首页 > 最新文献

International Review of Law and Economics最新文献

英文 中文
Bias in media coverage of antitrust actions 媒体对反垄断行动的报道存在偏见
IF 1.1 3区 社会学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-12-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.irle.2022.106085
Juan Luis Jiménez , Jordi Perdiguero , Inmaculada Gutiérrez

One of the main goals of competition authorities is to deter anticompetitive practices. That is one of the reasons why antitrust decisions are made public: to reinforce the deterrence effect, as the impact of the mass media on public opinion may affect firms’ reputations. Our empirical strategy focuses on identifying how the nature of specific antitrust actions by competition authorities affects the size of news items and their visibility within the newspaper. We study this relationship by using a new database containing all news published in Spain over a 30-month period, regarding all cases analysed by the Spanish competition authority. Our analysis produced two key conclusions about how the media deals with positive and negative news on the reputation of listed and non-listed companies. On average, the difference in size between positive and negative news for listed firms is greater than the difference present in the actions referring to non-listed firms. Secondly, newspapers concede greater visibility to them by positioning more favourably, both on the right-hand side of the paper and on initial pages. These results suggest that the deterrence effect that competition authorities seek by making their decisions public may be weakened by the presence of bias in media.

竞争管理机构的主要目标之一是遏制反竞争行为。这就是为什么反垄断决定要公开的原因之一:为了加强威慑效应,因为大众媒体对公众舆论的影响可能会影响到公司的声誉。我们的实证策略侧重于确定竞争监管机构具体反垄断行动的性质如何影响新闻项目的规模及其在报纸中的可见性。我们通过使用一个新的数据库来研究这种关系,该数据库包含西班牙30个月内发布的所有新闻,涉及西班牙竞争管理局分析的所有案例。我们的分析得出了媒体如何处理关于上市公司和非上市公司声誉的正面和负面新闻的两个关键结论。平均而言,上市公司正面和负面消息的规模差异大于针对非上市公司的行动的差异。其次,报纸通过更有利的定位,无论是在报纸的右侧还是在首页,让他们更容易看到。这些结果表明,竞争主管部门通过公开决策寻求的威慑效果可能会被媒体偏见的存在所削弱。
{"title":"Bias in media coverage of antitrust actions","authors":"Juan Luis Jiménez ,&nbsp;Jordi Perdiguero ,&nbsp;Inmaculada Gutiérrez","doi":"10.1016/j.irle.2022.106085","DOIUrl":"10.1016/j.irle.2022.106085","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p>One of the main goals of competition authorities is to deter anticompetitive practices. That is one of the reasons why antitrust decisions are made public: to reinforce the deterrence effect, as the impact of the mass media on public opinion may affect firms’ reputations. Our empirical strategy focuses on identifying how the nature of specific antitrust actions by competition authorities affects the size of news items and their visibility within the newspaper. We study this relationship by using a new database containing all news published in Spain over a 30-month period, regarding all cases analysed by the Spanish competition authority. Our analysis produced two key conclusions about how the media deals with positive and negative news on the reputation of listed and non-listed companies. On average, the difference in size between positive and negative news for listed firms is greater than the difference present in the actions referring to non-listed firms. Secondly, newspapers concede greater visibility to them by positioning more favourably, both on the right-hand side of the paper and on initial pages. These results suggest that the deterrence effect that competition authorities seek by making their decisions public may be weakened by the presence of bias in media.</p></div>","PeriodicalId":47202,"journal":{"name":"International Review of Law and Economics","volume":"72 ","pages":"Article 106085"},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2022-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0144818822000412/pdfft?md5=3917fcaf89f3f2c08cdb0d8322727a83&pid=1-s2.0-S0144818822000412-main.pdf","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"47708360","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Is it the firm, the innovator, or the innovation? Determinants of perceived non-imitability leading to unprotected intellectual property 是企业,创新者,还是创新?认知不可模仿性导致知识产权不受保护的决定因素
IF 1.1 3区 社会学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-12-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.irle.2022.106095
Marilena Vecco , Nikos Georgantzis , Pieter Kroonenberg

