完全反映工人边际生产率的工资。由于残疾有时会影响工作效率或需要昂贵的住宿,雇主可能会发现很难避免向一些“其他方面符合”特定工作条件的残疾员工支付过高的工资。文章认为,在这种情况下,《美国残疾人法》的有效执行通常对整个社会都是有效的,但未必对所有雇主都有效。也就是说,《美国残疾人法》有时会造成私人和社会福利之间的分歧。因为《美国残疾人法》要求雇主雇佣和安置那些他们本来会因为成本太高而避开的工人,该法规避免了劳动力市场不完善造成的无谓损失,即让有潜力生产能力的残疾人失业。但是,由于根据《美国残疾人法》的规定雇用的许多残疾工人可能会得到“过高”的报酬,该法规实际上将补贴残疾工人的费用从公众转移到了雇主身上——其中最值得注意的是,那些收入如果真正反映了净生产率,就会太低而无法维持体面生活水平的工人。简而言之,《美国残疾人法》虽然有利于潜在的生产性残疾人和纳税人,但对雇主可能是不公平的。本文探讨了这些观察结果对改革和重组《美国残疾人法》的一些启示。报告还探讨了一项建议,这一建议可以说是根据报告的分析得出的,即许多残疾人——就像其他出于与医疗残疾无关的原因,生产力不足以实现经济完全自给自足的人一样——应被视为有义务和权利通过工作为自己的生活作出贡献。
{"title":"Disability, Reciprocity, and \"Real Efficiency\": A Unified Approach","authors":"Amy Wax","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.358621","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.358621","url":null,"abstract":"The Americans with Disabilities Act (ADA) requires private employers to offer reasonable accommodation to disabled persons capable of performing the core elements of a job. Some economists have attacked the statute as ill-advised and inefficient. In examining the efficiency of the ADA, this article analyzes its cost-effectiveness against the following social and legal background conditions: First, society will honor a minimum commitment to provide basic support to persons - including the medically disabled - who, through no fault of their own, cannot earn enough to maintain a minimally decent standard of living. Second, legal and pragmatic factors, including \"sticky\" or rigid compensation schedules and job classifications, sometimes prevent employers from paying wages that perfectly reflect workers' marginal productivity. Because disabilities sometimes compromise productivity or require costly accommodations, employers may find it difficult to avoid overpaying some disabled employees who \"otherwise qualify\" for particular jobs. The article argues that effective enforcement of the ADA under these conditions will often be efficient for society as a whole, but may not be for all employers. That is, the ADA will sometimes create a divergence between private and social benefits. Because the ADA mandates that employers hire and accommodate workers they otherwise would shun as too expensive, the statute avoids the dead-weight loss, generated by imperfections in labor markets, of keeping potentially productive disabled persons in idleness. But because many disabled workers hired under the ADA's commands are likely to be paid \"too much,\" the statute effectively shifts from the public at large to employers the expense of subsidizing disabled workers - including, most notably, those workers whose earnings, if truly reflective of net productivity, would otherwise be too meager to sustain a decent standard of living. In short, the ADA, although good for potentially productive disabled persons and for taxpayers, is potentially unfair to employers. The article examines some implications of these observations for reforming and restructuring the ADA. It also explores the suggestion, which arguably follows from its analysis, that many disabled persons - like other persons who, for reasons unrelated to medical disability, are not productive enough to achieve full economic self-sufficiency - should be regarded as having an obligation, as well as a right, to contribute something to their own support through work.","PeriodicalId":75324,"journal":{"name":"William and Mary law review","volume":"44 1","pages":"1421"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2002-12-05","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68609437","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
The Legislator-in-Chief 的Legislator-in-Chief
Pub Date : 2002-12-03 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.310163
Vasan Kesavan, J. Sidak
The State of the Union and Recommendation Clauses of Article II, Section 3 provide that the President shall from time to time give to the Congress Information of the State of the Union, and recommend to their consideration such Measures as he shall judge necessary and expedient. Those thirty-one words envision the President as an active participant in the embryonic stages of the making of laws. Eight separate principles animate the President's legislative responsibilities before the presentment process. The State of the Union Clause imposes an executive duty on the President. That duty must be discharged periodically. The President's assessment of the State of the Union must be publicized to Congress, and thus to the nation. The publication of the President's assessment conveys information to Congress - information uniquely gleaned from the President's perspective in his various roles as Commander-in-Chief, chief law enforcer, negotiator with foreign powers, and the like - that shall aid the legislature in public deliberation on matters that may justify the enactment of legislation because of their national importance. The Recommendation Clause also imposes an executive duty on the President. His recommendations respect the equal dignity of Congress and thus embody the anti-royalty sentiment that ignited the American Revolution and subsequently stripped the trappings of monarchy away from the new chief executive. Through his recommendations to Congress, the President speaks collectively for the People as they petition Government for a redress of grievances, and thus his recommendations embody popular sovereignty. The President tailors his recommendations so that their natural implication is the enactment of new legislation, rather then some other action that Congress might undertake. Finally, the President shall have executive discretion to recommend measures of his choosing. When the State of the Union and Recommendation Clauses are seen to have this textual and analytical subtlety, they reveal the sophistication of the Framer's design that the President, through his institutionally unique ability to acquire and analyze information valuable to the leadership of the Republic, would have more to contribute to the making of laws than merely to sign off on their creation by another branch. Far from making the President a cipher in the legislative process, the Constitution created a Legislator-in-Chief.
