首页 > 最新文献

Journal of Economic Perspectives最新文献

英文 中文
Retrospectives: On the Evolution of the Rules versus Discretion Debate in Monetary Policy 回顾:论货币政策规则与自由裁量权之争的演变
IF 8.4 1区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2022-08-01 DOI: 10.1257/jep.36.3.245
Harris Dellas, G. Tavlas
Episodes of macroeconomic upheaval associated with monetary policy failure have provided the stage for important debates on rules versus discretion. We discuss the main features, results, commonalities, and differences in the debates that emerged after three such episodes. The modern debate was born during the Great Inflation of the 1970s and focused on both rules versus discretion and the properties of alternative rules. The middle debate originated with Henry Simons and the Chicago School during the Great Depression in the 1930s and focuses on policy uncertainty. The earliest systematic debate involved the Currency and Banking Schools in Britain in the 1820s, but, in spite the views of many of its participants and doctrinal historians, it seems to have primarily been about the degree of activism under a single rule—that of the gold standard.
与货币政策失败相关的宏观经济动荡为关于规则与自由裁量权的重要辩论提供了舞台。我们讨论了三次这样的事件后出现的辩论的主要特点、结果、共性和差异。现代辩论诞生于20世纪70年代的大通货膨胀时期,重点关注规则与自由裁量权以及替代规则的性质。中间辩论起源于20世纪30年代大萧条时期的亨利·西蒙斯和芝加哥学派,主要关注政策的不确定性。最早的系统性辩论涉及19世纪20年代英国的货币和银行学派,但尽管许多参与者和学说历史学家都有观点,但它似乎主要是关于金本位制下的激进主义程度。
{"title":"Retrospectives: On the Evolution of the Rules versus Discretion Debate in Monetary Policy","authors":"Harris Dellas, G. Tavlas","doi":"10.1257/jep.36.3.245","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.36.3.245","url":null,"abstract":"Episodes of macroeconomic upheaval associated with monetary policy failure have provided the stage for important debates on rules versus discretion. We discuss the main features, results, commonalities, and differences in the debates that emerged after three such episodes. The modern debate was born during the Great Inflation of the 1970s and focused on both rules versus discretion and the properties of alternative rules. The middle debate originated with Henry Simons and the Chicago School during the Great Depression in the 1930s and focuses on policy uncertainty. The earliest systematic debate involved the Currency and Banking Schools in Britain in the 1820s, but, in spite the views of many of its participants and doctrinal historians, it seems to have primarily been about the degree of activism under a single rule—that of the gold standard.","PeriodicalId":15611,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economic Perspectives","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":8.4,"publicationDate":"2022-08-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"45723255","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Expected and Realized Inflation in Historical Perspective 从历史角度看预期通货膨胀和已实现通货膨胀
IF 8.4 1区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2022-08-01 DOI: 10.1257/jep.36.3.131
C. Binder, Rupal Kamdar
This paper provides historical context for the relationship between expected and realized inflation. We begin with a discussion of early theoretical thought about how inflation expectations are formed. Then, we discuss survey- and asset- based measures of inflation expectations and assess their empirical relationship with realized inflation. Expected and realized inflation are strongly correlated over long samples, but over short samples the correlations can weaken. Lastly, to better understand the subtleties of the interaction between expected and realized inflation over short-lived but important events, we provide a narrative account of the relationship during the Great Depression of the 1930s, the Great Inflation of the 1970s, the Great Recession of 2008–2009, and the recent COVID-19 pandemic. These episodes offer compelling evidence of the importance of expectations and policy regime changes in inflation dynamics.