Why are innovators in creative industries often not concerned about their unprotected intellectual properties? Based on a unique dataset obtained from an extensive survey among one, two and three-starred Italian chefs, we explore the determinants of a creator’s lack of concern about the imitation of their innovations. Several determinants are identified. We confirm that the lack of fear of imitation and, thus, the lack of need for further IP protection, is associated with organizational strategies for the management of new ideas. Furthermore, this lack of fear of imitation is motivated by the innovator’s strategies aimed at product differentiation and client loyalty. Interestingly, in all the models estimated with the two samples considered (full sample and 2 and 3-starred chefs only), the most robust driver of innovators’ peace of mind is their own perception that innovative creation is a spontaneous, individual, innovator-specific process.

为什么创意产业的创新者往往不关心他们未受保护的知识产权?基于对意大利一星、二星和三星厨师的广泛调查获得的独特数据集,我们探讨了创造者不关心他们的创新被模仿的决定因素。确定了几个决定因素。我们确认,缺乏对模仿的恐惧,从而不需要进一步的知识产权保护,与管理新思想的组织战略有关。此外,这种对模仿的恐惧的缺乏是由创新者旨在产品差异化和客户忠诚度的战略所激发的。有趣的是,在考虑了两个样本(全样本和2星和3星厨师)的所有模型中,创新者内心平静的最强大驱动因素是他们自己的看法,即创新创造是一个自发的、个人的、创新者特有的过程。
{"title":"Is it the firm, the innovator, or the innovation? Determinants of perceived non-imitability leading to unprotected intellectual property","authors":"Marilena Vecco ,&nbsp;Nikos Georgantzis ,&nbsp;Pieter Kroonenberg","doi":"10.1016/j.irle.2022.106095","DOIUrl":"10.1016/j.irle.2022.106095","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p>Why are innovators in creative industries<span> often not concerned about their unprotected intellectual properties? Based on a unique dataset obtained from an extensive survey among one, two and three-starred Italian chefs, we explore the determinants of a creator’s lack of concern about the imitation of their innovations. Several determinants are identified. We confirm that the lack of fear of imitation and, thus, the lack of need for further IP protection, is associated with organizational strategies for the management of new ideas. Furthermore, this lack of fear of imitation is motivated by the innovator’s strategies aimed at product differentiation and client loyalty. Interestingly, in all the models estimated with the two samples considered (full sample and 2 and 3-starred chefs only), the most robust driver of innovators’ peace of mind is their own perception that innovative creation is a spontaneous, individual, innovator-specific process.</span></p></div>","PeriodicalId":47202,"journal":{"name":"International Review of Law and Economics","volume":"72 ","pages":"Article 106095"},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2022-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"43839882","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Crime and the Mariel Boatlift 犯罪和玛丽埃尔劫船案
IF 1.1 3区 社会学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-12-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.irle.2022.106094
Alexander Billy , Michael Packard

We describe crime attributable to the Mariel Boatlift, the 1980 Cuban refugee crisis that increased Miami’s population by nearly 10%. Using synthetic control methods to match Miami with cities that exhibit similar pre-intervention crime patterns, we find the phenomenon comparatively increased property crime and murder rates; we also document weaker but suggestive relative growth in violent crime. Compositional features of the newcomers partially drive results; the disproportionately young, male Cubans’ characteristics highly correlate with illicit activity. However, the degree of prior incarceration and psychiatric institutionalization likely explains the majority of the observed effects. Given the group’s unique composition and the absence of rigorous screening, it likely constitutes the worst observed migration event in terms of public safety in US history. The Marielitos bear little resemblance to other groups of newcomers. Hence, it would be imprudent to use crime connected with the 1980 event we study to inform immigration policy.