第2条第3款的国情咨文和建议条款规定,总统应不时向国会提供国情咨文情况,并建议国会考虑他认为必要和适宜的措施。这31个字将总统设想为法律制定萌芽阶段的积极参与者。在提交程序之前,总统的立法责任由八项独立原则决定。《国情咨文》条款规定总统负有行政责任。这项职责必须定期履行。总统对国情咨文的评估必须向国会公布,从而向全国公布。总统评估报告的公布向国会传达了信息——这些信息是总统在担任总司令、首席执法者、与外国势力谈判代表等各种角色时从他的角度独特收集到的——这将有助于立法机关就可能因其对国家的重要性而有理由颁布立法的事项进行公开审议。建议条款还规定了总统的行政责任。他的建议尊重国会的平等尊严,因此体现了反皇室的情绪,这种情绪点燃了美国革命,并随后从新任首席执行官身上剥去了君主制的外衣。总统通过向国会提出建议,代表全体人民向政府请愿,要求纠正他们的不满,因此他的建议体现了人民主权。总统修改了他的建议,使其自然的含义是制定新的立法,而不是国会可能采取的其他行动。最后,总统应有行政自由裁量权建议他所选择的措施。当国情咨文和建议条款被视为具有这种文本和分析上的微妙之处时,它们揭示了制宪者设计的复杂性,即总统通过其制度上独特的能力来获取和分析对共和国领导层有价值的信息,将对法律的制定做出更多贡献,而不仅仅是签署另一个部门的创建。宪法并没有让总统在立法过程中成为一个无足轻重的人物,而是设立了一个首席立法官。
{"title":"The Legislator-in-Chief","authors":"Vasan Kesavan, J. Sidak","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.310163","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.310163","url":null,"abstract":"The State of the Union and Recommendation Clauses of Article II, Section 3 provide that the President shall from time to time give to the Congress Information of the State of the Union, and recommend to their consideration such Measures as he shall judge necessary and expedient. Those thirty-one words envision the President as an active participant in the embryonic stages of the making of laws. Eight separate principles animate the President's legislative responsibilities before the presentment process. The State of the Union Clause imposes an executive duty on the President. That duty must be discharged periodically. The President's assessment of the State of the Union must be publicized to Congress, and thus to the nation. The publication of the President's assessment conveys information to Congress - information uniquely gleaned from the President's perspective in his various roles as Commander-in-Chief, chief law enforcer, negotiator with foreign powers, and the like - that shall aid the legislature in public deliberation on matters that may justify the enactment of legislation because of their national importance. The Recommendation Clause also imposes an executive duty on the President. His recommendations respect the equal dignity of Congress and thus embody the anti-royalty sentiment that ignited the American Revolution and subsequently stripped the trappings of monarchy away from the new chief executive. Through his recommendations to Congress, the President speaks collectively for the People as they petition Government for a redress of grievances, and thus his recommendations embody popular sovereignty. The President tailors his recommendations so that their natural implication is the enactment of new legislation, rather then some other action that Congress might undertake. Finally, the President shall have executive discretion to recommend measures of his choosing. When the State of the Union and Recommendation Clauses are seen to have this textual and analytical subtlety, they reveal the sophistication of the Framer's design that the President, through his institutionally unique ability to acquire and analyze information valuable to the leadership of the Republic, would have more to contribute to the making of laws than merely to sign off on their creation by another branch. Far from making the President a cipher in the legislative process, the Constitution created a Legislator-in-Chief.","PeriodicalId":75324,"journal":{"name":"William and Mary law review","volume":"52 1","pages":"1"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2002-12-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.2139/SSRN.310163","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68561638","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4
Law as Largess: Shifting Paradigms of Law for the Poor 法律即慷慨:穷人法律范式的转变
Pub Date : 2002-11-01 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.348521
Deborah M. Weissman
The article examines the tension between the principles of the Rule of Law and cultural norms of self-sufficiency. It begins by reviewing the principles of the Rule of Law as an ideal, the pursuit of which has led to historical efforts to meet the legal needs of the poor. It then examines recent legal events including federal statutory changes, three Supreme Court cases, and a federal circuit court case which have limited legal resources for those who cannot pay. The article then examines these developments in the context of a sea-change in the political environment of the nation, coinciding with increasing wealth disparities and the shrinking of social welfare programs. It argues that diminished legal resources for the poor are best understood in the context of the structural inequities and the normative biases by which goods and services are delivered to the needy. It reviews the principles of the welfare state as well as charity for the purposes of examining their relevance to legal services for the poor and the deficiencies that result from either method of largess. The article concludes with a recognition that although the current political realities reduce the possibilities for decommodifying the law, corrective measures to expand access to the law are both necessary and possible.
