首页 > 最新文献

ERN: Regulation (IO) (Topic)最新文献

英文 中文
Regulation As Public Service, Public Servants As Regulators 监管是公共服务,公务员是监管者
Pub Date : 2021-01-08 DOI: 10.1007/978-3-030-29980-4_103
J. van der Heijden
{"title":"Regulation As Public Service, Public Servants As Regulators","authors":"J. van der Heijden","doi":"10.1007/978-3-030-29980-4_103","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-29980-4_103","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":11797,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Regulation (IO) (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-01-08","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"81320042","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Public Interest in Cartelization: A Factor to Develop in Regulating Anti-Competitive Practices in India 卡特尔化中的公共利益:印度监管反竞争行为的一个发展因素
Pub Date : 2021-01-02 DOI: 10.2139/SSRN.3758954
Tejas Hinder, Ashutosh Kumar Singh, G. Singh
Owing to the extensive harm that cartels could potentially cause and create to the economies at national and international levels as well as to the consumers, they become concerns that need to be addressed extensively in relation to the interest of the public. There are multiple factors that have to be taken into account in the study of public interest surrounding cartels, which include, recognition of a target base of consumers, the impact of enforcement action on them in the surrounding legal scenario, and the extent of corrigibility of the actions against the cartel operators, alleged in cases of violation of the aforesaid legal scenario. In determining each of the aforementioned factors prior to the setting up or institutionalization of a cartel, it is imperative to keep the nature of practice within the limits of what is legally construed as a competitive practice, and in exercise of legal due diligence, look into the potential level of consumer detriment, the existing market scenario as well as the priority of the prevailing nature of market, and the actual resources present for investigation of the cartel. Analysing the aforementioned issues in India, this paper, through a critical analysis of the relevant provisions of the Competition Act, 2002 (hereinafter “the Act”), covers issues that arise in light of public interest and its consideration, in the process of cartelization. The authors base their comment on insufficiency of the provisions of the Act to meet the issues of public interest through a detailed analysis of the interplay between consumer benefits and high level of competition between market participants operating on the same relevant market. In doing so, the authors look into adherence to competition policies and the welfare of the consumers. In addition to this, the authors attempt to explore the issue of emergency cartelisation, and bring out the need for its statutory inclusivity.
由于卡特尔可能对国家和国际两级的经济以及消费者造成广泛的损害,它们成为需要从公众利益的角度广泛处理的问题。在研究围绕卡特尔的公共利益时,必须考虑多个因素,其中包括对目标消费者群体的认识,在周围的法律情景中对他们采取的执法行动的影响,以及在违反上述法律情景的情况下对卡特尔经营者采取的行动的可纠正程度。在决定之前所有上述因素设置或卡特尔的制度化,必须保持自然的实践范围内合法视为竞争实践,在行使法律尽职调查,调查消费者损害的潜在水平,现有的市场情况以及市场的普遍性质的优先级,以及欧佩克的实际资源现状进行调查。本文分析了印度的上述问题,通过对2002年《竞争法》(以下简称“该法”)相关条款的批判性分析,涵盖了在卡特尔化过程中根据公共利益及其考虑而产生的问题。作者通过对消费者利益与在同一相关市场上运作的市场参与者之间的高度竞争之间的相互作用的详细分析,将他们的评论建立在该法案的规定不足以满足公共利益问题的基础上。在此过程中,作者研究了对竞争政策和消费者福利的遵守情况。除此之外,作者还试图探讨紧急卡特尔化问题,并提出其法定包容性的必要性。
{"title":"Public Interest in Cartelization: A Factor to Develop in Regulating Anti-Competitive Practices in India","authors":"Tejas Hinder, Ashutosh Kumar Singh, G. Singh","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.3758954","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.3758954","url":null,"abstract":"Owing to the extensive harm that cartels could potentially cause and create to the economies at national and international levels as well as to the consumers, they become concerns that need to be addressed extensively in relation to the interest of the public. \u0000 \u0000There are multiple factors that have to be taken into account in the study of public interest surrounding cartels, which include, recognition of a target base of consumers, the impact of enforcement action on them in the surrounding legal scenario, and the extent of corrigibility of the actions against the cartel operators, alleged in cases of violation of the aforesaid legal scenario. In determining each of the aforementioned factors prior to the setting up or institutionalization of a cartel, it is imperative to keep the nature of practice within the limits of what is legally construed as a competitive practice, and in exercise of legal due diligence, look into the potential level of consumer detriment, the existing market scenario as well as the priority of the prevailing