我们描述了1980年古巴难民危机导致迈阿密人口增加近10%的马里埃尔偷渡船事件。采用综合控制方法将迈阿密与表现出类似干预前犯罪模式的城市进行匹配,我们发现财产犯罪和谋杀率相对增加;我们还记录了暴力犯罪相对较弱但具有暗示性的增长。新来者的成分特征部分推动了结果;不成比例的年轻男性古巴人的特征与非法活动高度相关。然而,先前监禁和精神病院的程度可能解释了大多数观察到的影响。考虑到这群人的独特组成和缺乏严格的筛选,这可能是美国历史上最严重的公共安全移民事件。Marielitos和其他新来者没有什么相似之处。因此,利用与我们研究的1980年事件有关的犯罪来指导移民政策是不明智的。
{"title":"Crime and the Mariel Boatlift","authors":"Alexander Billy ,&nbsp;Michael Packard","doi":"10.1016/j.irle.2022.106094","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.irle.2022.106094","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p>We describe crime attributable to the Mariel Boatlift, the 1980 Cuban refugee crisis that increased Miami’s population by nearly 10%. Using synthetic control methods to match Miami with cities that exhibit similar pre-intervention crime patterns, we find the phenomenon comparatively increased property crime and murder rates; we also document weaker but suggestive relative growth in violent crime. Compositional features of the newcomers partially drive results; the disproportionately young, male Cubans’ characteristics highly correlate with illicit activity. However, the degree of prior incarceration and psychiatric institutionalization likely explains the majority of the observed effects. Given the group’s unique composition and the absence of rigorous screening, it likely constitutes the worst observed migration event in terms of public safety in US history. The Marielitos bear little resemblance to other groups of newcomers. Hence, it would be imprudent to use crime connected with the 1980 event we study to inform immigration policy.</p></div>","PeriodicalId":47202,"journal":{"name":"International Review of Law and Economics","volume":"72 ","pages":"Article 106094"},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2022-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"136549013","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Consent or coordination? assemblies in early medieval Europe 同意还是协调?中世纪早期欧洲的集会
IF 1.1 3区 社会学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-12-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.irle.2022.106096
Andrew T. Young

The standard political economy narrative of representative assemblies in Western Europe is one of political bargaining and credible commitments. Monarchs sought to bargain with the leading men of the realms, exchanging their commitments on various policies for revenues and other resources. This narrative has been forcibly challenged by Boucoyannis (2015, 2021) who points out that, in the High Middle Ages, it was strong monarchs who were able to compel the leading men of their realms to assemblies She argues that strong monarchs were able to leverage their subjects’ demand for adjudication (justice) to compel their attendance; and then extract their promises of resources. In this paper, I add to the discussion of the origins of representative institutions. Prior to the High Middle Ages, assemblies were ubiquitous but scarcely democratic. I provide a coordination model of assemblies that provides a compelling account of these early medieval assemblies. Similar to arguments put forth by Hardin (1989, 1999), Ordeshook (1992), Weingast (1997), Weingast (2005), and Hadfield and Weingast (2014) regarding modern de jure constitutions, I argue that assemblies allowed monarchs to provide focal point around which they could coordinate their leading men. There was relatively little meaningful bargaining at these assemblies; rather, monarchs provided ceremony and spectacle meant to focus their leading men on their agendas.