本文为预期通货膨胀与实际通货膨胀之间的关系提供了历史背景。我们首先讨论通胀预期是如何形成的早期理论思想。然后,我们讨论了基于调查和基于资产的通胀预期指标,并评估了它们与已实现通胀的实证关系。在长样本中,预期通货膨胀和实际通货膨胀是强烈相关的,但在短样本中,相关性会减弱。最后,为了更好地理解短期但重要事件中预期通胀与实现通胀之间相互作用的微妙之处,我们对20世纪30年代的大萧条、70年代的大通胀、2008-2009年的大衰退以及最近的COVID-19大流行期间的通胀与预期通胀之间的关系进行了叙述。这些事件提供了令人信服的证据,证明预期和政策机制变化对通胀动态的重要性。
{"title":"Expected and Realized Inflation in Historical Perspective","authors":"C. Binder, Rupal Kamdar","doi":"10.1257/jep.36.3.131","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.36.3.131","url":null,"abstract":"This paper provides historical context for the relationship between expected and realized inflation. We begin with a discussion of early theoretical thought about how inflation expectations are formed. Then, we discuss survey- and asset- based measures of inflation expectations and assess their empirical relationship with realized inflation. Expected and realized inflation are strongly correlated over long samples, but over short samples the correlations can weaken. Lastly, to better understand the subtleties of the interaction between expected and realized inflation over short-lived but important events, we provide a narrative account of the relationship during the Great Depression of the 1930s, the Great Inflation of the 1970s, the Great Recession of 2008–2009, and the recent COVID-19 pandemic. These episodes offer compelling evidence of the importance of expectations and policy regime changes in inflation dynamics.","PeriodicalId":15611,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economic Perspectives","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":8.4,"publicationDate":"2022-08-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"47379337","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 5
Intangible Capital and Modern Economies 无形资本与现代经济
IF 8.4 1区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2022-08-01 DOI: 10.1257/jep.36.3.3
C. Corrado, J. Haskel, C. Jona-Lasinio, Massimiliano Iommi
The production of goods and services is central to understanding economies. The textbook description of a firm, typically in agriculture or manufacturing, focuses on its physical “tangible” capital (machines), labor (workers), and the state of “know-how. ” Yet real-world firms, such as Apple, Microsoft, and Google, have almost no physical capital. Instead, their main capital assets are “intangible”: software, data, design, reputation, supply-chain expertise, and R&D. We discuss investment in these knowledge-based types of capital: How to measure it; how it affects macroeconomic data on investment, rates of return, and GDP; and how it relates to growth theory and practical growth accounting. We present estimates of productivity in the US and European economies in recent decades including intangibles and discuss why, despite relatively rapid growth in intangible capital and what seems to be a modern technological revolution, productivity growth has slowed since the global financial crisis.
商品和服务的生产是理解经济的核心。教科书上对企业的描述,通常是在农业或制造业中,关注的是它的物理“有形”资本(机器)、劳动力(工人)和“专有技术”状态。然而,现实世界的公司,如苹果、微软和b谷歌,几乎没有实物资本。相反,他们的主要资本资产是“无形的”:软件、数据、设计、声誉、供应链专业知识和研发。我们讨论了这些以知识为基础的资本类型的投资:如何衡量;它如何影响投资、回报率和GDP等宏观经济数据;以及它与增长理论和实际增长会计的关系。我们对近几十年来美国和欧洲经济体的生产率(包括无形资产)进行了估计,并讨论了尽管无形资本增长相对较快,而且似乎发生了一场现代技术革命,但自全球金融危机以来生产率增长却有所放缓的原因。
{"title":"Intangible Capital and Modern Economies","authors":"C. Corrado, J. Haskel, C. Jona-Lasinio, Massimiliano Iommi","doi":"10.1257/jep.36.3.3","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.36.3.3","url":null,"abstract":"The production of goods and services is central to understanding economies. The textbook description of a firm, typically in agriculture or manufacturing, focuses on its physical “tangible” capital (machines), labor (workers), and the state of “know-how. ” Yet real-world firms, such as Apple, Microsoft, and Google, have almost no physical capital. Instead, their main capital assets are “intangible”: software, data, design, reputation, supply-chain expertise, and R&D. We discuss investment in these knowledge-based types of capital: How to measure it; how it affects macroeconomic data on investment, rates