nature of market, and the actual resources present for investigation of the cartel. \u0000 \u0000Analysing the aforementioned issues in India, this paper, through a critical analysis of the relevant provisions of the Competition Act, 2002 (hereinafter “the Act”), covers issues that arise in light of public interest and its consideration, in the process of cartelization. The authors base their comment on insufficiency of the provisions of the Act to meet the issues of public interest through a detailed analysis of the interplay between consumer benefits and high level of competition between market participants operating on the same relevant market. In doing so, the authors look into adherence to competition policies and the welfare of the consumers. In addition to this, the authors attempt to explore the issue of emergency cartelisation, and bring out the need for its statutory inclusivity.","PeriodicalId":11797,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Regulation (IO) (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-01-02","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"86274237","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Regulatory Warnings and Endorsement Disclosures on Social Media 社交媒体上的监管警告和背书披露
Pub Date : 2021-01-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3777034
Abhishek Rishabh
Social media platforms such as Instagram have become an important channel for influencer marketing. Regulatory bodies such as FTC(U.S.) and ASA(U.K.) require influencers on these platforms to clearly declare an advertised social media post as an ad using hashtags such as #ad, #sponsored. However, many a times influencers fail to disclose the endorsements. In light of these malpractices, FTC sent notices to 90 influencers in March 2017. In this paper, I estimate the impact of such disclosure notices on a) disclosure levels b) follower engagement. I create a novel dataset which consists of nearly 150,000 posts across 60 influencers. I use difference-in-difference method to find out that after the notice was sent out disclosure increases. I find that follower engagement (likes and comments) for the influencers which received warnings from the FTC got reduced substantially. Interestingly, I find substantial spillover effects of these notices on influencers which are in FTC jurisdiction but didn’t received the notice. Specifically, disclosure percent of these influencers increased and engagement rate reduced, however, as expected these influencers are relatively less impacted by these notices as compared to the influencers which did receive the FTC notice. I find these results consistent across different categories of influencers. This research is relevant for both social media influencers and policy makers, in that, influencers should preemptively disclose because if the regulator sends out notice, then customers may punish the influencer through less engagement. For policymakers, notices turn out to be a substantive policing instrument, in that, it not only effects the influencers who get the notice but also the influencers who are within the jurisdiction but didn’t get the notice.
Instagram等社交媒体平台已经成为网红营销的重要渠道。美国联邦贸易委员会(FTC)和英国广告协会(ASA)等监管机构要求这些平台上的网红明确声明,在社交媒体上发布的广告是广告,并使用#ad, #sponsored等标签。然而,很多时候,网红没有披露代言。鉴于这些不当行为,联邦贸易委员会于2017年3月向90名影响者发出了通知。在本文中,我估计了此类披露通知对a)披露水平b)追随者参与度的影响。我创建了一个新的数据集,其中包括60位有影响力的人的近15万篇帖子。我用差分法发现,在通知发出后,披露增加了。我发现那些收到FTC警告的网红的追随者参与度(喜欢和评论)大大减少了。有趣的是,我发现这些通知对在FTC管辖范围内但没有收到通知的影响者产生了实质性的溢出效应。具体来说,这些影响者的披露百分比增加了,参与度降低了,然而,正如预期的那样,与收到联邦贸易委员会通知的影响者相比,这些影响者受这些通知的影响相对较小。我发现这些结果在不同类别的影响者中是一致的。这项研究对社交媒体影响者和政策制定者都是相关的,因为影响者应该先发制人地披露,因为如果监管机构发出通知,那么客户可能会通过减少参与来惩罚影响者。对于政策制定者来说,通知是一种实质性的监管工具,因为它不仅影响到收到通知的网红,也影响到在管辖范围内但没有收到通知的网红。
{"title":"Regulatory Warnings and Endorsement Disclosures on Social Media","authors":"Abhishek Rishabh","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3777034","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3777034","url":null,"abstract":"Social media platforms such as Instagram have become an important channel for influencer marketing. Regulatory bodies such as FTC(U.S.) and ASA(U.K.) require influencers on these platforms to clearly declare an advertised social media post as an ad using hashtags such as #ad, #sponsored. However, many a times influencers fail to disclose the endorsements. In light of these malpractices, FTC sent notices to 90 influencers in March 2017. In this paper, I estimate the impact of such disclosure notices on a) disclosure levels b) follower engagement. I create a novel dataset which consists of nearly 150,000 posts across 60 influencers. I use difference-in-difference method to find out that after the notice was sent out disclosure increases. I find