西欧代议制议会的标准政治经济学叙事是一种政治讨价还价和可信承诺。君主们试图与王国的领袖们讨价还价,用他们在各种政策上的承诺来换取收入和其他资源。Boucoyannis(2015, 2021)对这种说法提出了强烈的质疑,他指出,在中世纪盛期,只有强大的君主才能迫使其领域的主要人物参加集会。她认为,强大的君主能够利用臣民对裁决(正义)的需求来迫使他们出席;然后提取他们承诺的资源。在本文中,我补充了对代议制起源的讨论。在中世纪盛期之前,集会无处不在,但几乎不民主。我提供了一个会议的协调模型,提供了一个令人信服的中世纪早期会议的说明。与Hardin(1989,1999)、Ordeshook(1992)、Weingast(1997)、Weingast(2005)以及Hadfield和Weingast(2014)提出的关于现代法律宪法的论点类似,我认为议会允许君主提供协调其领导人物的焦点。在这些集会上,几乎没有什么有意义的谈判;相反,君主们提供仪式和场面,目的是让他们的领导人专注于自己的议程。
{"title":"Consent or coordination? assemblies in early medieval Europe","authors":"Andrew T. Young","doi":"10.1016/j.irle.2022.106096","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.irle.2022.106096","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p><span>The standard political economy narrative of representative assemblies in Western Europe is one of political bargaining and credible commitments. Monarchs sought to bargain with the leading men of the realms, exchanging their commitments on various policies for revenues and other resources. This narrative has been forcibly challenged by Boucoyannis (2015, 2021) who points out that, in the High Middle Ages, it was strong monarchs who were able to compel the leading men of their realms to assemblies She argues that strong monarchs were able to leverage their subjects’ demand for adjudication (justice) to compel their attendance; and then extract their promises of resources. In this paper, I add to the discussion of the origins of representative institutions. Prior to the High Middle Ages, assemblies were ubiquitous but scarcely democratic. I provide a coordination model of assemblies that provides a compelling account of these early medieval assemblies. Similar to arguments put forth by Hardin (1989, 1999), Ordeshook (1992), Weingast (1997), Weingast (2005), and Hadfield and Weingast (2014) regarding modern </span><em>de jure</em> constitutions, I argue that assemblies allowed monarchs to provide focal point around which they could coordinate their leading men. There was relatively little meaningful bargaining at these assemblies; rather, monarchs provided ceremony and spectacle meant to focus their leading men on their agendas.</p></div>","PeriodicalId":47202,"journal":{"name":"International Review of Law and Economics","volume":"72 ","pages":"Article 106096"},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2022-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"92143424","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
The value of fiduciary duties: Evidence from en bloc sales in Singapore 受托责任的价值:来自新加坡整体销售的证据
IF 1.1 3区 社会学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-12-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.irle.2022.106093
Jianfeng Hu , Kelvin F.K. Low , Wei Zhang

This paper examines the impact of fiduciary duties on collective asset sales in the case of owners acting as delegates for other owners, thereby potentially inducing conflicts of interests. Our identification strategy exploits a unique legal shock in Singapore, which established fiduciary duties in those transactions in the real estate market known colloquially as en bloc sales. The imposition of fiduciary duties caused the price premium of units sold via en bloc sales to increase over units ineligible for en bloc sale, as well as over units that, although eligible for en bloc sale, are sold individually. In addition, this valuation effect is stronger for projects with especially severe agency problems as proxied by high ownership turnover. This legal reform also affects the general private housing market beyond the en bloc premium: findings show that residential owners are increasingly willing to participate and reduce condominium turnover. Finally, we find that the stock price of public real estate developers responded positively to the legal reform, which indicates a possible overall positive welfare effect. Our study highlights the importance of judicial oversight for addressing agency conflicts in non-consensual asset-sale mechanisms.

