首页 > 最新文献

Nber Macroeconomics Annual最新文献

英文 中文
Accounting for Factorless Income 核算无因素收入
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2019-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/700894
Loukas Karabarbounis, Brent Neiman
Comparing US gross domestic product to the sum of measured payments to labor and imputed rental payments to capital results in a large and volatile residual or “factorless” income. We analyze three common strategies of allocating and interpreting factorless income, specifically that it arises from economic profits (case Π), unmeasured capital (case K), or deviations of the rental rate of capital from standard measures based on bond returns (case R). We are skeptical of case Π because it reveals a tight negative relationship between real interest rates and economic profits, leads to large fluctuations in inferred factor-augmenting technologies, and results in profits that have risen since the early 1980s but that remain lower today than in the 1960s and 1970s. Case K shows how unmeasured capital plausibly accounts for all factorless income in recent decades, but its value in the 1960s would have to be more than half of the capital stock, which we find less plausible. We view case R as most promising as it leads to more stable factor shares and technology growth than the other cases, though we acknowledge that it requires an explanation for the pattern of deviations from common measures of the rental rate. Using a model with multiple sectors and types of capital, we show that our assessment of the drivers of changes in output, factor shares, and functional inequality depends critically on the interpretation of factorless income.
将美国国内生产总值(gdp)与对劳动力的实际支付和对资本的估算租金支付的总和进行比较,会得出一个巨大而不稳定的剩余收入或“无因素”收入。我们分析了分配和解释无因素收入的三种常见策略,特别是它源于经济利润(案例Π),未测量的资本(案例K),或基于债券回报的标准衡量的资本租金率的偏差(案例R)。我们对案例Π持怀疑态度,因为它揭示了实际利率与经济利润之间的紧密负相关关系,导致推断的因素增强技术的大幅波动。自20世纪80年代初以来,利润一直在上升,但今天的利润仍低于20世纪60年代和70年代。案例K表明,未测量的资本如何合理地解释了近几十年来所有不考虑因素的收入,但在20世纪60年代,其价值必须超过资本存量的一半,我们发现这一点不太合理。我们认为情况R是最有希望的,因为它比其他情况导致更稳定的要素份额和技术增长,尽管我们承认它需要解释偏离租金的常见措施的模式。通过使用包含多个部门和资本类型的模型,我们发现我们对产出、要素份额和功能不平等变化驱动因素的评估主要取决于对无要素收入的解释。
{"title":"Accounting for Factorless Income","authors":"Loukas Karabarbounis, Brent Neiman","doi":"10.1086/700894","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/700894","url":null,"abstract":"Comparing US gross domestic product to the sum of measured payments to labor and imputed rental payments to capital results in a large and volatile residual or “factorless” income. We analyze three common strategies of allocating and interpreting factorless income, specifically that it arises from economic profits (case Π), unmeasured capital (case K), or deviations of the rental rate of capital from standard measures based on bond returns (case R). We are skeptical of case Π because it reveals a tight negative relationship between real interest rates and economic profits, leads to large fluctuations in inferred factor-augmenting technologies, and results in profits that have risen since the early 1980s but that remain lower today than in the 1960s and 1970s. Case K shows how unmeasured capital plausibly accounts for all factorless income in recent decades, but its value in the 1960s would have to be more than half of the capital stock, which we find less plausible. We view case R as most promising as it leads to more stable factor shares and technology growth than the other cases, though we acknowledge that it requires an explanation for the pattern of deviations from common measures of the rental rate. Using a model with multiple sectors and types of capital, we show that our assessment of the drivers of changes in output, factor shares, and functional inequality depends critically on the interpretation of factorless income.","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"61 10","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2019-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"138495556","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 138
Discussion 讨论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2019-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/700912
The authors opened the discussion by thanking Richard Rogerson and MatthewRognlie for their comments. They expressed their appreciation for Rognlie’s effort to frame their paper in the context of the literature. The authors also shared his skepticism about the implications of caseP. AndrewAtkeson spoke next and pointed out that the ratio of after-tax net operating surplus to the capital stock for nonfinancial corporations has remained roughly constant since the 1960s, fluctuating between 6% and 8%. In support of this statement, Atkeson cited figures from the Bureau of Economic Analysis’s annual report on the “Returns for Domestic Nonfinancial Business.” Atkeson argued that the literature has mostly focused on decomposing this series into various components: the return on observed and unobserved physical capital, the return on intangible capital, and monopoly markups. In his view, the relevant source of variation in factorless income is government bond yields. Atkeson noted that a balanced growth model, where the return on capital is stochastic and has a mean of roughly 7%, would be consistent with the empirical evidence on the behavior of after-tax net operating surplus. In this model, the net operating surplus is entirely attributed to the return on physical capital. The authors responded that case R in their paper focuses precisely on the role of bond yields. Although Atkeson’s neoclassical benchmark implies zero profits, the authors mentioned that there is no consensus about the importance of profits and their evolution over time. In addition, there has been growing interest recently in the evolution of markups over the past few decades. The authors noted that when profits are not zero, the counterpart to Atkeson’s measure of profits corresponds to the return on capital (R) plus firms’ profits divided by the capital stock (P/K).