that follower engagement (likes and comments) for the influencers which received warnings from the FTC got reduced substantially. Interestingly, I find substantial spillover effects of these notices on influencers which are in FTC jurisdiction but didn’t received the notice. Specifically, disclosure percent of these influencers increased and engagement rate reduced, however, as expected these influencers are relatively less impacted by these notices as compared to the influencers which did receive the FTC notice. I find these results consistent across different categories of influencers. This research is relevant for both social media influencers and policy makers, in that, influencers should preemptively disclose because if the regulator sends out notice, then customers may punish the influencer through less engagement. For policymakers, notices turn out to be a substantive policing instrument, in that, it not only effects the influencers who get the notice but also the influencers who are within the jurisdiction but didn’t get the notice.","PeriodicalId":11797,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Regulation (IO) (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"83885172","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Can We Take the 'Stress' Out of Stress Testing? Applications of Generalized Structural Equation Modeling to Consumer Finance 我们能把压力测试中的“压力”去掉吗?广义结构方程模型在消费金融中的应用
Pub Date : 2021-01-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3775322
José J. Canals-Cerdá
Financial firms, and banks in particular, rely heavily on complex suites of interrelated statistical models in their risk management and business reporting infrastructures. Statistical model infrastructures are often developed using a piecemeal approach to model building, in which different components are developed and validated separately. This type of modeling framework has significant limitations at each stage of the model management life cycle, from development and documentation to validation, production, and redevelopment. We propose an empirical framework, spurred by recent developments in the implementation of Generalized Structural Equation Modeling (GSEM), which brings to bear a modular and all-inclusive approach to statistical model building. We illustrate the “game changing” potential of this framework with an application to the stress testing of credit risk for a representative portfolio of mortgages; we also extend it to the analysis of the allowance for credit loss under the novel Current Expected Credit Loss (CECL) accounting regulation. We illustrate how GSEM techniques can significantly enhance every step of the modeling framework life cycle. We also illustrate how GSEM can be used to combine various risk management projects and tasks into a single framework; we specifically illustrate how to seamlessly integrate stress testing and CECL (or IFRS9) frameworks and champion, and challenger, modeling frameworks. Finally, we identify other areas of model risk management that can benefit from the GSEM framework and highlight other potentially fruitful applications of the methodology.
金融公司,特别是银行,在其风险管理和业务报告基础设施中严重依赖复杂的相互关联的统计模型套件。统计模型基础结构通常使用一种零碎的模型构建方法来开发,在这种方法中,不同的组件被单独开发和验证。这种类型的建模框架在模型管理生命周期的每个阶段(从开发和文档编制到验证、生产和再开发)都有明显的限制。我们提出了一个经验框架,受到最近在实现广义结构方程建模(GSEM)的发展的刺激,它带来了一个模块化和全包的方法来建立统计模型。我们通过应用于典型抵押贷款组合的信贷风险压力测试来说明该框架“改变游戏规则”的潜力;我们还将其扩展到分析新的当期预期信用损失(CECL)会计准则下的信用损失准备。我们演示了GSEM技术如何显著增强建模框架生命周期的每一步。我们还说明了如何使用GSEM将各种风险管理项目和任务组合到一个框架中;我们特别说明了如何无缝地集成压力测试和CECL(或IFRS9)框架以及冠军和挑战者建模框架。最后,我们确定了可以从GSEM框架中受益的模型风险管理的其他领域,并强调了该方法的其他潜在的富有成效的应用。
{"title":"Can We Take the 'Stress' Out of Stress Testing? Applications of Generalized Structural Equation Modeling to Consumer Finance","authors":"José J. Canals-Cerdá","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3775322","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3775322","url":null,"abstract":"Financial firms, and banks in particular, rely heavily on complex suites of interrelated statistical models in their risk management and business reporting infrastructures. Statistical model infrastructures are often developed using a piecemeal approach to model building, in which different components are developed and validated separately. This type of modeling framework has significant limitations at each stage of the model management life cycle, from development and documentation to validation, production, and redevelopment. We propose an empirical framework, spurred by recent developments in the implementation of Generalized Structural Equation Modeling (GSEM), which brings to bear a modular and all-inclusive approach to statistical model building. We illustrate the “game changing” potential of