本文考察了在所有者作为其他所有者的代表的情况下,信托义务对集体资产销售的影响,从而可能引发利益冲突。我们的识别策略利用了新加坡独特的法律冲击,它在房地产市场的交易中建立了信托义务,俗称整体销售。信托税的征收导致通过整体销售出售的单位的价格溢价高于不符合整体销售条件的单位,以及尽管符合整体销售条件但单独出售的单位。此外,对于以高所有权周转率为代表的代理问题特别严重的项目,这种估值效应更强。这项法律改革还影响了整体溢价之外的一般私人住房市场:调查结果显示,住宅业主越来越愿意参与并减少共管公寓的成交量。最后,我们发现公共房地产开发商的股票价格对法律改革的响应是积极的,这表明可能存在整体的正福利效应。我们的研究强调了司法监督对于解决非自愿资产出售机制中的代理冲突的重要性。
{"title":"The value of fiduciary duties: Evidence from en bloc sales in Singapore","authors":"Jianfeng Hu ,&nbsp;Kelvin F.K. Low ,&nbsp;Wei Zhang","doi":"10.1016/j.irle.2022.106093","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.irle.2022.106093","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p><span>This paper examines the impact of fiduciary duties on collective asset sales in the case of owners acting as delegates for other owners, thereby potentially inducing conflicts of interests. Our identification strategy exploits a unique legal shock in Singapore, which established fiduciary duties in those transactions in the real estate market known colloquially as </span><em>en bloc</em> sales. The imposition of fiduciary duties caused the price premium of units sold <em>via en bloc</em> sales to increase over units ineligible for <em>en bloc</em> sale, as well as over units that, although eligible for <em>en bloc</em> sale, are sold individually. In addition, this valuation effect is stronger for projects with especially severe agency problems as proxied by high ownership turnover. This legal reform also affects the general private housing market beyond the <em>en bloc</em><span> premium: findings show that residential owners are increasingly willing to participate and reduce condominium turnover. Finally, we find that the stock price of public real estate developers responded positively to the legal reform, which indicates a possible overall positive welfare effect. Our study highlights the importance of judicial oversight for addressing agency conflicts in non-consensual asset-sale mechanisms.</span></p></div>","PeriodicalId":47202,"journal":{"name":"International Review of Law and Economics","volume":"72 ","pages":"Article 106093"},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2022-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"92078554","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Spatial and temporal correlations of crime in Detroit: Evidence from spatial dynamic panel data models 底特律犯罪的时空相关性:来自空间动态面板数据模型的证据
IF 1.1 3区 社会学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-12-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.irle.2022.106100
Xu Lin , Jihu Zhang , Shanhe Jiang

Since the infamous riot of 1967, high crime rates and negative media reports have labeled the city of Detroit as one of the most dangerous cities in the United States. Using a Spatial Dynamic Panel Data model with both individual and time fixed effects to capture the unobserved heterogeneity as well as the time varying common factors, we investigate the spatial and temporal interactions of criminal activities among the block groups in Detroit. The results indicate that the crime incidents in a block is correlated with the average crime incidents in neighboring block groups contemporaneously, with an estimated coefficient of 0.4758, and the block crime incidents is also correlated with the average crime incidents in neighboring blocks from the previous year, with an estimated coefficient of 0.1572. And crime incidents in a block are positively correlated with its own crime incidents in the previous year. The findings are robust against different model specifications based on alternative spatial weights matrices. The results for both violent crimes and property crimes also suggest strong spatial and temporal correlations among neighboring blocks, providing suggestive and preliminary evidence for policy implementation.

自1967年臭名昭著的暴乱以来,高犯罪率和负面媒体报道使底特律成为美国最危险的城市之一。利用具有个体效应和时间固定效应的空间动态面板数据模型来捕捉未观察到的异质性以及随时间变化的共同因素,我们研究了底特律街区群体之间犯罪活动的时空相互作用。结果表明,街区内犯罪事件与相邻街区同期平均犯罪事件的相关系数估计为0.4758,街区犯罪事件与相邻街区前一年平均犯罪事件的相关系数估计为0.1572。街区内的犯罪事件与该街区前一年的犯罪事件呈正相关。研究结果对基于替代空间权重矩阵的不同模型规范具有鲁棒性。暴力犯罪和财产犯罪的研究结果也表明,相邻街区之间存在很强的时空相关性,为政策实施提供了初步证据。
{"title":"Spatial and temporal correlations of crime in Detroit: Evidence from spatial dynamic panel data models","authors":"Xu Lin ,&nbsp;Jihu Zhang ,&nbsp;Shanhe Jiang","doi":"10.1016/j.irle.2022.106100","DOIUrl":"10.1016/j.irle.2022.106100","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p>Since the infamous riot of 1967, high crime rates and negative media reports have labeled the city of Detroit as one of the most dangerous cities in the United States. Using a Spatial Dynamic Panel Data model<span> with both individual and time fixed effects to capture the unobserved heterogeneity as well as the time varying common factors, we investigate the spatial and temporal interactions of criminal activities among the block groups in Detroit. The results indicate that the crime incidents in a block is correlated with the average crime incidents in neighboring block groups contemporaneously, with an estimated coefficient of 0.4758, and the block crime incidents is also correlated with the average crime incidents in neighboring blocks from the previous year, with an estimated coefficient of 0.1572. And crime incidents in a block are positively correlated with its own crime incidents in the previous year. The findings are robust against different model specifications based on alternative spatial weights matrices. The results for both violent crimes and property crimes also suggest strong spatial and temporal correlations among neighboring blocks, providing suggestive and preliminary evidence for policy implementation.</span></p></div>","PeriodicalId":47202,"journal":{"name":"International Review of Law and Economics","volume":"72 ","pages":"Article 106100"},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2022-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"43139077","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Do women drive corporate social responsibility? Evidence from gender diversity reforms around the world 女性是否推动了企业的社会责任?来自世界各地性别多样性改革的证据
IF 1.1 3区 社会学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-12-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.irle.2022.106097
Rong Ding , Tinghua Duan , Wenxuan Hou , Xianda Liu , Ziwei Xu