本文考察了法治原则与自给自足的文化规范之间的紧张关系。它首先回顾了作为一种理想的法治原则,对法治的追求导致了历史上为满足穷人的法律需要而做出的努力。然后,它考察了最近的法律事件,包括联邦法律的变化,三个最高法院的案件,以及一个联邦巡回法院的案件,这些案件对那些无法支付费用的人来说法律资源有限。然后,文章在国家政治环境发生巨大变化的背景下考察了这些发展,同时加剧了财富差距和社会福利计划的萎缩。它认为,在向穷人提供商品和服务的结构性不平等和规范偏见的背景下,穷人的法律资源减少是最好的理解。它回顾了福利国家和慈善的原则,目的是研究它们与穷人的法律服务的相关性,以及任何一种慷慨方式所导致的缺陷。文章最后承认,虽然目前的政治现实减少了取消修改法律的可能性,但采取纠正措施扩大利用法律的机会是必要和可能的。
{"title":"Law as Largess: Shifting Paradigms of Law for the Poor","authors":"Deborah M. Weissman","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.348521","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.348521","url":null,"abstract":"The article examines the tension between the principles of the Rule of Law and cultural norms of self-sufficiency. It begins by reviewing the principles of the Rule of Law as an ideal, the pursuit of which has led to historical efforts to meet the legal needs of the poor. It then examines recent legal events including federal statutory changes, three Supreme Court cases, and a federal circuit court case which have limited legal resources for those who cannot pay. The article then examines these developments in the context of a sea-change in the political environment of the nation, coinciding with increasing wealth disparities and the shrinking of social welfare programs. It argues that diminished legal resources for the poor are best understood in the context of the structural inequities and the normative biases by which goods and services are delivered to the needy. It reviews the principles of the welfare state as well as charity for the purposes of examining their relevance to legal services for the poor and the deficiencies that result from either method of largess. The article concludes with a recognition that although the current political realities reduce the possibilities for decommodifying the law, corrective measures to expand access to the law are both necessary and possible.","PeriodicalId":75324,"journal":{"name":"William and Mary law review","volume":"44 1","pages":"737"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2002-11-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.2139/SSRN.348521","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68597857","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 10
The Americans with Disabilities Act as Welfare Reform 美国残疾人法案作为福利改革
Pub Date : 2002-06-23 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.311400
S. Bagenstos
When Congress enacted the Americans with Disabilities Act (ADA) in 1990, disability rights supporters hailed the law as a radical shift in our nation's policy toward people with disabilities. Today, however, the statute's impact, at least in the employment area seems anything but radical. Many explain this disconnect as resulting from a "backlash" against the ADA and particularly a set of judicial decisions in which courts have imposed their own retrograde views of the proper response to disability on a statute that decisively rejects those views. This article challenges that explanation. While many of the disability rights advocates who assisted in drafting and lobbying for the statute shared a basic commitment to society's responsibility to alter its institutions to make all opportunities accessible to all - a commitment that the courts have not well assimilated - those who urged passage of the statute relied to a significant extent on a distinct argument that rests in some tension with that commitment. Throughout the extensive consideration of the ADA, the bill's supporters consistently argued that the statute was necessary to reduce the high societal cost of dependency by moving people with disabilities off of the public assistance rolls and into the workforce. If the "basic premise" of the ADA is seen as the imperative to reduce the cost of dependency of people with disabilities, then many of the courts' restrictive decisions begin to make sense. Roughly put, those decisions limit the statute's protections to individuals who would be largely unable to work without them, and they limit required accommodations to those that are necessary to move those individuals into the workforce in a reasonably cost-effective manner. The point of this article is not to endorse those restrictive decisions but rather to unearth the avoiding-dependency basis for the ADA and begin the process of demonstrating its inadequacy as a guide to disability employment policy. To the extent that the ADA has failed to bring more people with disabilities into the workforce, that failure has as much to do with its own inherent limitations as with judges' refusal to accept the statute's basic premises. While civil rights protections for people with disabilities are essential to serve many purposes, they are not and cannot be the exclusive means of assuring meaningful employment for the maximal number of people with disabilities. The issue remains an important one because disability rights advocates' reliance on avoiding-dependency arguments in lobbying for the ADA was not merely a tactical decision that had some unfortunate effects. Those arguments drew directly on a set of ideas, indigenous to the disability rights movement, that served a crucial purpose both in obtaining wider public support for the disability rights movement and in creating a disability rights movement in the first place. As the restrictive development of ADA case law makes clear, however, framing disabil
当国会于1990年颁布《美国残疾人法案》(ADA)时,残疾人权利支持者称赞这项法律是我国对残疾人政策的一个根本转变。然而,今天,法令的影响,至少在就业领域似乎一点也不激进。许多人将这种脱节解释为对《美国残疾人法》的“强烈反对”,特别是对一系列司法判决的“强烈反对”,在这些判决中,法院将自己对残疾的适当回应的倒退观点强加给了一项坚决拒绝这些观点的法规。本文对这种解释提出了质疑。虽然许多协助起草和游说该法规的残疾人权利倡导者都有一个基本的承诺,即社会有责任改变其制度,使所有人都能获得所有的机会——法院并没有很好地吸收这一承诺——但那些敦促通过该法规的人在很大程度上依赖于一种与该承诺有些矛盾的独特论点。在对《美国残疾人法》的广泛审议过程中,该法案的支持者一直认为,通过将残疾人从公共援助名单中移出,进入劳动力市场,这项法规对于降低依赖他人的高额社会成本是必要的。如果《美国残疾人法》的“基本前提”被视为降低残疾人依赖成本的必要条件,那么许多法院的限制性决定就开始有意义了。粗略地说,这些决定将法规的保护限制在那些没有法律就无法工作的人身上,并将所需的便利限制在那些以合理的成本效益方式将这些人转移到劳动力市场所必需的条件上。本文的重点不是支持那些限制性的决定,而是揭示《美国残疾人法》的避免依赖基础,并开始证明其作为残疾人就业政策指南的不足之处。从某种程度上说,《美国残疾人法》未能让更多的残疾人进入劳动力市场,这种失败既与法官拒绝接受该法规的基本前提有关,也与它自身固有的局限性有关。虽然保护残疾人的公民权利对于实现许多目的至关重要,但它们不是也不可能是确保尽可能多的残疾人获得有意义就业的唯一手段。这个问题仍然是一个重要的问题,因为残疾人权利倡导者在游说《美国残疾人法》时依赖于避免依赖的论点,这不仅仅是一个战术决定,会产生一些不幸的影响。这些论点直接引用了残疾人权利运动的一套思想,这些思想在为残疾人权利运动争取更广泛的公众支持和首先创建残疾人权利运动方面发挥了至关重要的作用。然而,正如《美国残疾人法》案例法的限制性发展所表明的那样,从避免依赖的角度来构建残疾人权利的论点是有代价的,因为它可能无法为改善残疾人就业前景所需的重大政府干预提供充分的理由。