this framework with an application to the stress testing of credit risk for a representative portfolio of mortgages; we also extend it to the analysis of the allowance for credit loss under the novel Current Expected Credit Loss (CECL) accounting regulation. We illustrate how GSEM techniques can significantly enhance every step of the modeling framework life cycle. We also illustrate how GSEM can be used to combine various risk management projects and tasks into a single framework; we specifically illustrate how to seamlessly integrate stress testing and CECL (or IFRS9) frameworks and champion, and challenger, modeling frameworks. Finally, we identify other areas of model risk management that can benefit from the GSEM framework and highlight other potentially fruitful applications of the methodology.","PeriodicalId":11797,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Regulation (IO) (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"91444906","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
U.S. Franchise Regulation as a Paradigm for the European Union 美国特许经营法规对欧盟的借鉴
Pub Date : 2021-01-01 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3910856
R. W. Emerson, Michala Meiselles
The protection afforded to franchisees differs widely across the world. Nations with economically strong franchise sectors typically regulate the contract’s bargaining phase and post-formation. Responding to the European Parliament’s call for a review of regulations governing Europe’s underperforming retail franchise sector, we propose reforms to counter the structural and economic inequality between franchise parties. Drawing on lessons from comparatively successful federal frameworks, we present a regulatory trifecta of mandatory disclosures to prospective franchisees, required express or implied contractual obligations and rights for both franchisors and franchisees, and compulsory adherence to certain protections of franchisees throughout the franchise relationship.
对特许经营商的保护在世界各地差别很大。特许经营行业经济实力雄厚的国家通常会对合同的谈判阶段和形成后进行监管。为响应欧洲议会对管理欧洲表现不佳的零售特许经营部门的法规进行审查的呼吁,我们建议进行改革,以应对特许经营各方之间的结构和经济不平等。借鉴相对成功的联邦框架的经验教训,我们提出了一套三管其下的监管制度,包括对潜在加盟商的强制性披露、对特许人和被特许人双方明示或默示的合同义务和权利的要求,以及在整个特许经营关系中对加盟商的某些保护的强制性遵守。
{"title":"U.S. Franchise Regulation as a Paradigm for the European Union","authors":"R. W. Emerson, Michala Meiselles","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3910856","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3910856","url":null,"abstract":"The protection afforded to franchisees differs widely across the world. Nations with economically strong franchise sectors typically regulate the contract’s bargaining phase and post-formation. Responding to the European Parliament’s call for a review of regulations governing Europe’s underperforming retail franchise sector, we propose reforms to counter the structural and economic inequality between franchise parties. Drawing on lessons from comparatively successful federal frameworks, we present a regulatory trifecta of mandatory disclosures to prospective franchisees, required express or implied contractual obligations and rights for both franchisors and franchisees, and compulsory adherence to certain protections of franchisees throughout the franchise relationship.","PeriodicalId":11797,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Regulation (IO) (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2021-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"74675483","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Monopolies: A Threat to Consumers or a Political Ploy 垄断:对消费者的威胁还是政治策略
Pub Date : 2020-12-21 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3752950
James S. Rowe
The United States Department of Justice recently announced an antitrust lawsuit against the search and search advertising giant, Google. Referencing anticompetitive practices that restrict competition and harm consumers, the DOJ, by attempting to break up Google’s control of the search market due to harm it is inflicting upon consumers as a result of its monopoly power, is continuing a policy of ensuring competitive markets that goes back more than a century to President Theodore Roosevelt and his crusade against trusts, and in particular, John D. Rockefeller’s Standard Oil Monopoly.

Monopolistic behavior can take many forms, but opponents of monopolies, of which there are many, share the common criticism that monopolies are toxic for the economy and commit an injustice against individual consumers. Their solution to these harmful effects includes robust regulation and providing readily available detailed information to the public demonstrating the extent to which industry in the United States is concentrated.