of return, and GDP; and how it relates to growth theory and practical growth accounting. We present estimates of productivity in the US and European economies in recent decades including intangibles and discuss why, despite relatively rapid growth in intangible capital and what seems to be a modern technological revolution, productivity growth has slowed since the global financial crisis.","PeriodicalId":15611,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economic Perspectives","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":8.4,"publicationDate":"2022-08-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"44078233","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 18
Marketing Investment and Intangible Brand Capital 营销投资与无形品牌资本
IF 8.4 1区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2022-08-01 DOI: 10.1257/jep.36.3.53
Bart J. Bronnenberg, Jean-Pierre Dubé, C. Syverson
US companies invested over $500 billion in 2021 in intangible brand capital, over 2% of GDP. During the past decade, US companies have also been growing their internal marketing capabilities, an often overlooked source of human capital. We discuss the private and social benefits of these intangible brand capital stocks. While the private returns to companies are fairly clear, the academic literature has been divided over the social benefits and costs of advertising and promotion, the two key investment vehicles. We also discuss the implications of brand capital for measured productivity.
2021年,美国企业在无形品牌资本上的投资超过5000亿美元,超过GDP的2%。过去10年,美国企业也一直在增强内部营销能力,这是一种常常被忽视的人力资本来源。我们讨论了这些无形品牌资本股票的私人和社会效益。尽管私人部门给企业带来的回报相当明显,但学术文献对广告和促销这两种关键投资工具的社会效益和成本存在分歧。我们还讨论了品牌资本对测量生产率的影响。
{"title":"Marketing Investment and Intangible Brand Capital","authors":"Bart J. Bronnenberg, Jean-Pierre Dubé, C. Syverson","doi":"10.1257/jep.36.3.53","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.36.3.53","url":null,"abstract":"US companies invested over $500 billion in 2021 in intangible brand capital, over 2% of GDP. During the past decade, US companies have also been growing their internal marketing capabilities, an often overlooked source of human capital. We discuss the private and social benefits of these intangible brand capital stocks. While the private returns to companies are fairly clear, the academic literature has been divided over the social benefits and costs of advertising and promotion, the two key investment vehicles. We also discuss the implications of brand capital for measured productivity.","PeriodicalId":15611,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economic Perspectives","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":8.4,"publicationDate":"2022-08-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"41494242","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 7
Should We Insure Workers or Jobs During Recessions? 在经济衰退期间,我们应该为工人或工作提供保险吗?
IF 8.4 1区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2022-05-01 DOI: 10.1257/jep.36.2.29
G. Giupponi, Camille Landais, Alice Lapeyre
What is the most efficient way to respond to recessions in the labor market? To this question, policymakers on the two sides of the pond gave diametrically opposed answers during the COVID-19 crisis. In the United States, the focus was on insuring workers by increasing the generosity of unemployment insurance. In Europe, instead, policies were concentrated on saving jobs, with the expansion of short-time work programs to subsidize labor hoarding. Who got it right? In this article, we show that far from being substitutes, unemployment insurance and short-time work exhibit strong complementarities. They provide insurance to different types of workers and against different types of shocks. Short-time work can be effective at reducing socially costly layoffs against large temporary shocks, but it is less effective against more persistent shocks that require reallocation across firms and sectors. We conclude that short-time work is an important addition to the labor market policy-toolkit during recessions, to be used alongside unemployment insurance.
