This paper contributes to the literature by quantifying the effects of supply shortages on inflation in 19 European economies. In contrast to many other papers, it focuses on factual country-specific shortages in materials and equipment reported by enterprises in the business surveys conducted by the European Commission rather than supply chain tensions that are measured only globally or for some major economies. We apply the local projections method in a panel framework, and estimate the responses of nine measures of consumer and producer inflation to supply shortages. We find that supply shortages are inflationary for all considered measures of inflation, and a larger effect can be observed for the inflation of prices of goods rather than services. The peak of impulse responses can be observed 4–6 quarters after a shock, while the effect usually dies out after 8–12 quarters. After a year, a one-standard-deviation shock in supply shortages is followed by annual inflation being higher by 0.7–3.4 percentage points, depending on the inflation measure. Interestingly, the inflationary effects of supply shortages seem to be related mainly to periods of intense global supply tensions.
{"title":"Supply shortages and inflation in Europe","authors":"Jakub Mućk, Łukasz Postek","doi":"10.1111/ecca.12573","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/ecca.12573","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This paper contributes to the literature by quantifying the effects of supply shortages on inflation in 19 European economies. In contrast to many other papers, it focuses on factual country-specific shortages in materials and equipment reported by enterprises in the business surveys conducted by the European Commission rather than supply chain tensions that are measured only globally or for some major economies. We apply the local projections method in a panel framework, and estimate the responses of nine measures of consumer and producer inflation to supply shortages. We find that supply shortages are inflationary for all considered measures of inflation, and a larger effect can be observed for the inflation of prices of goods rather than services. The peak of impulse responses can be observed 4–6 quarters after a shock, while the effect usually dies out after 8–12 quarters. After a year, a one-standard-deviation shock in supply shortages is followed by annual inflation being higher by 0.7–3.4 percentage points, depending on the inflation measure. Interestingly, the inflationary effects of supply shortages seem to be related mainly to periods of intense global supply tensions.</p>","PeriodicalId":48040,"journal":{"name":"Economica","volume":"92 366","pages":"420-456"},"PeriodicalIF":1.6,"publicationDate":"2025-02-21","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"143554968","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
In the aftermath of the Great Recession, hiring credits have become popular worldwide. The empirical literature shows positive but moderate effects of such interventions on employment. However, an in-depth analysis of the characteristics of the beneficiary firms and their wage-setting policies is still lacking. By using a linked employer–employee dataset, this paper presents a firm-level analysis of a three-year employer-borne payroll tax cut for permanent hirings introduced in Italy in 2015. After estimating firm and worker fixed effects through the standard AKM model, we show that the take-up of hiring credits is significantly higher for firms that pay lower wages, are less productive, employ workers with lower mean abilities, and have a lower retention rate. This result is robust to several specifications and stratifications of the sample, and provides a further and different perspective from which to question the use of active labour market policies based on employer-borne payroll tax cuts.
{"title":"Cui prodest? A firm-level analysis of hiring credits","authors":"Edoardo Santoni, Fabrizio Patriarca, Margherita Scarlato","doi":"10.1111/ecca.12572","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/ecca.12572","url":null,"abstract":"<p>In the aftermath of the Great Recession, hiring credits have become popular worldwide. The empirical literature shows positive but moderate effects of such interventions on employment. However, an in-depth analysis of the characteristics of the beneficiary firms and their wage-setting policies is still lacking. By using a linked employer–employee dataset, this paper presents a firm-level analysis of a three-year employer-borne payroll tax cut for permanent hirings introduced in Italy in 2015. After estimating firm and worker fixed effects through the standard AKM model, we show that the take-up of hiring credits is significantly higher for firms that pay lower wages, are less productive, employ workers with lower mean abilities, and have a lower retention rate. This result is robust to several specifications and stratifications of the sample, and provides a further and different perspective from which to question the use of active labour market policies based on employer-borne payroll tax cuts.</p>","PeriodicalId":48040,"journal":{"name":"Economica","volume":"92 366","pages":"580-613"},"PeriodicalIF":1.6,"publicationDate":"2025-02-07","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/ecca.12572","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"143555084","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
The objective of the Federal Reserve (the Fed), namely, its dovish stance, is often blamed for the so-called Great Inflation. A popular proxy for the Fed's dovish stance is constructed using the inflation coefficients in estimated Taylor rules. However, for a welfare-optimizing central bank, the estimated Taylor coefficients are not sufficient for inferring its underlying preference. We quantify the Fed's objective—the targeting rule—relying on a conditional estimator that is free of the classical simultaneity problem. We discover that the Fed's targeting rule remained stable during the pre- and post-Volcker periods—the opposite of what is implied through a Taylor rule estimation.