Unfortunately, while it is true that monopolies have the power to cause harm through the market power possessed by monopolies, it is equally true that monopolies are uniquely capable of taking actions that benefit the country, the economy, and consumers. The benefits of monopoly do not receive a lot of publicity because it’s not politically valuable and goes against the traditions of thought to which Americans have been subjected for well over a century. The fact that 10 percent of the world’s public companies generate 80 percent of all profits and the United States’ 100 largest companies have increased their share of GDP creation by 13 percentage points to 46 percent in two decades, it’s urgent to discuss monopolies more expansively and focus on the facts rather than political talking points.1

This paper will make the argument that monopolies are overregulated, which harms the economy and its consumers more so than it helps. Monopolies should be subject to less scrutiny in the U.S. economy to perform their functions more efficiently. Regulators have alternative means of guarding against the negative effects of monopoly while allowing for the positive effects.
美国司法部最近宣布对搜索和搜索广告巨头b谷歌提起反垄断诉讼。参考限制竞争和伤害消费者的反竞争行为,司法部试图打破谷歌对搜索市场的控制,因为它的垄断力量对消费者造成了伤害,这是在继续一项确保竞争市场的政策,该政策可以追溯到一个多世纪前西奥多·罗斯福总统和他对托拉斯的讨讨会,特别是约翰·d·洛克菲勒的标准石油垄断。垄断行为有很多种形式,但反对垄断的人都有一个共同的批评,即垄断对经济有害,对个人消费者不公平。他们对这些有害影响的解决方案包括强有力的监管,并向公众提供现成的详细信息,说明美国工业集中的程度。不幸的是,虽然垄断确实有能力通过垄断所拥有的市场力量造成伤害,但同样真实的是,垄断有独特的能力采取有利于国家、经济和消费者的行动。垄断的好处并没有得到很多宣传,因为它没有政治价值,也违背了美国人一个多世纪以来所遵循的思想传统。事实上,世界上10%的上市公司创造了80%的利润,美国100家最大的公司在20年内将其在GDP创造中的份额提高了13个百分点,达到46%,迫切需要更广泛地讨论垄断问题,关注事实,而不是政治话题。本文将提出这样的论点:垄断被过度监管,这对经济和消费者的危害大于帮助。在美国经济中,垄断企业应该受到较少的审查,以更有效地履行其职能。监管机构有其他方法来防范垄断的负面影响,同时允许其产生积极影响。
{"title":"Monopolies: A Threat to Consumers or a Political Ploy","authors":"James S. Rowe","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3752950","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3752950","url":null,"abstract":"The United States Department of Justice recently announced an antitrust lawsuit against the search and search advertising giant, Google. Referencing anticompetitive practices that restrict competition and harm consumers, the DOJ, by attempting to break up Google’s control of the search market due to harm it is inflicting upon consumers as a result of its monopoly power, is continuing a policy of ensuring competitive markets that goes back more than a century to President Theodore Roosevelt and his crusade against trusts, and in particular, John D. Rockefeller’s Standard Oil Monopoly.<br><br>Monopolistic behavior can take many forms, but opponents of monopolies, of which there are many, share the common criticism that monopolies are toxic for the economy and commit an injustice against individual consumers. Their solution to these harmful effects includes robust regulation and providing readily available detailed information to the public demonstrating the extent to which industry in the United States is concentrated.<br><br>Unfortunately, while it is true that monopolies have the power to cause harm through the market power possessed by monopolies, it is equally true that monopolies are uniquely capable of taking actions that benefit the country, the economy, and consumers. The benefits of monopoly do not receive a lot of publicity because it’s not politically valuable and goes against the traditions of thought to which Americans have been subjected for well over a century. The fact that 10 percent of the world’s public companies generate 80 percent of all profits and the United States’ 100 largest companies have increased their share of GDP creation by 13 percentage points to 46 percent in two decades, it’s urgent to discuss monopolies more expansively and focus on the facts rather than political talking points.1<br><br>This paper will make the argument that monopolies are overregulated, which harms the economy and its consumers more so than it helps. Monopolies should be subject to less scrutiny in the U.S. economy to perform their functions more efficiently. Regulators have alternative means of guarding against the negative effects of monopoly while allowing for the positive effects.","PeriodicalId":11797,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Regulation (IO) (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-12-21","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"82287173","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Pricing and Compatibility in Network Goods Markets 网络商品市场的定价与兼容性
Pub Date : 2020-12-17 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3235943
T. Athanasopoulos
I examine an incumbent monopolist's pricing strategy in a two-period durable goods market for complements, such as the Operating System and software applications, and its compatibility stance with a future competitor when the market for applications is characterised by direct network effects and quality growth as well as potential switching costs. Consumers arrive in the market in the first period and the “threat” to exercise their option to postpone their purchase may lead the incumbent to charge a price for its Operating System that is lower than that of a static monopolist no matter what the compatibility regime. I also show that the incumbent may support compatibility regardless of the presence of switching costs. The welfare effects of mandatory compatibility are ambiguous.