应对劳动力市场衰退的最有效方式是什么?对于这个问题,在新冠肺炎危机期间,大西洋两岸的决策者给出了截然相反的答案。在美国,重点是通过增加失业保险的慷慨程度来为工人提供保险。相反,在欧洲,政策的重点是保住工作,扩大了短期工作计划,以补贴劳动力囤积。谁说对了?在本文中,我们发现失业保险和短期工作并不是相互替代的,而是具有很强的互补性。它们为不同类型的工人提供保险,防范不同类型的冲击。短期工作可以有效地减少社会成本高昂的裁员,以应对大规模的临时冲击,但对于需要在公司和部门之间重新分配的更持久的冲击,它的效果较差。我们的结论是,在经济衰退期间,短期工作是劳动力市场政策工具包的一个重要补充,可以与失业保险一起使用。
{"title":"Should We Insure Workers or Jobs During Recessions?","authors":"G. Giupponi, Camille Landais, Alice Lapeyre","doi":"10.1257/jep.36.2.29","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.36.2.29","url":null,"abstract":"What is the most efficient way to respond to recessions in the labor market? To this question, policymakers on the two sides of the pond gave diametrically opposed answers during the COVID-19 crisis. In the United States, the focus was on insuring workers by increasing the generosity of unemployment insurance. In Europe, instead, policies were concentrated on saving jobs, with the expansion of short-time work programs to subsidize labor hoarding. Who got it right? In this article, we show that far from being substitutes, unemployment insurance and short-time work exhibit strong complementarities. They provide insurance to different types of workers and against different types of shocks. Short-time work can be effective at reducing socially costly layoffs against large temporary shocks, but it is less effective against more persistent shocks that require reallocation across firms and sectors. We conclude that short-time work is an important addition to the labor market policy-toolkit during recessions, to be used alongside unemployment insurance.","PeriodicalId":15611,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economic Perspectives","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":8.4,"publicationDate":"2022-05-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"44661523","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 28
Retrospectives: Joan Robinson on Karl Marx: “His Sense of Reality Is Far Stronger” 回顾:琼·罗宾逊评卡尔·马克思:“他的现实感要强烈得多”
IF 8.4 1区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2022-05-01 DOI: 10.1257/jep.36.2.247
Carolina Alves
This paper revisits why Joan Robinson turned to Karl Marx in 1942 and which insights from Marxian economics she sought to incorporate into her later works, while commenting on how her encounter with Marx was received by some her of contemporaries. By the end of the 1930s, Robinson wanted to bring academic and Marxian economics together in a search for a more realist theory of the rate of profit and income distribution, along with clarifications on Keynes’s concept of full employment and the nature of technical progress and a long-period theory within the Keynesian framework. The result, An Essay on Marxian Economics (1942), was her most important work in terms of laying the foundations of her enduring challenge to the orthodox economics. Here she relied on Marxian insights to escape Marshallian orthodoxy. It is the story of how the originator of imperfect competition pushed further into a theory of exploitation.
本文回顾了琼·罗宾逊为什么在1942年转向卡尔·马克思,以及她试图将马克思经济学的哪些见解融入她后来的作品中,同时评论了她与马克思的相遇是如何被同时代的一些人所接受的。到20世纪30年代末,罗宾逊希望将学术界和马克思主义经济学结合起来,寻找一种更现实的利润率和收入分配理论,同时澄清凯恩斯的充分就业概念和技术进步的性质,以及凯恩斯框架内的长期理论。《马克思主义经济学随笔》(1942)是她最重要的作品,为她对正统经济学的持久挑战奠定了基础。在这里,她依靠马克思主义的真知灼见来逃避马歇尔式的正统观念。这是一个关于不完全竞争的创始人如何进一步推进剥削理论的故事。
{"title":"Retrospectives: Joan Robinson on Karl Marx: “His Sense of Reality Is Far Stronger”","authors":"Carolina Alves","doi":"10.1257/jep.36.2.247","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.36.2.247","url":null,"abstract":"This paper revisits why Joan Robinson turned to Karl Marx in 1942 and which insights from Marxian economics she sought to incorporate into her later works, while commenting on how her encounter with Marx was received by some her of contemporaries. By the end of the 1930s, Robinson wanted to bring academic and Marxian economics together in a search for a more realist theory of the rate of profit and income distribution, along with clarifications on Keynes’s concept of full employment and the nature of technical progress and a long-period theory within the Keynesian framework. The result, An Essay on Marxian Economics (1942), was her most important work in terms of laying the foundations of her enduring challenge to the orthodox economics. Here she relied on Marxian insights to escape Marshallian orthodoxy. It is the story of how the originator of imperfect competition pushed further into a theory of exploitation.","PeriodicalId":15611,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economic Perspectives","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":8.4,"publicationDate":"2022-05-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"44257834","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Universal Early-Life Health Policies in the Nordic Countries 北欧国家的普遍早期健康政策