{"title":"The Americans with Disabilities Act as Welfare Reform","authors":"S. Bagenstos","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.311400","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.311400","url":null,"abstract":"When Congress enacted the Americans with Disabilities Act (ADA) in 1990, disability rights supporters hailed the law as a radical shift in our nation's policy toward people with disabilities. Today, however, the statute's impact, at least in the employment area seems anything but radical. Many explain this disconnect as resulting from a \"backlash\" against the ADA and particularly a set of judicial decisions in which courts have imposed their own retrograde views of the proper response to disability on a statute that decisively rejects those views. This article challenges that explanation. While many of the disability rights advocates who assisted in drafting and lobbying for the statute shared a basic commitment to society's responsibility to alter its institutions to make all opportunities accessible to all - a commitment that the courts have not well assimilated - those who urged passage of the statute relied to a significant extent on a distinct argument that rests in some tension with that commitment. Throughout the extensive consideration of the ADA, the bill's supporters consistently argued that the statute was necessary to reduce the high societal cost of dependency by moving people with disabilities off of the public assistance rolls and into the workforce. If the \"basic premise\" of the ADA is seen as the imperative to reduce the cost of dependency of people with disabilities, then many of the courts' restrictive decisions begin to make sense. Roughly put, those decisions limit the statute's protections to individuals who would be largely unable to work without them, and they limit required accommodations to those that are necessary to move those individuals into the workforce in a reasonably cost-effective manner. The point of this article is not to endorse those restrictive decisions but rather to unearth the avoiding-dependency basis for the ADA and begin the process of demonstrating its inadequacy as a guide to disability employment policy. To the extent that the ADA has failed to bring more people with disabilities into the workforce, that failure has as much to do with its own inherent limitations as with judges' refusal to accept the statute's basic premises. While civil rights protections for people with disabilities are essential to serve many purposes, they are not and cannot be the exclusive means of assuring meaningful employment for the maximal number of people with disabilities. The issue remains an important one because disability rights advocates' reliance on avoiding-dependency arguments in lobbying for the ADA was not merely a tactical decision that had some unfortunate effects. Those arguments drew directly on a set of ideas, indigenous to the disability rights movement, that served a crucial purpose both in obtaining wider public support for the disability rights movement and in creating a disability rights movement in the first place. As the restrictive development of ADA case law makes clear, however, framing disabil","PeriodicalId":75324,"journal":{"name":"William and Mary law review","volume":"44 1","pages":"921"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2002-06-23","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.2139/SSRN.311400","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68563432","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 29
The Common Law Genius of the Warren Court 沃伦法院的普通法天才
Pub Date : 2002-05-01 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.315682
D. Strauss
The Warren Court's most important decisions -- on school segregation, reapportionment, free speech, and criminal procedure -- are firmly entrenched in the law. But the idea persists, even among those who were sympathetic to the results that Warren Court reached, that what the Warren Court was doing was somehow not really law: that the Warren Court "made it up," and that the important Warren Court decisions cannot be justified by reference to conventional legal materials. It is true that the Warren Court's most important decisions cannot be easily justified on the basis of the text of the Constitution or the original understandings. But in its major constitutional decisions, the Warren Court was, in a deep sense, a common law court. The decisions in Brown v. Board of Education, Gideon v. Wainwright, Miranda v. Arizona, and even the reapportionment cases, all can be justified as common law decisions. The Warren Court's decisions in these areas resemble the paradigm examples of innovation in the common law, such as Cardozo's decision in MacPherson v. Buick Motor Co. In all of those areas, the Warren Court, although it was innovating, did so in a way that was justified by lessons drawn from precedents. And the Warren Court's decisions were consistent with the presuppositions of a common law system -- that judges should build on previous decisions rather than claiming superior insight, and that innovation should be justified on the basis of what has gone before.
沃伦法院最重要的裁决——关于学校种族隔离、重新分配、言论自由和刑事诉讼程序——都牢牢地根植于法律之中。但是,即使在那些对沃伦法院的判决结果表示同情的人当中,仍然有一种观点认为,沃伦法院所做的事情在某种程度上不是真正的法律:沃伦法院“编造”了它,沃伦法院的重要判决不能通过参考传统法律材料来证明是合理的。确实,沃伦法院最重要的裁决不能轻易地以宪法文本或最初的理解为依据。但就其主要的宪法裁决而言,沃伦法院在很大程度上是一家普通法法院。布朗诉教育委员会案、吉迪恩诉温赖特案、米兰达诉亚利桑那州案,甚至是重新分配的案件,都可以作为普通法裁决来证明是合理的。沃伦法院在这些领域的裁决类似于普通法中创新的范例,如卡多佐在麦克弗森诉别克汽车公司案中的裁决。在所有这些领域,沃伦法院虽然在创新,但其创新的方式是通过从先例中吸取教训来证明的。沃伦法院的判决与普通法制度的前提是一致的,即法官应该以以前的判决为基础,而不是声称自己有更高的洞察力,创新应该在过去的基础上得到证明。
{"title":"The Common Law Genius of the Warren Court","authors":"D. Strauss","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.315682","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.315682","url":null,"abstract":"The Warren Court's most important decisions -- on school segregation, reapportionment, free speech, and criminal procedure -- are firmly entrenched in the law. But the idea persists, even among those who were sympathetic to the results that Warren Court reached, that what the Warren Court was doing was somehow not really law: that the Warren Court \"made it up,\" and that the important Warren Court decisions cannot be justified by reference to conventional legal materials. It is true that the Warren Court's most important decisions cannot be easily justified on the basis of the text of the Constitution or the original understandings. But in its major constitutional decisions, the Warren Court was, in a deep sense, a common law court. The decisions in Brown v. Board of Education, Gideon v. Wainwright, Miranda v. Arizona, and even the reapportionment cases, all can be justified as common law decisions. The Warren Court's decisions in these areas resemble the paradigm examples of innovation in the common law, such as Cardozo's decision in MacPherson v. Buick Motor Co. In all of those areas, the Warren Court, although it was innovating, did so in a way that was justified by lessons drawn from precedents. And the Warren Court's decisions were consistent with the presuppositions of a common law system -- that judges should build on previous decisions rather than claiming superior insight, and that innovation should be justified on the basis of what has gone before.","PeriodicalId":75324,"journal":{"name":"William and Mary law review","volume":"49 1","pages":"845"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2002-05-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68567191","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 142
Commercial Activity and Charitable Tax-Exemption 商业活动及慈善免税