我研究了在位垄断者在两期耐用品市场的定价策略,以补充产品,如操作系统和软件应用程序,以及当应用程序市场以直接网络效应和质量增长以及潜在转换成本为特征时,其与未来竞争对手的兼容性立场。消费者在第一阶段进入市场,而“威胁”行使他们推迟购买的选择权,可能导致在位者对其操作系统收取的价格低于静态垄断者的价格,无论兼容机制是什么。我还说明,无论是否存在转换成本,现有系统都可以支持兼容性。强制兼容性的福利效应是模糊的。
{"title":"Pricing and Compatibility in Network Goods Markets","authors":"T. Athanasopoulos","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3235943","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3235943","url":null,"abstract":"I examine an incumbent monopolist's pricing strategy in a two-period durable goods market for complements, such as the Operating System and software applications, and its compatibility stance with a future competitor when the market for applications is characterised by direct network effects and quality growth as well as potential switching costs. Consumers arrive in the market in the first period and the “threat” to exercise their option to postpone their purchase may lead the incumbent to charge a price for its Operating System that is lower than that of a static monopolist no matter what the compatibility regime. I also show that the incumbent may support compatibility regardless of the presence of switching costs. The welfare effects of mandatory compatibility are ambiguous.","PeriodicalId":11797,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Regulation (IO) (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-12-17","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"78409826","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Green Antitrust: Friendly Fire in the Fight against Climate Change 绿色反垄断:对抗气候变化中的友军火力
Pub Date : 2020-12-15 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3749147
M. Schinkel, L. Treuren
The green antitrust movement aims to increase sustainability efforts by allowing restrictions of competition. Yet the economic evidence so far points to more, not less, competition as the right stimulus for inducing sustainability efforts. Incentives to produce more sustainably are stronger when firms compete than when they are allowed to make sustainability agreements. This is also true when firms are intrinsically motivated to promote sustainability. It is not good policy to relax the general competition rules in order to accommodate the rare genuine sustainability agreement. However well-intended, green antitrust risks damaging both competition and the environment. It will suppress the gathering market forces for companies to produce more sustainably, overburden competition authorities, invite abusive cartel greenwashing, and give the part of government that should promote sustainability further excuse to shun their responsibility for designing proper regulation.
绿色反垄断运动旨在通过允许限制竞争来增加可持续发展的努力。然而,迄今为止的经济证据表明,更多(而不是更少)的竞争才是促使可持续发展努力的正确刺激因素。与允许企业签订可持续性协议相比,企业通过竞争来生产更可持续产品的动机更强。当公司有促进可持续发展的内在动机时,这也是正确的。为了适应罕见的真正的可持续性协议而放松一般竞争规则并不是一个好政策。无论意图多么美好,绿色反垄断都有可能损害竞争和环境。它将抑制促使企业生产更具可持续性产品的市场力量的聚集,使竞争监管机构负担过重,引发卡特尔滥用“洗绿”行为,并让本应促进可持续性的政府部门有更多借口逃避设计适当监管的责任。
{"title":"Green Antitrust: Friendly Fire in the Fight against Climate Change","authors":"M. Schinkel, L. Treuren","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3749147","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3749147","url":null,"abstract":"The green antitrust movement aims to increase sustainability efforts by allowing restrictions of competition. Yet the economic evidence so far points to more, not less, competition as the right stimulus for inducing sustainability efforts. Incentives to produce more sustainably are stronger when firms compete than when they are allowed to make sustainability agreements. This is also true when firms are intrinsically motivated to promote sustainability. It is not good policy to relax the general competition rules in order to accommodate the rare genuine sustainability agreement. However well-intended, green antitrust risks damaging both competition and the environment. It will suppress the gathering market forces for companies to produce more sustainably, overburden competition authorities, invite abusive cartel greenwashing, and give the part of government that should promote sustainability further excuse to shun their responsibility for designing proper regulation.","PeriodicalId":11797,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Regulation (IO) (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-12-15","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"88679948","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 12
Antitrust in Attention Markets: Definition, Power, Harm 注意力市场中的反垄断:定义、权力、危害