{"title":"Quantifying the Federal Reserve's objectives using a structural vector autoregressive model","authors":"Shengliang Ou, Donghai Zhang","doi":"10.1111/ecca.12571","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/ecca.12571","url":null,"abstract":"<p>The objective of the Federal Reserve (the Fed), namely, its dovish stance, is often blamed for the so-called Great Inflation. A popular proxy for the Fed's dovish stance is constructed using the inflation coefficients in estimated Taylor rules. However, for a welfare-optimizing central bank, the estimated Taylor coefficients are not sufficient for inferring its underlying preference. We quantify the Fed's objective—the targeting rule—relying on a conditional estimator that is free of the classical simultaneity problem. We discover that the Fed's targeting rule remained stable during the pre- and post-Volcker periods—the opposite of what is implied through a Taylor rule estimation.</p>","PeriodicalId":48040,"journal":{"name":"Economica","volume":"92 366","pages":"351-367"},"PeriodicalIF":1.6,"publicationDate":"2025-02-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/ecca.12571","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"143554198","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
This paper evaluates the effects of the Hungarian disability employment quota, which requires firms over a size threshold to employ individuals with disabilities or pay a non-compliance tax. In 2010, the tax was raised from very low levels to 170% of the minimum wage cost associated with meeting the quota. We employ a regression discontinuity design on firm-level data to estimate the effects of the policy and provide a lower-bound estimate to account for the potential bias resulting from firms bunching below the threshold. Firms respond to the quota by hiring 0.24–0.29 additional workers with disabilities, with a lower bound estimate of 0.12–0.17. However, about two-thirds of the quota is not fulfilled, which is puzzling as the tax is higher than the minimum wage cost of a worker with disabilities. Our model shows that high hiring costs associated with employing individuals with disabilities might be an important factor behind this anomaly. We test this hypothesis by showing that the effect is weaker in regions with a low share of individuals with disabilities, implying that without adequate policies targeting the removal of supply-side barriers to the employment of people with disabilities, even strong demand-side financial incentives cannot achieve their goals.
{"title":"The effects of a disability employment quota when compliance is cheaper than defiance","authors":"Judit Krekó, Álmos Telegdy","doi":"10.1111/ecca.12568","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/ecca.12568","url":null,"abstract":"<p>This paper evaluates the effects of the Hungarian disability employment quota, which requires firms over a size threshold to employ individuals with disabilities or pay a non-compliance tax. In 2010, the tax was raised from very low levels to 170% of the minimum wage cost associated with meeting the quota. We employ a regression discontinuity design on firm-level data to estimate the effects of the policy and provide a lower-bound estimate to account for the potential bias resulting from firms bunching below the threshold. Firms respond to the quota by hiring 0.24–0.29 additional workers with disabilities, with a lower bound estimate of 0.12–0.17. However, about two-thirds of the quota is not fulfilled, which is puzzling as the tax is higher than the minimum wage cost of a worker with disabilities. Our model shows that high hiring costs associated with employing individuals with disabilities might be an important factor behind this anomaly. We test this hypothesis by showing that the effect is weaker in regions with a low share of individuals with disabilities, implying that without adequate policies targeting the removal of supply-side barriers to the employment of people with disabilities, even strong demand-side financial incentives cannot achieve their goals.</p>","PeriodicalId":48040,"journal":{"name":"Economica","volume":"92 366","pages":"614-643"},"PeriodicalIF":1.6,"publicationDate":"2025-01-24","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"143554990","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
Digitalization has an impact on many vested businesses, decreasing marginal costs and increasing informed customers, among other things. However, measuring the impact of digitalization remains difficult. Betting markets provide a clean setting to estimate the price impact of digitalization, as products are homogeneous and it is easy to measure pricing behaviour. Consistent with mixed strategy models under imperfect information, we show that between 2000 and 2023, transaction costs for gamblers dropped by over 60%, although transaction-cost dispersion persists. Furthermore, we also find that betting markets became more informationally efficient over this period, with a significant decrease in the favourite–longshot bias.
{"title":"How digitalization can shape markets: the case of sports betting","authors":"Jonas Vandenbruaene, Jan Annaert, Marc De Ceuster","doi":"10.1111/ecca.12570","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/ecca.12570","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Digitalization has an impact on many vested businesses, decreasing marginal costs and increasing informed customers, among other things. However, measuring the impact of digitalization remains difficult. Betting markets provide a clean setting to estimate the price impact of digitalization, as products are homogeneous and it is easy to measure pricing behaviour. Consistent with mixed strategy models under imperfect information, we show that between 2000 and 2023, transaction costs for gamblers dropped by over 60%, although transaction-cost dispersion persists. Furthermore, we also find that betting markets became more informationally efficient over this period, with a significant decrease in the favourite–longshot bias.</p>","PeriodicalId":48040,"journal":{"name":"Economica","volume":"92 366","pages":"644-673"},"PeriodicalIF":1.6,"publicationDate":"2025-01-24","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"143554991","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
Using firm-level data from the manufacturing sector in China, I document that zombie firms are larger and less productive, and receive higher subsidy rates on average. The difference in subsidy rates between zombies and non-zombies reflects both the selection criteria of zombies and the underlying joint distribution of subsidy rate and productivity. I develop a model with heterogeneous firms to quantify the impact of zombies on aggregate productivity. Quantitative exercises show that while both policies—reducing subsidy dispersion and facilitating zombie exits—effectively reduce the zombie rate, the former yields greater productivity gains.