Pub Date : 2002-03-01 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.310070
J. Colombo
This article looks at the relationships between three separate legal doctrines that deal with commercial activity by tax-exempt charities: the "commerciality doctrine" (which governs when commercial activity endangers tax exemption); the unrelated business income tax (which taxes some commercial activity); and the Moline Properties corporate-separate-identity rule (which governs how commercial activity by a subsidiary in a complex structure affects a parent or sibling corporation). After reviewing the current state of legal doctrine in these three areas and concluding that current doctrine is inadequate and contradictory, the article turns to reconstructing the applicable rules in light of the public policy concerns raised with respect to commercial activity by charities. The article identifies six potential policy concerns: (1) unfair competition between exempt and for-profit organizations; (2) protection of the corporate tax base; (3) managerial diversion from charitable mission; (4) economic efficiency; (5) measuring the worth and need for tax subsidies by exempt organizations; and (6) protecting charitable assets from liabilities generated by for-profit business activities. The article then contrasts how two different general approaches to dealing with commercial activity by charities affect these six policy concerns. The two general approaches are permitting such activity to continue tax-free in order to provide additional tax subsidies to exempt organizations versus restricting such activity by expanding the UBIT into a general commercial-activity tax. The article concludes that the best solution to the policy concerns raised by commercial activity is to radically restructure the underlying tests for tax exemption; in absence of such radical restructuring, the article suggests that the next best approach is to restrict commercial activity by expansion of the UBIT, and provides specific doctrinal suggestions for implementing such a "commerciality tax". The article also suggests that under either suggested solution, both the commerciality doctrine and corporate-seprate-identity rule as applied to exempt status should be repealed.
本文着眼于处理免税慈善机构的商业活动的三个独立的法律原则之间的关系:“商业性原则”(当商业活动危及免税时进行管理);不相关企业所得税(对某些商业活动征税);以及Moline Properties公司独立身份规则(该规则规定了复杂结构中子公司的商业活动如何影响母公司或兄弟公司)。在回顾了这三个领域的法律原则的现状后,得出了现有原则的不足和矛盾的结论,文章转向根据公共政策对慈善商业活动提出的关注来重建适用规则。文章指出了六个潜在的政策问题:(1)免税组织和营利性组织之间的不公平竞争;(2)保护企业税基;(三)管理偏离慈善使命;(4)经济效益;(五)测算免税组织的税收补贴价值和需求;(六)保护慈善财产不受营利性经营活动产生的负债的影响。然后,文章对比了处理慈善机构商业活动的两种不同的一般方法如何影响这六项政策问题。两种一般办法是允许这种活动继续免税,以便向获得豁免的组织提供额外的税收补贴;另一种办法是通过将UBIT扩大为一般商业活动税来限制这种活动。本文的结论是,解决商业活动引起的政策关切的最佳办法是从根本上调整免税的基本检验标准;在没有这种彻底的重组的情况下,本文建议,次佳的办法是通过扩大UBIT来限制商业活动,并为实施这种“商业税”提供了具体的理论建议。文章还建议,在这两种解决方案下,适用于豁免地位的商业主义和公司独立身份规则都应被废除。
{"title":"Commercial Activity and Charitable Tax-Exemption","authors":"J. Colombo","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.310070","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.310070","url":null,"abstract":"This article looks at the relationships between three separate legal doctrines that deal with commercial activity by tax-exempt charities: the \"commerciality doctrine\" (which governs when commercial activity endangers tax exemption); the unrelated business income tax (which taxes some commercial activity); and the Moline Properties corporate-separate-identity rule (which governs how commercial activity by a subsidiary in a complex structure affects a parent or sibling corporation). After reviewing the current state of legal doctrine in these three areas and concluding that current doctrine is inadequate and contradictory, the article turns to reconstructing the applicable rules in light of the public policy concerns raised with respect to commercial activity by charities. The article identifies six potential policy concerns: (1) unfair competition between exempt and for-profit organizations; (2) protection of the corporate tax base; (3) managerial diversion from charitable mission; (4) economic efficiency; (5) measuring the worth and need for tax subsidies by exempt organizations; and (6) protecting charitable assets from liabilities generated by for-profit business activities. The article then contrasts how two different general approaches to dealing with commercial activity by charities affect these six policy concerns. The two general approaches are permitting such activity to continue tax-free in order to provide additional tax subsidies to exempt organizations versus restricting such activity by expanding the UBIT into a general commercial-activity tax. The article concludes that the best solution to the policy concerns raised by commercial activity is to radically restructure the underlying tests for tax exemption; in absence of such radical restructuring, the article suggests that the next best approach is to restrict commercial activity by expansion of the UBIT, and provides specific doctrinal suggestions for implementing such a \"commerciality tax\". The article also suggests that under either suggested solution, both the commerciality doctrine and corporate-seprate-identity rule as applied to exempt status should be repealed.","PeriodicalId":75324,"journal":{"name":"William and Mary law review","volume":"44 1","pages":"487-568"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2002-03-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68561488","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
Judges as Altruistic Hierarchs 法官是无私的等级者
Pub Date : 2001-10-16 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.287458
Lynn A. Stout
Many formal discussions of judicial behavior employ a rational choice framework that presumes that judges are rational actors concerned only with improving their own welfare. This essay, prepared as the 2001 George P. Wythe Lecture at the William & Mary School of Law, suggests it may be both inappropriate and misleading to focus exclusively on self-interest as a judicial motivation. The social institution of the judiciary is premised on the expectation of a certain amount of judicial "altruism," in the form of a willingness to devote significant effort to deciding cases impartially and according to law even when external punishments and rewards are largely absent. This expectation rests on a solid empirical foundation: social scientists have compiled extensive evidence demonstrating that other-regarding behavior, including altruistic behavior, is both a common and a predictable phenomenon. As a result there may be much to be gained from formally incorporating the reality of other-regarding behavior into our accounts of the judiciary. As a first step in that direction, the essay reviews some of the voluminous evidence that has been compiled on when and why people display altruistic behavior in experimental games. It explores some implications for how we might better encourage judges largely insulated from external pressures to nevertheless decide cases carefully, impartially, and well.