作者首先感谢Richard Rogerson和matthew wrognlie的评论。他们对Rognlie在文献背景下构建论文的努力表示赞赏。作者也分享了他对caseP的影响的怀疑。安德鲁·沃特克森接着发言,他指出,自20世纪60年代以来,非金融企业税后净营业盈余与股本的比率基本保持不变,在6%至8%之间波动。为了支持这一说法,Atkeson引用了经济分析局关于“国内非金融业务回报”的年度报告中的数据。Atkeson认为,文献主要集中在将这一系列分解为各种组成部分:观察到的和未观察到的实物资本的回报,无形资本的回报,以及垄断加价。在他看来,无因素收入变化的相关来源是政府债券收益率。Atkeson指出,平衡增长模型(资本回报率是随机的,平均约为7%)将与税后净经营盈余行为的经验证据相一致。在这个模型中,净营业盈余完全归因于实物资本的回报。作者回应说,他们论文中的案例R恰恰关注的是债券收益率的作用。尽管阿特克森的新古典主义基准意味着零利润,但作者提到,对利润的重要性及其随时间的演变并没有达成共识。此外,最近人们对过去几十年加价的演变越来越感兴趣。作者指出,当利润不为零时,与阿特克森的利润衡量标准对应的是资本回报率(R)加上公司利润除以资本存量(P/K)。
{"title":"Discussion","authors":"","doi":"10.1086/700912","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/700912","url":null,"abstract":"The authors opened the discussion by thanking Richard Rogerson and MatthewRognlie for their comments. They expressed their appreciation for Rognlie’s effort to frame their paper in the context of the literature. The authors also shared his skepticism about the implications of caseP. AndrewAtkeson spoke next and pointed out that the ratio of after-tax net operating surplus to the capital stock for nonfinancial corporations has remained roughly constant since the 1960s, fluctuating between 6% and 8%. In support of this statement, Atkeson cited figures from the Bureau of Economic Analysis’s annual report on the “Returns for Domestic Nonfinancial Business.” Atkeson argued that the literature has mostly focused on decomposing this series into various components: the return on observed and unobserved physical capital, the return on intangible capital, and monopoly markups. In his view, the relevant source of variation in factorless income is government bond yields. Atkeson noted that a balanced growth model, where the return on capital is stochastic and has a mean of roughly 7%, would be consistent with the empirical evidence on the behavior of after-tax net operating surplus. In this model, the net operating surplus is entirely attributed to the return on physical capital. The authors responded that case R in their paper focuses precisely on the role of bond yields. Although Atkeson’s neoclassical benchmark implies zero profits, the authors mentioned that there is no consensus about the importance of profits and their evolution over time. In addition, there has been growing interest recently in the evolution of markups over the past few decades. The authors noted that when profits are not zero, the counterpart to Atkeson’s measure of profits corresponds to the return on capital (R) plus firms’ profits divided by the capital stock (P/K).","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"33 1","pages":"249 - 251"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2019-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/700912","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"43423637","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Comment 评论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2019-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/700898
Jennifer La'O
In most macroeconomic models, time is infinite. Agents are endowed with rational expectations including the cognitive ability to solve complex infinite-horizon planning problems. This is a heroic assumption; but when does it matter? In “Monetary Policy Analysis When Planning Horizons Are Finite,” Michael Woodford reconsiders this unrealistic feature, introduces a novel bounded-rationality framework to address it, and explores under what circumstances this affects the policy conclusions of the standard New Keynesian paradigm. Woodford develops a new cognitive framework in which agents transform their infinite-horizon problem into a sequence of simpler, finite-horizon ones. The solution method used by the agent is to backward induct over a finite set of periods given some perceived value function he has assigned to his perceived terminal nodes. This solution method seems quite natural; in fact, Woodford is motivated by a beautiful analogy to how state-of-the-art artificial intelligence (AI) programs play the games of chess or go. Take chess—a gamewith a finite strategy space and thereby in theory solvable via backward induction. In practice, however, the space of strategies is so large that solving the game in this fashion would require unfathomableprocessing power. Consider then themost effectiveAI programs. A typical decision-making process may be described as follows: at each turn, the machine looks forward at all possible moves for both itself and its opponent a finite number of turns, thereby creating a decision tree with finite nodes. It assigns a value to each of the different possible terminal nodes; these values may be based on past experience or data. Finally, given these terminal node values, the machine backward