IF 8.4 1区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2022-05-01 DOI: 10.1257/jep.36.2.175
Miriam Wüst
Given mounting evidence on the negative impact of early-life shocks for the wellbeing of people over the life course, a growing economics literature studies whether early-life policies have symmetric positive effects. This paper zooms in on research on this topic from the Nordic countries, where all families have access to a comprehensive set of early-life health programs, including prenatal, maternity, and well-infant care. I describe this Nordic model of universal early-life health policies and discuss the existing evidence on its causal effects from two categories of studies. First, studying the introduction of universal policies, research has documented important short- and long-run benefits for the health, education, and labor market trajectories of treated cohorts. Second, exploiting modern-day changes to policy design, research for now documents short- and medium-run impacts of universal care on primarily maternal and child health as well as parental investment behaviors. I conclude with directions for future research.
鉴于越来越多的证据表明,早期生活冲击在整个人生过程中对人们的福祉产生了负面影响,越来越多的经济学文献研究了早期生活政策是否具有对称的积极影响。本文重点介绍了北欧国家对这一主题的研究,在北欧国家,所有家庭都可以获得一套全面的早期健康计划,包括产前、产妇和良好的婴儿护理。我描述了普遍早期健康政策的北欧模式,并讨论了两类研究中关于其因果影响的现有证据。首先,在研究普遍政策的引入时,研究记录了对接受治疗的人群的健康、教育和劳动力市场轨迹的重要短期和长期益处。其次,利用现代政策设计的变化,研究目前记录了普遍护理对母婴健康以及父母投资行为的短期和中期影响。最后,我提出了未来研究的方向。
{"title":"Universal Early-Life Health Policies in the Nordic Countries","authors":"Miriam Wüst","doi":"10.1257/jep.36.2.175","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.36.2.175","url":null,"abstract":"Given mounting evidence on the negative impact of early-life shocks for the wellbeing of people over the life course, a growing economics literature studies whether early-life policies have symmetric positive effects. This paper zooms in on research on this topic from the Nordic countries, where all families have access to a comprehensive set of early-life health programs, including prenatal, maternity, and well-infant care. I describe this Nordic model of universal early-life health policies and discuss the existing evidence on its causal effects from two categories of studies. First, studying the introduction of universal policies, research has documented important short- and long-run benefits for the health, education, and labor market trajectories of treated cohorts. Second, exploiting modern-day changes to policy design, research for now documents short- and medium-run impacts of universal care on primarily maternal and child health as well as parental investment behaviors. I conclude with directions for future research.","PeriodicalId":15611,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economic Perspectives","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":8.4,"publicationDate":"2022-05-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"46601352","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4
Slavery and the Rise of the Nineteenth-Century American Economy 奴隶制与19世纪美国经济的崛起
IF 8.4 1区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2022-05-01 DOI: 10.1257/jep.36.2.123
Gavin Wright
The essay considers the claim that slavery played a leading role in the acceleration of US economic growth in the nineteenth century. Although popular among pro-slavery apologists, the proposition fails under rigorous historical scrutiny. The slave South discouraged immigration, underinvested in transportation infrastructure, and failed to educate the majority of its population. It is not even clear that the region produced more cotton than it would have under a counterfactual alternative settlement by free family farmers, on the free-state pattern. The grain of truth in recently popular narratives is that many northerners and business interests were complicit in the crime of slavery: routinely engaging in transactions with slaveholders, even promoting activities that facilitated slavery and the domestic slave trade. Complicity complicates simple historical moralism, but it is quite different from the notion that the prosperity of the nation as a whole derived from slavery in any fundamental way.