{"title":"Zombie firms, state subsidies and aggregate productivity","authors":"Xijie Gao","doi":"10.1111/ecca.12569","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/ecca.12569","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Using firm-level data from the manufacturing sector in China, I document that zombie firms are larger and less productive, and receive higher subsidy rates on average. The difference in subsidy rates between zombies and non-zombies reflects both the selection criteria of zombies and the underlying joint distribution of subsidy rate and productivity. I develop a model with heterogeneous firms to quantify the impact of zombies on aggregate productivity. Quantitative exercises show that while both policies—reducing subsidy dispersion and facilitating zombie exits—effectively reduce the zombie rate, the former yields greater productivity gains.</p>","PeriodicalId":48040,"journal":{"name":"Economica","volume":"92 366","pages":"507-547"},"PeriodicalIF":1.6,"publicationDate":"2025-01-21","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"143554969","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
In the post-pandemic period, there was substantial cross-country heterogeneity in energy prices faced by consumers, due to variation in countries' energy mixes, as well as variation in government energy subsidy policies. The main contribution of this paper is to exploit this country-level variation to show that countries with higher domestic energy prices faced higher subsequent core inflation. Core inflation rises gradually after an energy shock, for a little over a year, before falling back to the pre-shock rate of inflation. We argue that in the aftermath of large energy price shocks, core inflation is not a reliable measure of underlying or persistent inflation, and should be adjusted for the predicted, country-specific, energy cost pass-through. Focusing more narrowly on services inflation rather than core inflation does not solve the problem, as services inflation responds similarly, in both magnitude and duration, to energy price shocks.
{"title":"Core strength: international evidence on the impact of energy prices on core inflation","authors":"Gertjan Vlieghe","doi":"10.1111/ecca.12565","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/ecca.12565","url":null,"abstract":"<p>In the post-pandemic period, there was substantial cross-country heterogeneity in energy prices faced by consumers, due to variation in countries' energy mixes, as well as variation in government energy subsidy policies. The main contribution of this paper is to exploit this country-level variation to show that countries with higher domestic energy prices faced higher subsequent core inflation. Core inflation rises gradually after an energy shock, for a little over a year, before falling back to the pre-shock rate of inflation. We argue that in the aftermath of large energy price shocks, core inflation is not a reliable measure of underlying or persistent inflation, and should be adjusted for the predicted, country-specific, energy cost pass-through. Focusing more narrowly on services inflation rather than core inflation does not solve the problem, as services inflation responds similarly, in both magnitude and duration, to energy price shocks.</p>","PeriodicalId":48040,"journal":{"name":"Economica","volume":"92 366","pages":"406-419"},"PeriodicalIF":1.6,"publicationDate":"2025-01-14","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"143554957","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
Governments have increasing access to individual information, but they exploit little of it when setting taxes. This paper shows how to reveal inequality aversion from observed tax policy choices of such governments. First, I map governments' priorities into concerns for vertical and horizontal equity. While vertical equity underlies inequality aversion, horizontal equity introduces a restriction against tax discrimination. This restriction affects the measurement of inequality aversion. Second, I apply the model to a hypothetical gender tax using Norwegian tax return data. The main result is that inequality aversion is overestimated when horizontal equity is ignored.
{"title":"Revealing inequality aversion from tax policy and the role of non-discrimination","authors":"Kristoffer Berg","doi":"10.1111/ecca.12567","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1111/ecca.12567","url":null,"abstract":"<p>Governments have increasing access to individual information, but they exploit little of it when setting taxes. This paper shows how to reveal inequality aversion from observed tax policy choices of such governments. First, I map governments' priorities into concerns for vertical and horizontal equity. While vertical equity underlies inequality aversion, horizontal equity introduces a restriction against tax discrimination. This restriction affects the measurement of inequality aversion. Second, I apply the model to a hypothetical gender tax using Norwegian tax return data. The main result is that inequality aversion is overestimated when horizontal equity is ignored.</p>","PeriodicalId":48040,"journal":{"name":"Economica","volume":"92 366","pages":"483-506"},"PeriodicalIF":1.6,"publicationDate":"2025-01-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/ecca.12567","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"143554562","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}