在大多数宏观经济模型中,时间是无限的。代理人被赋予了理性的期望,包括解决复杂的无限地平线规划问题的认知能力。这是一个英勇的假设;但什么时候重要呢?在《规划视野有限时的货币政策分析》一书中,Michael Woodford重新考虑了这一不切实际的特征,引入了一个新颖的有限理性框架来解决这一问题,并探讨了在什么情况下这会影响标准新凯恩斯主义范式的政策结论。Woodford开发了一个新的认知框架,在这个框架中,代理人将他们的无限视界问题转化为一系列更简单、有限视界问题。代理使用的解决方法是在给定他分配给他感知的终端节点的一些感知值函数的情况下,在有限的一组周期上进行后向归纳。这种解决方法似乎很自然;事实上,伍德福德的动机是一个美丽的类比,即最先进的人工智能(AI)程序是如何玩国际象棋或围棋的。以国际象棋为例,这是一种策略空间有限的游戏,因此在理论上可以通过向后归纳来解决。然而,在实践中,策略的空间如此之大,以这种方式解决游戏需要深不可测的处理能力。然后考虑最有效的AI程序。一个典型的决策过程可以描述如下:在每一个转弯处,机器都会向前看自己和对手的所有可能动作——有限的转弯次数,从而创建一个具有有限节点的决策树。它为每个不同的可能的终端节点分配一个值;这些值可以基于过去的经验或数据。最后,给定这些终端节点值,机器向后
{"title":"Comment","authors":"Jennifer La'O","doi":"10.1086/700898","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/700898","url":null,"abstract":"In most macroeconomic models, time is infinite. Agents are endowed with rational expectations including the cognitive ability to solve complex infinite-horizon planning problems. This is a heroic assumption; but when does it matter? In “Monetary Policy Analysis When Planning Horizons Are Finite,” Michael Woodford reconsiders this unrealistic feature, introduces a novel bounded-rationality framework to address it, and explores under what circumstances this affects the policy conclusions of the standard New Keynesian paradigm. Woodford develops a new cognitive framework in which agents transform their infinite-horizon problem into a sequence of simpler, finite-horizon ones. The solution method used by the agent is to backward induct over a finite set of periods given some perceived value function he has assigned to his perceived terminal nodes. This solution method seems quite natural; in fact, Woodford is motivated by a beautiful analogy to how state-of-the-art artificial intelligence (AI) programs play the games of chess or go. Take chess—a gamewith a finite strategy space and thereby in theory solvable via backward induction. In practice, however, the space of strategies is so large that solving the game in this fashion would require unfathomableprocessing power. Consider then themost effectiveAI programs. A typical decision-making process may be described as follows: at each turn, the machine looks forward at all possible moves for both itself and its opponent a finite number of turns, thereby creating a decision tree with finite nodes. It assigns a value to each of the different possible terminal nodes; these values may be based on past experience or data. Finally, given these terminal node values, the machine backward","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"33 1","pages":"51 - 66"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2019-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/700898","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"43488525","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Copyright 版权
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2019-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/704584
{"title":"Copyright","authors":"","doi":"10.1086/704584","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/704584","url":null,"abstract":"","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"1 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2019-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/704584","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"44268222","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Comment 评论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2019-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/700899
G. Lorenzoni
“Monetary Policy Analysis When Planning Horizons Are Finite” byMichael Woodford fits in a fast-growing literature that attempts to introduce forms of bounded rationality in macroeconomic models. Bounded rationality can be introduced in a variety ofways, depending on howwe describe the agents’ limited ability to process information, to form forecasts, and to compute optimal plans. The paper I am discussing captures bounded rationality by giving agents a finite planning horizon and exploring in depth a variety of consequences of this modeling assumption. The paper provides a nice motivation for the exercise by connecting the macro literature to existing work in artificial intelligence. In this discussion I want tomake two points, one on the role of general equilibrium effects and one on difference between finite lives and finite planning horizons. There is one dimension of bounded rationality that appears in different forms in a variety of models: the limited capacity of agents to think through general equilibrium effects in their environment. My first point is that this limited capacity for general equilibrium thinking also plays an important role in this paper. To make this point, let me use a simple example of the “forward guidance puzzle” (Del Negro, Giannoni, and Patterson 2012), inspired by Farhi and Werning (2017). Take an infinitely lived consumer, with standard time-separable preferences, who receives a deterministic stream of labor income {Yt} and has access to a single bond that pays the real interest rate rt. The optimal behavior of this consumer can be derived from the Euler equation