Pub Date : 2020-12-09 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3745839
J. Newman
Despite its vital role in the modern marketplace, attention has largely escaped the notice of the antitrust community. Existing discourse exhibits a variety of misconceptions and flawed prescriptions. One example is the widely held notion that attention markets necessitate two-sided platform analysis. Another is a marked overemphasis on data-collection practices. Yet another is that human users, viewers, and listeners are “the consumers” in these markets. And a fourth is that competition for attention occurs within one massive relevant market, obviating the possibility that any single firm could exercise market power. In light of nascent enforcement actions against Facebook, Google, and others, these defects require correction. This Article begins by explaining the basic economics of attention markets, which often involve zero-price barter transactions. It turns next to the appropriate antitrust methodology for market definition. Attention markets need not encompass two “sides”; instead, they are best understood as traditional top-down distribution systems. The oft-used SSNIP test is facially unworkable in zero-price attention markets, but the SSNIC or SSNDQ variants may offer some utility. Practical indicia will often be more useful, however, given the unwieldy nature of hypothetical-monopolist tests. Regardless of methodology, courts and enforcers should take care to avoid the “massive market” fallacy espoused by some commentators. As to market power, both market shares and direct evidence can be useful. The three most common methods for assigning shares—time on-site, active users, and advertising revenues—can each shed light on the issue. Wherever available, direct evidence on attention-cost changes and competitive responses (or lack thereof) should play a significant role. Turning to anticompetitive effects, the “attention overcharge” should be a core concern. Recent litigation efforts have framed this harm instead as “lower quality,” an approach that will often be suboptimal. Finally, competition for attention can lead to overuse, overconsumption, heightened racial and gender animus, and other societal ills. In response, courts and enforcement agencies should extend leniency to certain attention-related conduct that might initially appear harmful.
尽管它在现代市场中发挥着至关重要的作用,但人们对它的关注在很大程度上没有引起反垄断界的注意。现有的话语表现出各种各样的误解和有缺陷的处方。一个例子是,人们普遍认为注意力市场需要双边平台分析。另一个是过分强调数据收集的做法。还有一个原因是,人类用户、观众和听众都是这些市场中的“消费者”。第四点是,争夺注意力的竞争发生在一个巨大的相关市场内,这就排除了任何一家公司行使市场支配力的可能性。鉴于针对Facebook、b谷歌和其他公司的初步执法行动,这些缺陷需要纠正。本文首先解释注意力市场的基本经济学,它通常涉及零价格易货交易。接下来是市场定义的适当反垄断方法。注意力市场不需要包含两个“方面”;相反,它们最好被理解为传统的自上而下的分配系统。通常使用的SSNIP测试在零价格注意力市场上表面上是不可用的,但是SSNIC或SSNDQ变体可能提供一些实用程序。然而,考虑到假设垄断者测试的笨拙性质,实际的指标往往会更有用。无论采用何种方法,法院和执法者都应注意避免某些评论员所支持的“大规模市场”谬论。至于市场力量,市场份额和直接证据都是有用的。分配份额的三种最常见的方法——站点时间、活跃用户和广告收入——都可以解释这个问题。只要有证据,关于注意力成本变化和竞争性反应(或缺乏)的直接证据应该发挥重要作用。至于反竞争效应,“注意力过度收费”应该是一个核心问题。最近的诉讼努力将这种危害定义为“低质量”,这种方法通常是次优的。最后,争夺注意力可能导致过度使用、过度消费、加剧种族和性别敌意,以及其他社会弊病。作为回应,法院和执法机构应对某些最初可能看起来有害的与注意力有关的行为予以宽大处理。
{"title":"Antitrust in Attention Markets: Definition, Power, Harm","authors":"J. Newman","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3745839","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3745839","url":null,"abstract":"Despite its vital role in the modern marketplace, attention has largely escaped the notice of the antitrust community. Existing discourse exhibits a variety of misconceptions and flawed prescriptions. One example is the widely held notion that attention markets necessitate two-sided platform analysis. Another is a marked overemphasis on data-collection practices. Yet another is that human users, viewers, and listeners are “the consumers” in these markets. And a fourth is that competition for attention occurs within one massive relevant market, obviating the possibility that any single firm could exercise market power. In light of nascent enforcement actions against Facebook, Google, and others, these defects require correction. This Article begins by explaining the basic economics of attention markets, which often involve zero-price barter transactions. It turns next to the appropriate antitrust methodology for market definition. Attention markets need not encompass two “sides”; instead, they are best understood as traditional top-down distribution systems. The oft-used SSNIP test is facially unworkable in zero-price attention markets, but the SSNIC or SSNDQ variants may offer some