本文认为奴隶制在19世纪美国经济增长的加速中发挥了主导作用。尽管这一主张在支持奴隶制的辩护者中很受欢迎,但在严格的历史审查下失败了。蓄奴的南方不鼓励移民,在交通基础设施方面投资不足,也未能对大多数人口进行教育。甚至还不清楚该地区的棉花产量是否超过了自由家庭农民在自由国家模式下的反事实替代解决方案。最近流行的叙事中的真相是,许多北方人和商业利益集团是奴隶制犯罪的同谋:经常与奴隶主进行交易,甚至推动为奴隶制和国内奴隶贸易提供便利的活动。复杂性使简单的历史道德主义复杂化,但它与整个国家的繁荣在任何根本上都源于奴隶制的概念截然不同。
{"title":"Slavery and the Rise of the Nineteenth-Century American Economy","authors":"Gavin Wright","doi":"10.1257/jep.36.2.123","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.36.2.123","url":null,"abstract":"The essay considers the claim that slavery played a leading role in the acceleration of US economic growth in the nineteenth century. Although popular among pro-slavery apologists, the proposition fails under rigorous historical scrutiny. The slave South discouraged immigration, underinvested in transportation infrastructure, and failed to educate the majority of its population. It is not even clear that the region produced more cotton than it would have under a counterfactual alternative settlement by free family farmers, on the free-state pattern. The grain of truth in recently popular narratives is that many northerners and business interests were complicit in the crime of slavery: routinely engaging in transactions with slaveholders, even promoting activities that facilitated slavery and the domestic slave trade. Complicity complicates simple historical moralism, but it is quite different from the notion that the prosperity of the nation as a whole derived from slavery in any fundamental way.","PeriodicalId":15611,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economic Perspectives","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":8.4,"publicationDate":"2022-05-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"46499504","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6
The Cumulative Costs of Racism and the Bill for Black Reparations 种族主义的累积成本与黑人赔偿法案
IF 8.4 1区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2022-05-01 DOI: 10.1257/jep.36.2.99
W. Darity, A. Mullen, Marvin Slaughter
Two major procedures for establishing the monetary value of a plan for reparations for Black American descendants of US slavery are considered in this paper: 1) Enumeration of atrocities and assignment of a dollar value to each as a prelude to adding up the total, and 2) Identification of a summary measure that captures the dollar amount of the cumulative, intergenerational effects of anti-Black atrocities. Under the first approach, the itemization strategy, we assess wage costs to the enslaved of bondage; financial gains to the perpetrators of slavery; damages to Black victims of post-Civil War white massacres and lynchings; losses from discrimination in the provision of the home buying supports from the Federal Housing Administration and the G.I. Bill; and income penalties due to racial discrimination in employment. Under the second approach, the global indicator strategy, we calculate the present value of providing 40 acres of land to freed slaves in 1865 and the current wealth gap between Black and White Americans. We conclude that the latter standard, the racial wealth gap, provides the best gauge for the size of the bill for Black reparations.