迈克尔·伍德福德(Michael Woodford)的《规划视野有限时的货币政策分析》(Monetary Policy Analysis When Planning Horizons Are Finite)符合一篇快速增长的文献,该文献试图在宏观经济模型中引入有限理性的形式。有限理性可以通过多种方式引入,这取决于我们如何描述代理处理信息、形成预测和计算最优计划的有限能力。我正在讨论的这篇论文通过给代理人一个有限的规划范围来捕捉有限理性,并深入探讨这种建模假设的各种后果。本文通过将宏观文献与人工智能领域的现有工作联系起来,为这项工作提供了很好的动机。在这次讨论中,我想指出两点,一点是关于一般均衡效应的作用,另一点是有限寿命和有限规划范围之间的区别。有一个维度的有限理性以不同的形式出现在各种模型中:主体通过其环境中的一般均衡效应进行思考的能力有限。我的第一点是,这种有限的一般均衡思维能力在本文中也起着重要作用。为了说明这一点,让我举一个受Farhi和Werning(2017)启发的“前向引导谜题”(Del Negro、Giannoni和Patterson,2012)的简单例子。以一个具有标准时间可分离偏好的无限寿命消费者为例,他获得了确定的劳动力收入流{Yt},并有权获得支付实际利率rt的单一债券。该消费者的最佳行为可以从欧拉方程中得出
{"title":"Comment","authors":"G. Lorenzoni","doi":"10.1086/700899","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/700899","url":null,"abstract":"“Monetary Policy Analysis When Planning Horizons Are Finite” byMichael Woodford fits in a fast-growing literature that attempts to introduce forms of bounded rationality in macroeconomic models. Bounded rationality can be introduced in a variety ofways, depending on howwe describe the agents’ limited ability to process information, to form forecasts, and to compute optimal plans. The paper I am discussing captures bounded rationality by giving agents a finite planning horizon and exploring in depth a variety of consequences of this modeling assumption. The paper provides a nice motivation for the exercise by connecting the macro literature to existing work in artificial intelligence. In this discussion I want tomake two points, one on the role of general equilibrium effects and one on difference between finite lives and finite planning horizons. There is one dimension of bounded rationality that appears in different forms in a variety of models: the limited capacity of agents to think through general equilibrium effects in their environment. My first point is that this limited capacity for general equilibrium thinking also plays an important role in this paper. To make this point, let me use a simple example of the “forward guidance puzzle” (Del Negro, Giannoni, and Patterson 2012), inspired by Farhi and Werning (2017). Take an infinitely lived consumer, with standard time-separable preferences, who receives a deterministic stream of labor income {Yt} and has access to a single bond that pays the real interest rate rt. The optimal behavior of this consumer can be derived from the Euler equation","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"33 1","pages":"67 - 74"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2019-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/700899","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"44884031","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Comment 评论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2019-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/700904
François Gourio
The paper by Kozlowski, Veldkamp, and Venkateswaran argues that economic agents rationally revised their estimates of tail risk following the Great Recession and that this revision explains, at least in part, the persistent decline of interest rates on safe and liquid assets such as US Treasury securities. In a previous paper (Kozlowski, Veldkamp, and Venkateswaran 2015), the authors argued that the same belief revision can explain the slow recovery of investment and output. One important contribution of this work ismethodological: they propose a tractable approach to embedding learning dynamics in fairly standard quantitative models. Substantively, the overall argument is quite plausible, and I believe the remaining issues are really quantitative: How much did people’s beliefs about tail risk change after the Great Recession? And how sensitive are interest rates (in this paper) or economic activity (in the previous paper) to perceived tail risk? In this discussion, I will address the first question briefly, before turning to the second, and then dissect themechanisms throughwhich interest rates depend on tail risk in the paper. In Kozlowski and colleagues’ model, the risk-free asset combines two qualities: it is safe, and it is excellent collateral. Conceptually, one can separate these two characteristics, even though they are joint in the model and, to some extent, in the data. This allows us to distinguish twomechanisms throughwhich higher tail risk increases the value of the risk-free asset. First, agents’ willingness to pay for safe assets increases with tail risk. I will call this the “safety channel.” This is a standard precautionary savings effect, a wellknown piece of canonical asset-pricing theory. Second, agents’ willingness to pay for assets that are good collateral increases with tail risk, in large part because the tail risk reduces investment and thus the supply