许多关于司法行为的正式讨论都采用理性选择框架,该框架假定法官是只关心提高自身福利的理性行为者。这篇文章是为2001年威廉与玛丽法学院的乔治·p·威斯讲座而准备的,它表明,仅仅把自身利益作为一种司法动机,可能是不恰当的,也是误导性的。司法制度的社会制度是以一定程度的司法“利他主义”为前提的,其表现形式是,即使在基本没有外部惩罚和奖励的情况下,司法人员也愿意付出巨大努力,公正地、依法地裁决案件。这一期望建立在坚实的经验基础之上:社会科学家已经收集了大量证据,证明考虑他人的行为,包括利他行为,既是一种普遍现象,也是一种可预测的现象。因此,在我们对司法机构的描述中正式纳入考虑他人行为的现实,可能会有很多收获。作为这个方向的第一步,本文回顾了关于人们在实验游戏中何时以及为何表现出利他行为的大量证据。它探讨了我们如何更好地鼓励基本上不受外部压力影响的法官谨慎、公正、出色地裁决案件的一些含义。
{"title":"Judges as Altruistic Hierarchs","authors":"Lynn A. Stout","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.287458","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.287458","url":null,"abstract":"Many formal discussions of judicial behavior employ a rational choice framework that presumes that judges are rational actors concerned only with improving their own welfare. This essay, prepared as the 2001 George P. Wythe Lecture at the William & Mary School of Law, suggests it may be both inappropriate and misleading to focus exclusively on self-interest as a judicial motivation. The social institution of the judiciary is premised on the expectation of a certain amount of judicial \"altruism,\" in the form of a willingness to devote significant effort to deciding cases impartially and according to law even when external punishments and rewards are largely absent. This expectation rests on a solid empirical foundation: social scientists have compiled extensive evidence demonstrating that other-regarding behavior, including altruistic behavior, is both a common and a predictable phenomenon. As a result there may be much to be gained from formally incorporating the reality of other-regarding behavior into our accounts of the judiciary. As a first step in that direction, the essay reviews some of the voluminous evidence that has been compiled on when and why people display altruistic behavior in experimental games. It explores some implications for how we might better encourage judges largely insulated from external pressures to nevertheless decide cases carefully, impartially, and well.","PeriodicalId":75324,"journal":{"name":"William and Mary law review","volume":"43 1","pages":"1605"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2001-10-16","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68409468","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 11
Easing the Spring: Strict Scrutiny and Affirmative Action After the Redistricting Cases 缓和春天:选区重划案件后的严格审查和平权行动
Pub Date : 2001-09-17 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.282570
Pamela S. Karlan
In Adarand Constructors v. Pena, 515 U.S. 200 (1995), the Supreme Court held that all racial classifications, imposed by whatever federal, state, or local governmental actor, must be analyzed by a reviewing court under strict scrutiny. Since then, the Court has been essentially absent from the battle over affirmative action, but it has decided a series of cases involving race-conscious redistricting that may potentially change the way strict scrutiny actually operates. Faced with the prospect of applying a standard of review that would resegregate state legislatures and congressional delegations, the Supreme Court was unwilling to apply strict scrutiny strictly. First, it constricted the domain in which strict scrutiny comes into play at all, permitting race to be taken into account when it is one factor among many and its inclusion produces districts that do not deviate too greatly from those created for other groups. Second, it broadened the interests that can justify race-conscious redistricting, by holding that compliance with the Voting Rights Act's results and effects tests can serve as a compelling state interest. The understanding of political equality embodied in the Act goes beyond what the Constitution itself demands. It requires states to arrange their electoral institutions to minimize the lingering effects of prior unconstitutional discrimination not otherwise chargeable to them, as well as to mitigate the impact of racially polarized voting that involves otherwise constitutionally protected private choice. In short, the theory of strict scrutiny yielded to the need for an electoral system that is equally open to members of minority groups. Having explored the redistricting cases, this article then turns to the question whether, and how, the Court might translate its doctrinal innovations here into its consideration of affirmative action in higher education. It identifies ways in which the admissions process more closely resembles redistricting, and therefore calls for a softer form of scrutiny, than it resembles the competitive bidding process at issue in cases like Adarand. And it suggests that Title VI-based disparate impact standards may perform a role similar to the Voting Rights Act in defining what counts as a compelling state interest.