utility. Practical indicia will often be more useful, however, given the unwieldy nature of hypothetical-monopolist tests. Regardless of methodology, courts and enforcers should take care to avoid the “massive market” fallacy espoused by some commentators. As to market power, both market shares and direct evidence can be useful. The three most common methods for assigning shares—time on-site, active users, and advertising revenues—can each shed light on the issue. Wherever available, direct evidence on attention-cost changes and competitive responses (or lack thereof) should play a significant role. Turning to anticompetitive effects, the “attention overcharge” should be a core concern. Recent litigation efforts have framed this harm instead as “lower quality,” an approach that will often be suboptimal. Finally, competition for attention can lead to overuse, overconsumption, heightened racial and gender animus, and other societal ills. In response, courts and enforcement agencies should extend leniency to certain attention-related conduct that might initially appear harmful.","PeriodicalId":11797,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Regulation (IO) (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-12-09","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"91209688","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
Shadow Banks and Optimal Regulation 影子银行与最优监管
Pub Date : 2020-12-02 DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3746495
C. Clayton, A. Schaab
We develop a new framework to study regulatory policy in the presence of unregulated financial institutions ("shadow banks'') when there are pecuniary externalities. Using sufficient statistics, we show that optimal regulation in the presence of shadow banks is scaled by a "regulatory arbitrage multiplier.'' This multiplier only depends on aggregate shadow banking activity. Our framework provides guidance on how to regulate currently unregulated financial institutions and sectors. To first order, the marginal welfare gain of regulating a shadow bank is large when a notion of its intermediary activity substitution effects across its activities is large. We further characterize optimal activity-based regulation whereby the planner regulates a particular activity across all shadow banks, e.g. a tax on debt. To first order, gains from activity regulation are large when average substitution effects across intermediaries are large for the regulated activity. We show how our results extend to broader classes of non-pecuniary externalities.
我们开发了一个新的框架来研究在存在货币外部性的不受监管的金融机构(“影子银行”)的情况下的监管政策。利用充分的统计数据,我们表明,在影子银行存在的情况下,最优监管是用“监管套利乘数”来衡量的。“这个乘数只取决于影子银行活动总量。我们的框架为如何监管目前不受监管的金融机构和部门提供了指导。对于第一阶,当中介活动替代效应的概念较大时,监管影子银行的边际福利收益较大。我们进一步描述了基于活动的最优监管,即计划者对所有影子银行的特定活动进行监管,例如对债务征税。对于第一阶,当中介之间的平均替代效应对于被监管的活动很大时,活动监管的收益就很大。我们展示了我们的结果如何扩展到更广泛的非货币外部性类别。
{"title":"Shadow Banks and Optimal Regulation","authors":"C. Clayton, A. Schaab","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3746495","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3746495","url":null,"abstract":"We develop a new framework to study regulatory policy in the presence of unregulated financial institutions (\"shadow banks'') when there are pecuniary externalities. Using sufficient statistics, we show that optimal regulation in the presence of shadow banks is scaled by a \"regulatory arbitrage multiplier.'' This multiplier only depends on aggregate shadow banking activity. Our framework provides guidance on how to regulate currently unregulated financial institutions and sectors. To first order, the marginal welfare gain of regulating a shadow bank is large when a notion of its intermediary activity substitution effects across its activities is large. We further characterize optimal activity-based regulation whereby the planner regulates a particular activity across all shadow banks, e.g. a tax on debt. To first order, gains from activity regulation are large when average substitution effects across intermediaries are large for the regulated activity. We show how our results extend to broader classes of non-pecuniary externalities.<br>","PeriodicalId":11797,"journal":{"name":"ERN: Regulation (IO) (Topic)","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2020-12-02","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"75044447","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":"","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
期刊
ERN: Regulation (IO) (Topic)
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1