Kozlowski、Veldkamp和Venkateswaran的论文认为,经济主体在大衰退(Great Recession)之后理性地修正了他们对尾部风险的估计,这种修正至少部分解释了美国国债等安全和流动性资产利率持续下降的原因。在之前的一篇论文中(Kozlowski, Veldkamp, and Venkateswaran 2015),作者认为同样的信念修正可以解释投资和产出的缓慢复苏。这项工作的一个重要贡献是方法论:他们提出了一种易于处理的方法,将学习动态嵌入到相当标准的定量模型中。从本质上讲,整个论点是相当合理的,我认为剩下的问题确实是量化的:在大衰退之后,人们对尾部风险的看法发生了多大的变化?利率(在本文中)或经济活动(在前一篇论文中)对感知到的尾部风险有多敏感?在这个讨论中,我将简要地解决第一个问题,然后再转向第二个问题,然后在本文中剖析利率依赖于尾部风险的机制。在科兹洛夫斯基和他的同事的模型中,无风险资产结合了两个特性:它是安全的,它是优秀的抵押品。从概念上讲,人们可以将这两个特征分开,尽管它们在模型中以及在某种程度上在数据中是联合的。这使我们能够区分两种机制,通过这种机制,较高的尾部风险增加了无风险资产的价值。首先,代理人购买安全资产的意愿随着尾部风险的增加而增加。我称之为“安全通道”。这是一种标准的预防性储蓄效应,是众所周知的典型资产定价理论。其次,随着尾部风险的增加,代理人愿意为作为良好抵押品的资产买单,这在很大程度上是因为尾部风险减少了投资,从而减少了供给
{"title":"Comment","authors":"François Gourio","doi":"10.1086/700904","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/700904","url":null,"abstract":"The paper by Kozlowski, Veldkamp, and Venkateswaran argues that economic agents rationally revised their estimates of tail risk following the Great Recession and that this revision explains, at least in part, the persistent decline of interest rates on safe and liquid assets such as US Treasury securities. In a previous paper (Kozlowski, Veldkamp, and Venkateswaran 2015), the authors argued that the same belief revision can explain the slow recovery of investment and output. One important contribution of this work ismethodological: they propose a tractable approach to embedding learning dynamics in fairly standard quantitative models. Substantively, the overall argument is quite plausible, and I believe the remaining issues are really quantitative: How much did people’s beliefs about tail risk change after the Great Recession? And how sensitive are interest rates (in this paper) or economic activity (in the previous paper) to perceived tail risk? In this discussion, I will address the first question briefly, before turning to the second, and then dissect themechanisms throughwhich interest rates depend on tail risk in the paper. In Kozlowski and colleagues’ model, the risk-free asset combines two qualities: it is safe, and it is excellent collateral. Conceptually, one can separate these two characteristics, even though they are joint in the model and, to some extent, in the data. This allows us to distinguish twomechanisms throughwhich higher tail risk increases the value of the risk-free asset. First, agents’ willingness to pay for safe assets increases with tail risk. I will call this the “safety channel.” This is a standard precautionary savings effect, a wellknown piece of canonical asset-pricing theory. Second, agents’ willingness to pay for assets that are good collateral increases with tail risk, in large part because the tail risk reduces investment and thus the supply","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"33 1","pages":"284 - 296"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2019-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/700904","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"60683189","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Discussion 讨论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2019-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/700915
The authors opened the discussion by addressing two points raised by Gregory Mankiw in his discussion. First, they argued that their model allows for sizeable long-run effects. They explained that an adjustment of border taxes leads to an appreciation of the US dollar in their model. Because the United States is a net debtor in its own currency, this appreciation leads to a negative valuation effect, corresponding to a transfer from the United States to the rest of the world of roughly 16% of US gross domestic product. This valuation effect possibly outweighs the short-term benefits of border adjustment. Second, the authors challenged the idea put forth by Mankiw that there is a clear dichotomy between short-run and long-run effects when it comes to trade policy. The authors insisted on the importance of political economy considerations in the short run, which may prevent the adoption of desired tax changes and the realization of long-run benefits. The authors next replied to questions from both discussants regarding the role of dollar pricing and the importance of Calvo pricing in the context of a large tax policy change. They pointed out that dollar pricing plays a key role in the failure of the Lerner symmetry in their model. The adoption of a border tax on imports has two effects on US consumer prices. The direct effect raises these prices, while the indirect effect reduces them by leading to an appreciation of the US dollar. In the presence of dollar pricing, the direct pass-throughof a tax is full,whereas the short-run pass-through of the exchange rate to consumer prices in the United States is low. This asymmetry is responsible for the failure of the Lerner symmetry. The authors noted that dollar pricing is consistent with recent evidence: the dollar appreciated and then depreciated by 10%–12% while border prices remained roughly unchanged. They provide a rationale for dollar pricing as an equilibriumphenomenon. International firms decide to set prices in US dollars because US inputs