本文考虑了为美国奴隶制的美国黑人后裔制定赔偿计划的货币价值的两个主要程序:1)列举暴行并为每一暴行分配一美元价值,作为总数相加的前奏,反黑人暴行的代际影响。在第一种方法,逐项分析策略下,我们评估被奴役者的工资成本;奴役罪犯的经济利益;对内战后白人大屠杀和私刑的黑人受害者的损害;联邦住房管理局和G.I.法案在提供购房支持方面的歧视造成的损失;以及因就业中的种族歧视而受到的收入惩罚。根据第二种方法,即全球指标战略,我们计算了1865年向自由奴隶提供40英亩土地的现值,以及当前美国黑人和白人之间的贫富差距。我们得出的结论是,后一种标准,即种族财富差距,为黑人赔偿法案的规模提供了最佳衡量标准。
{"title":"The Cumulative Costs of Racism and the Bill for Black Reparations","authors":"W. Darity, A. Mullen, Marvin Slaughter","doi":"10.1257/jep.36.2.99","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.36.2.99","url":null,"abstract":"Two major procedures for establishing the monetary value of a plan for reparations for Black American descendants of US slavery are considered in this paper: 1) Enumeration of atrocities and assignment of a dollar value to each as a prelude to adding up the total, and 2) Identification of a summary measure that captures the dollar amount of the cumulative, intergenerational effects of anti-Black atrocities. Under the first approach, the itemization strategy, we assess wage costs to the enslaved of bondage; financial gains to the perpetrators of slavery; damages to Black victims of post-Civil War white massacres and lynchings; losses from discrimination in the provision of the home buying supports from the Federal Housing Administration and the G.I. Bill; and income penalties due to racial discrimination in employment. Under the second approach, the global indicator strategy, we calculate the present value of providing 40 acres of land to freed slaves in 1865 and the current wealth gap between Black and White Americans. We conclude that the latter standard, the racial wealth gap, provides the best gauge for the size of the bill for Black reparations.","PeriodicalId":15611,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economic Perspectives","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":8.4,"publicationDate":"2022-05-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"46414312","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 13
American Enslavement and the Recovery of Black Economic History 美国奴役与黑人经济史的复苏
IF 8.4 1区 经济学 Q1 Economics, Econometrics and Finance Pub Date : 2022-05-01 DOI: 10.1257/jep.36.2.81
Trevon Logan
This paper reconsiders the evidence needed to answer pressing questions of economic history and racial inequality, the Third Phase of research on American Enslavement and its Aftermath. First, I briefly summarize how economists have sought to understand slavery as an institution. Second, using my family’s narrative as a lens, I show how answers to questions from economic history and economic theory can be answered by expanding our evidentiary base and methodological approaches. In the process, I highlight some areas of what these “traditional” economic perspectives miss. Finally, I briefly provide some examples from other fields—such as recent work by historians—that have sought to provide texture on some of the key dimensions of slavery and racial inequality that have been under-studied by economists.
本文重新考虑了回答经济史和种族不平等、美国奴役及其后果研究的第三阶段等紧迫问题所需的证据。首先,我简要总结了经济学家如何试图将奴隶制理解为一种制度。其次,我以我家人的叙述为视角,展示了如何通过扩大我们的证据基础和方法论来回答经济史和经济理论中的问题。在这个过程中,我强调了这些“传统”经济观点所遗漏的一些领域。最后,我简要地提供了其他领域的一些例子,比如历史学家最近的工作,这些例子试图为经济学家研究不足的奴隶制和种族不平等的一些关键方面提供线索。
{"title":"American Enslavement and the Recovery of Black Economic History","authors":"Trevon Logan","doi":"10.1257/jep.36.2.81","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.36.2.81","url":null,"abstract":"This paper reconsiders the evidence needed to answer pressing questions of economic history and racial inequality, the Third Phase of research on American Enslavement and its Aftermath. First, I briefly summarize how economists have sought to understand slavery as an institution. Second, using my family’s narrative as a lens, I show how answers to questions from economic history and economic theory can be answered by expanding our evidentiary base and methodological approaches. In the process, I highlight some areas of what these “traditional” economic perspectives miss. Finally, I briefly provide some examples from other fields—such as recent work by historians—that have sought to provide texture on some of the key dimensions of slavery and racial inequality that have been under-studied by economists.","PeriodicalId":15611,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Economic Perspectives","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":8.4,"publicationDate":"2022-05-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"41649960","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 7
期刊
Journal of Economic Perspectives
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1