在Adarand Constructors诉Pena案(515 U.S. 200, 1995)中,最高法院认为,所有由联邦、州或地方政府行为者强加的种族分类,都必须由审查法院在严格审查下进行分析。从那以后,最高法院基本上没有参与有关平权法案的斗争,但它裁决了一系列涉及种族意识重划选区的案件,这些案件可能会改变严格审查的实际运作方式。面对可能会使州立法机构和国会代表团重新隔离的审查标准,最高法院不愿严格执行严格的审查。首先,它限制了严格审查发挥作用的范围,允许在种族是众多因素之一的情况下考虑种族因素,而且纳入种族因素后产生的选区不会与为其他群体创建的选区偏离太大。其次,它认为遵守《投票权法案》的结果和效果测试可以作为一项令人信服的州利益,从而扩大了可以为种族意识重划选区辩护的利益。该法案所体现的对政治平等的理解超越了宪法本身的要求。它要求各州安排其选举机构,以尽量减少先前违宪歧视的挥之不去的影响,否则它们就不会受到指控,并减轻涉及宪法保护的私人选择的种族两极化投票的影响。简而言之,严格审查的理论让位于对少数群体成员同样开放的选举制度的需要。在探讨了重新划分选区的案例之后,本文接着转向法院是否以及如何将其理论创新转化为对高等教育平权行动的考虑。它指出,招生过程在某些方面更类似于重新划分选区,因此需要一种更温和的审查形式,而不是类似于阿达兰等案件中存在争议的竞争性招标过程。它表明,基于第六章的差别影响标准在定义什么是引人注目的州利益方面可能发挥类似于《投票权法案》的作用。
{"title":"Easing the Spring: Strict Scrutiny and Affirmative Action After the Redistricting Cases","authors":"Pamela S. Karlan","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.282570","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.282570","url":null,"abstract":"In Adarand Constructors v. Pena, 515 U.S. 200 (1995), the Supreme Court held that all racial classifications, imposed by whatever federal, state, or local governmental actor, must be analyzed by a reviewing court under strict scrutiny. Since then, the Court has been essentially absent from the battle over affirmative action, but it has decided a series of cases involving race-conscious redistricting that may potentially change the way strict scrutiny actually operates. Faced with the prospect of applying a standard of review that would resegregate state legislatures and congressional delegations, the Supreme Court was unwilling to apply strict scrutiny strictly. First, it constricted the domain in which strict scrutiny comes into play at all, permitting race to be taken into account when it is one factor among many and its inclusion produces districts that do not deviate too greatly from those created for other groups. Second, it broadened the interests that can justify race-conscious redistricting, by holding that compliance with the Voting Rights Act's results and effects tests can serve as a compelling state interest. The understanding of political equality embodied in the Act goes beyond what the Constitution itself demands. It requires states to arrange their electoral institutions to minimize the lingering effects of prior unconstitutional discrimination not otherwise chargeable to them, as well as to mitigate the impact of racially polarized voting that involves otherwise constitutionally protected private choice. In short, the theory of strict scrutiny yielded to the need for an electoral system that is equally open to members of minority groups. Having explored the redistricting cases, this article then turns to the question whether, and how, the Court might translate its doctrinal innovations here into its consideration of affirmative action in higher education. It identifies ways in which the admissions process more closely resembles redistricting, and therefore calls for a softer form of scrutiny, than it resembles the competitive bidding process at issue in cases like Adarand. And it suggests that Title VI-based disparate impact standards may perform a role similar to the Voting Rights Act in defining what counts as a compelling state interest.","PeriodicalId":75324,"journal":{"name":"William and Mary law review","volume":"43 1","pages":"1569"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2001-09-17","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68359387","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 8
Designing Non-National Systems: The Case of the Uniform Domain Name Dispute Resolution Policy 设计非国家制度:以统一域名争议解决政策为例
Pub Date : 2001-06-29 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.275468
L. Helfer, Graeme Dinwoodie
The article critically assesses the Uniform Domain Name Dispute Resolution Policy (UDRP) as a potential model for solving the immense legal challenges presented by transborder activity. Inaugurated in late 1999 by the Internet Corporation for Assigned Names and Numbers (ICANN), the UDRP creates a fast, inexpensive online mechanism for trademark owners to recapture domain names held by persons who, in bad faith, register and use domain names that are confusingly similar to those marks. At present, the UDRP applies only to a narrow segment of disputes between trademark owners and domain name registrants. But the UDRP has been heralded by some as the model for a new non-national approach to lawmaking and dispute settlement applicable to a broader set of legal issues that transcend national borders. In this article, we describe the conditions that led to the UDRP's formation and consider whether the UDRP can and should be replicated elsewhere. The process by which the UDRP was created, and the way in which it is structured, departs significantly from preexisting approaches to international lawmaking and dispute settlement. The UDRP is the product not of national legislation nor an international treaty, but rather of a web of contractual obligations imposed by a private, non-profit corporation with a monopoly over a valuable resource. Through its agreements with the U.S. Department of Commerce, ICANN serves as the gatekeeper for anyone seeking to acquire the most commercially valuable internet addresses. Exclusive control of access to the root server enables ICANN to dictate the terms and conditions for domain name ownership. This technological control also facilitates enforcement of UDRP panel decisions compelling domain name registrars to cancel ownership of contested domain names or transfer them from registrants to trademark owners. The UDRP deviates from preexisting lawmaking and dispute settlement paradigms in other ways that make its advantages considerable (and which may make it attractive for