作者以Gregory Mankiw在他的讨论中提出的两点作为讨论的开始。首先,他们认为他们的模型考虑到了相当大的长期影响。他们解释说,在他们的模型中,边境税的调整会导致美元升值。由于美国是本国货币的净债务国,这种升值导致了负估值效应,相当于美国国内生产总值(gdp)的约16%从美国转移到世界其他地区。这种估值效应可能超过边界调整的短期好处。其次,作者对曼昆提出的观点提出了挑战,即在贸易政策方面,短期和长期影响之间存在明显的二分法。作者坚持认为,政治经济考虑在短期内的重要性,这可能会阻碍采用理想的税收改革和实现长期利益。作者接下来回答了两位讨论者关于美元定价的作用和卡尔沃定价在重大税收政策变化背景下的重要性的问题。他们指出,在他们的模型中,美元定价在勒纳对称失效中起着关键作用。对进口商品征收边境税对美国消费者价格有两个影响。直接影响提高了这些价格,而间接影响通过导致美元升值来降低价格。在美元定价的情况下,税收的直接传递是充分的,而汇率对美国消费者价格的短期传递则很低。这种不对称导致了勒纳对称的失效。作者指出,美元定价与最近的证据是一致的:美元先是升值,然后贬值10%-12%,而边境价格基本保持不变。它们为美元定价作为一种均衡现象提供了理论依据。由于美国的投入,国际公司决定以美元定价
{"title":"Discussion","authors":"","doi":"10.1086/700915","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/700915","url":null,"abstract":"The authors opened the discussion by addressing two points raised by Gregory Mankiw in his discussion. First, they argued that their model allows for sizeable long-run effects. They explained that an adjustment of border taxes leads to an appreciation of the US dollar in their model. Because the United States is a net debtor in its own currency, this appreciation leads to a negative valuation effect, corresponding to a transfer from the United States to the rest of the world of roughly 16% of US gross domestic product. This valuation effect possibly outweighs the short-term benefits of border adjustment. Second, the authors challenged the idea put forth by Mankiw that there is a clear dichotomy between short-run and long-run effects when it comes to trade policy. The authors insisted on the importance of political economy considerations in the short run, which may prevent the adoption of desired tax changes and the realization of long-run benefits. The authors next replied to questions from both discussants regarding the role of dollar pricing and the importance of Calvo pricing in the context of a large tax policy change. They pointed out that dollar pricing plays a key role in the failure of the Lerner symmetry in their model. The adoption of a border tax on imports has two effects on US consumer prices. The direct effect raises these prices, while the indirect effect reduces them by leading to an appreciation of the US dollar. In the presence of dollar pricing, the direct pass-throughof a tax is full,whereas the short-run pass-through of the exchange rate to consumer prices in the United States is low. This asymmetry is responsible for the failure of the Lerner symmetry. The authors noted that dollar pricing is consistent with recent evidence: the dollar appreciated and then depreciated by 10%–12% while border prices remained roughly unchanged. They provide a rationale for dollar pricing as an equilibriumphenomenon. International firms decide to set prices in US dollars because US inputs","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"33 1","pages":"472 - 475"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2019-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/700915","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"41412377","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Comment 评论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2019-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/700907
V. Ramey
This fine paper by Charles, Hurst, and Schwartz investigates the link between the post-2000 decline in manufacturing employment and the decline of the employment rate, and also analyzes the supporting roles played by transfer payments, geographic mobility, and opioid use. The paper is a particularly useful synthesis because it brings together threads from a number of other papers, including the authors’ own work, and it explores some competing explanations in a standardized empirical framework. The paper is a wonderful read because it tells a clear story based on an impressive marshalling of evidence. The paper contains numerous findings that shed light on a variety of changes that occurred around the same time. The span of the analysis from aggregate to commuting zone level is particularly enlightening. Here are highlights of a just a few of the many interesting results:
Charles、Hurst和Schwartz的这篇精细论文调查了2000年后制造业就业人数下降与就业率下降之间的联系,并分析了转移支付、地域流动和阿片类药物使用所起的支持作用。这篇论文是一篇特别有用的综合文章,因为它汇集了许多其他论文的线索,包括作者自己的工作,并在标准化的经验框架中探索了一些相互竞争的解释。这篇论文读起来很精彩,因为它在令人印象深刻的证据基础上告诉了一个清晰的故事。这篇论文包含了许多发现,这些发现揭示了大约在同一时间发生的各种变化。从总量到通勤区层面的分析跨度尤其具有启发性。以下是众多有趣结果中的几个亮点:
{"title":"Comment","authors":"V. Ramey","doi":"10.1086/700907","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/700907","url":null,"abstract":"This fine paper by Charles, Hurst, and Schwartz investigates the link between the post-2000 decline in manufacturing employment and the decline of the employment rate, and also analyzes the supporting roles played by transfer payments, geographic mobility, and opioid use. The paper is a particularly useful synthesis because it brings together threads from a number of other papers, including the authors’ own work, and it explores some competing explanations in a standardized empirical framework. The paper is a wonderful read because it tells a clear story based on an impressive marshalling of evidence. The paper contains numerous findings that shed light on a variety of changes that occurred around the same time. The span of the analysis from aggregate to commuting zone level is particularly enlightening. Here are highlights of a just a few of the many interesting results:","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"33 1","pages":"380 - 388"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2019-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/700907","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"41437894","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Monetary Policy Analysis When Planning Horizons Are Finite 计划视野有限时的货币政策分析
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2019-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/700892
Michael Woodford
It is common to analyze the effects of alternative possible monetary policy commitments under the assumption of optimization under rational (or fully model-consistent) expectations. This implicitly assumes unrealistic cognitive abilities on the part of economic decision makers. The relevant question, however, is not whether the assumption can be literally correct, but how much it would matter to model decision making in a more realistic way. A model is proposed, based on the architecture of artificial intelligence programs for problems such as chess or go, in which decision makers look ahead only a finite distance into the future and use a value function learned from experience to evaluate situations that may be reached after a finite sequence of actions by themselves and others. Conditions are discussed under which the predictions of a model with finite-horizon forward planning are similar to those of a rational expectations equilibrium, and under which they are instead quite different. The model is used to reexamine the consequences that should be expected from a central bank commitment to maintain a fixed nominal interest rate for a substantial period of time. “Neo-Fisherian” predictions are shown to depend on using rational expectations equilibrium analysis under circumstances in which it should be expected to be unreliable.
在理性(或完全模型一致)预期下的优化假设下,分析各种可能的货币政策承诺的影响是很常见的。这隐含地假设了经济决策者不现实的认知能力。然而,相关的问题不是假设是否真的正确,而是以更现实的方式模拟决策有多重要。本文提出了一种基于人工智能程序架构的模型,用于解决诸如国际象棋或围棋等问题,在这种模型中,决策者只展望未来有限的距离,并使用从经验中学习到的价值函数来评估自己和他人在有限的行动序列之后可能达到的情况。讨论了在哪些条件下,有限视界前瞻性规划模型的预测与理性预期均衡的预测相似,而在哪些条件下,它们是完全不同的。该模型用于重新审视央行承诺在相当长一段时间内保持固定名义利率的预期后果。“新费舍尔主义”的预测依赖于在预期不可靠的情况下使用理性预期均衡分析。
{"title":"Monetary Policy Analysis When Planning Horizons Are Finite","authors":"Michael Woodford","doi":"10.1086/700892","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/700892","url":null,"abstract":"It is common to analyze the effects of alternative possible monetary policy commitments under the assumption of optimization under rational (or fully model-consistent) expectations. This implicitly assumes unrealistic cognitive abilities on the part of economic decision makers. The relevant question, however, is not whether the assumption can be literally correct, but how much it would matter to model decision making in a more realistic way. A model is proposed, based on the architecture of artificial intelligence programs for problems such as chess or go, in which decision makers look ahead only a finite distance into the future and use a value function learned from experience to evaluate situations that may be reached after a finite sequence of actions by themselves and others. Conditions are discussed under which the predictions of a model with finite-horizon forward planning are similar to those of a rational expectations equilibrium, and under which they are instead quite different. The model is used to reexamine the consequences that should be expected from a central bank commitment to maintain a fixed nominal interest rate for a substantial period of time. “Neo-Fisherian” predictions are shown to depend on using rational expectations equilibrium analysis under circumstances in which it should be expected to be unreliable.","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"61 11","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2019-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"138495555","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 80
Comment 评论
IF 7.7 1区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2019-01-01 DOI: 10.1086/700908
A. Auerbach