replication). For example, the UDRP is a hybrid dispute settlement system. It contains an amalgam of elements from three distinct decision making paradigms - judicial, arbitral and ministerial - and it draws inspiration from international, supranational, and national legal systems. The UDRP thus reveals how dispute settlement structures can be tailored to the needs of new technologies and new types of legal conflicts. The UDRP is also non-national. Neither its substantive content nor its prescriptive force necessarily depends upon the laws, institutions, and enforcement mechanisms of any single nation-state or treaty regime. It thus suggests ways to bypass the often slow and cumbersome mechanisms of national and international lawmaking and to fulfil the demand for effective dispute settlement mechanisms that, like so much current social activity, transcend national borders. Even assuming the UDRP can be applied to other situations where the conditions of
本文批判性地评估了统一域名争议解决政策(UDRP)作为解决跨境活动所带来的巨大法律挑战的潜在模式。UDRP于1999年底由互联网名称与数字地址分配机构(ICANN)发起,为商标所有人创建了一种快速、廉价的在线机制,以夺回那些恶意注册和使用与这些商标令人混淆的域名的人所拥有的域名。目前,UDRP仅适用于商标所有人和域名注册人之间的一小部分争议。但是,一些人认为,UDRP是一种新的非国家立法和解决争端方法的典范,适用于超越国界的一系列更广泛的法律问题。在本文中,我们将描述导致UDRP形成的条件,并考虑UDRP是否可以并且应该在其他地方复制。《减贫方案》的建立过程及其结构方式与以前的国际立法和解决争端的方法有很大的不同。UDRP既不是国家立法的产物,也不是国际条约的产物,而是垄断一项宝贵资源的私营、非营利性公司强加的合同义务网的产物。通过与美国商务部的协议,ICANN充当了任何寻求获得最有商业价值的互联网地址的人的看门人。对根服务器的独家访问控制使ICANN能够规定域名所有权的条款和条件。这种技术控制还有助于执行UDRP专家组的决定,迫使域名注册商取消争议域名的所有权或将其从注册人转移给商标所有人。UDRP在其他方面偏离了先前存在的立法和解决争端的范例,使其具有相当大的优势(并可能使其具有复制的吸引力)。例如,UDRP是一种混合型争端解决制度。它融合了司法、仲裁和部长级三种不同决策范式的要素,并从国际、超国家和国家法律制度中汲取灵感。因此,UDRP揭示了如何使争端解决结构适应新技术和新类型法律冲突的需要。UDRP也是非国家性质的。其实质内容和规定性效力都不一定取决于任何单一民族国家或条约制度的法律、制度和执行机制。因此,它提出了绕过往往缓慢和繁琐的国家和国际立法机制的方法,并满足对有效解决争端机制的需求,这些机制与当前许多社会活动一样超越国界。然而,即使假设世界发展方案可以适用于垄断性技术控制条件不存在的其他情况,我们也不认为它应该在不首先询问如何构建非国家系统的情况下不加批判地扩展到其他情况。特别是,虽然我们赞扬为建立一个借鉴但不受现有范例限制的非国家模式所作的努力,但该模式的当前迭代未能纳入适当的检查机制,以控制立法的范围和速度以及给予解决争端决策者的有限权力。此外,在其他情况下,国家和非国家价值观之间的紧张关系可能更难以调和;相比之下,域名抢注受到普遍谴责,因此相互竞争的国家价值观较少受到牵连。我们试图确定这些和其他变量,这些变量应该指导新的非国家结构的新检查机制的作者。
{"title":"Designing Non-National Systems: The Case of the Uniform Domain Name Dispute Resolution Policy","authors":"L. Helfer, Graeme Dinwoodie","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.275468","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.275468","url":null,"abstract":"The article critically assesses the Uniform Domain Name Dispute Resolution Policy (UDRP) as a potential model for solving the immense legal challenges presented by transborder activity. Inaugurated in late 1999 by the Internet Corporation for Assigned Names and Numbers (ICANN), the UDRP creates a fast, inexpensive online mechanism for trademark owners to recapture domain names held by persons who, in bad faith, register and use domain names that are confusingly similar to those marks. At present, the UDRP applies only to a narrow segment of disputes between trademark owners and domain name registrants. But the UDRP has been heralded by some as the model for a new non-national approach to lawmaking and dispute settlement applicable to a broader set of legal issues that transcend national borders. In this article, we describe the conditions that led to the UDRP's formation and consider whether the UDRP can and should be replicated elsewhere. The process by which the UDRP was created, and the way in which it is structured, departs significantly from preexisting approaches to international lawmaking and dispute settlement. The UDRP is the product not of national legislation nor an international treaty, but rather of a web of contractual obligations imposed by a private, non-profit corporation with a monopoly over a valuable resource. Through its agreements with the U.S. Department of Commerce, ICANN serves as the gatekeeper for anyone seeking to acquire the most commercially valuable internet addresses. Exclusive control of access to the root server enables ICANN to dictate the terms and conditions for domain name ownership. This technological control also facilitates enforcement of UDRP panel decisions compelling domain name registrars to cancel ownership of contested domain names or transfer them from registrants to trademark owners. The UDRP deviates from preexisting lawmaking and dispute settlement paradigms in other ways that make its advantages considerable (and which may make it attractive for replication). For example, the UDRP is a hybrid dispute settlement system. It contains an amalgam of elements from three distinct decision making paradigms - judicial, arbitral and ministerial - and it draws inspiration from international, supranational, and national legal systems. The UDRP thus reveals how dispute settlement structures can be tailored to the needs of new technologies and new types of legal conflicts. The UDRP is also non-national. Neither its substantive content nor its prescriptive force necessarily depends upon the laws, institutions, and enforcement mechanisms of any single nation-state or treaty regime. It thus suggests ways to bypass the often slow and cumbersome mechanisms of national and international lawmaking and to fulfil the demand for effective dispute settlement mechanisms that, like so much current social activity, transcend national borders. Even assuming the UDRP can be applied to other situations where the conditions of","PeriodicalId":75324,"journal":{"name":"William and Mary law review","volume":"125 1","pages":"141"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2001-06-29","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.2139/SSRN.275468","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"68290996","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 31
期刊
William and Mary law review
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1