The tax reform process that culminated in the December 2017 enactment of the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act followed an unusual pattern regarding business tax reform. In particular, the original proposal, the “Blueprint” put forward by Republicans in the House of Representatives in June 2016 (Tax Reform Task Force 2016) called for the adoption of an approach that, at the time, was unfamiliar to many in the economics profession, a destination-based cash-flow tax (DBCFT). TheDBCFTwould have represented a sharp break from current policy, and the general lack of familiarity with it led many business leaders, policy makers, and economists to misinterpret its aims, characteristics, and properties. The paper by Omar Barbiero, Emmanuel Farhi, Gita Gopinath, and Oleg Itskhoki represents part of a small and growing literature seeking to analyze the DBCFT, or at least one of its key components: a border tax adjustment on imports and exports. In reading the paper, one is reminded of the advantages of following the more standard tax reform approach of analyzing new proposals before voting on them. This is not to say that I agree with all the paper’s modeling assumptions or conclusions, because I do not. But without such concrete analysis, it is difficult to identify key points of professional disagreement and, more importantly, to try to resolve them. The paper analyzes the short-run macroeconomic effects of adopting border tax adjustments on their own, although this is not what was being proposed. However, this is equivalent in the model to analyzing adoption of a full DBCFT, that is, a “source-based” cash-flow tax—a tax on domestic producers’ cash flows—plus border adjustment that removes tax on exports and imposes tax on imports. This equivalence follows because in themodel, a cash-flow taxwithout border adjustment is anondistortionary tax on pure profits—a lump-sum tax that would then be rebated via an
2017年12月颁布的《减税和就业法案》中,税收改革进程遵循了一种不同寻常的商业税改革模式。特别是,最初的提案,即2016年6月众议院共和党人提出的“蓝图”(2016年税收改革特别工作组),呼吁采用当时经济学界许多人不熟悉的方法,即基于目的地的现金流税(DBCFT)。DBCFT代表着与现行政策的彻底决裂,由于对其普遍不熟悉,导致许多商界领袖、政策制定者和经济学家误解了其目标、特征和性质。Omar Barbiero、Emmanuel Farhi、Gita Gopinath和Oleg Itskhoki的这篇论文代表了一小部分不断增长的文献的一部分,这些文献试图分析DBCFT,或者至少是其关键组成部分之一:进出口边境税调整。在阅读这篇论文时,人们会想起遵循更标准的税收改革方法的好处,即在对新提案进行投票之前对其进行分析。这并不是说我同意论文的所有建模假设或结论,因为我不同意。但如果没有这样的具体分析,就很难确定职业分歧的关键点,更重要的是,很难试图解决这些分歧。本文分析了自行采取边境税调整的短期宏观经济影响,尽管这不是提议的。然而,在该模型中,这相当于分析采用完整的DBCFT,即“基于来源”的现金流税——对国内生产商的现金流征税——加上取消出口税和征收进口税的边境调整。这种等价性是因为在该模型中,没有边界调整的现金流税是对纯利润的非扭曲税——一种一次性税收,然后通过
{"title":"Comment","authors":"A. Auerbach","doi":"10.1086/700908","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1086/700908","url":null,"abstract":"The tax reform process that culminated in the December 2017 enactment of the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act followed an unusual pattern regarding business tax reform. In particular, the original proposal, the “Blueprint” put forward by Republicans in the House of Representatives in June 2016 (Tax Reform Task Force 2016) called for the adoption of an approach that, at the time, was unfamiliar to many in the economics profession, a destination-based cash-flow tax (DBCFT). TheDBCFTwould have represented a sharp break from current policy, and the general lack of familiarity with it led many business leaders, policy makers, and economists to misinterpret its aims, characteristics, and properties. The paper by Omar Barbiero, Emmanuel Farhi, Gita Gopinath, and Oleg Itskhoki represents part of a small and growing literature seeking to analyze the DBCFT, or at least one of its key components: a border tax adjustment on imports and exports. In reading the paper, one is reminded of the advantages of following the more standard tax reform approach of analyzing new proposals before voting on them. This is not to say that I agree with all the paper’s modeling assumptions or conclusions, because I do not. But without such concrete analysis, it is difficult to identify key points of professional disagreement and, more importantly, to try to resolve them. The paper analyzes the short-run macroeconomic effects of adopting border tax adjustments on their own, although this is not what was being proposed. However, this is equivalent in the model to analyzing adoption of a full DBCFT, that is, a “source-based” cash-flow tax—a tax on domestic producers’ cash flows—plus border adjustment that removes tax on exports and imposes tax on imports. This equivalence follows because in themodel, a cash-flow taxwithout border adjustment is anondistortionary tax on pure profits—a lump-sum tax that would then be rebated via an","PeriodicalId":51680,"journal":{"name":"Nber Macroeconomics Annual","volume":"33 1","pages":"458 - 467"},"PeriodicalIF":7.7,"publicationDate":"2019-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1086/700908","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"42016765","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":1,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Nber Macroeconomics Annual
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1