In this study we investigate the effect of female director on corporate social responsibility (CSR) by taking the advantage of the introduction of legal gender quota that led to the exogenous change in the female representation in corporate board around the world. We find that the “gender quote” reforms effectively increase gender diversity and improve CSR performance. When comparing the legislation-based regulations with governance code-based regulations, we find that the former brings stronger effects on CSR performance. Finally, the effects are more pronounced in countries with higher gender equality or common law legal systems.

在本研究中,我们利用法律性别配额的引入导致世界各地公司董事会中女性代表的外生变化的优势,调查了女性董事对企业社会责任(CSR)的影响。我们发现,“性别报价”改革有效地增加了性别多样性,提高了企业社会责任绩效。通过比较立法规制与治理规范规制对企业社会责任绩效的影响,我们发现立法规制对企业社会责任绩效的影响更大。最后,在性别平等程度较高或普通法法律体系的国家,这种影响更为明显。
{"title":"Do women drive corporate social responsibility? Evidence from gender diversity reforms around the world","authors":"Rong Ding ,&nbsp;Tinghua Duan ,&nbsp;Wenxuan Hou ,&nbsp;Xianda Liu ,&nbsp;Ziwei Xu","doi":"10.1016/j.irle.2022.106097","DOIUrl":"10.1016/j.irle.2022.106097","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p><span>In this study we investigate the effect of female director on corporate social responsibility (CSR) by taking the advantage of the introduction of legal gender quota that led to the exogenous change in the female representation in corporate board around the world. We find that the “gender quote” reforms effectively increase </span>gender diversity<span> and improve CSR performance. When comparing the legislation-based regulations with governance code-based regulations, we find that the former brings stronger effects on CSR performance. Finally, the effects are more pronounced in countries with higher gender equality or common law legal systems.</span></p></div>","PeriodicalId":47202,"journal":{"name":"International Review of Law and Economics","volume":"72 ","pages":"Article 106097"},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2022-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"41926642","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Time to resolve insolvency and political elections 是时候解决破产和政治选举了
IF 1.1 3区 社会学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-12-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.irle.2022.106104
Nicolae Stef , Sami Ben Jabeur , Robert F. Scherer

Theories on electoral accountability argue that politicians have strong incentives to avoid punishment from voters for poor administrative abilities. As their chances of reelection can be harmed by failure of businesses, politicians may encourage the speed up of insolvency proceedings to mitigate the voters’ punishment before the elections. Using a sample of 82 countries covering the period 2005–2017, we examined how legislative and presidential elections affect the time required to resolve corporate insolvency. Surprisingly, panel estimates reveal that the length of time to resolve insolvency tends to actually increase during periods of legislative elections and one year prior to such elections in the case of rehabilitation procedures. As the political agenda of the new government can affect the efficiency of restructuring plans, the uncertainty of legislative election outcomes can incentivize debtor and creditors to prolong the resolution of a firm’s reorganization to adjust the plan and/or adopt the most suitable plan. Additionally, our econometric approach reports no significant association between the duration of insolvency procedures and the cycle of presidential elections.

选举问责理论认为,政治家有强烈的动机避免因行政能力差而受到选民的惩罚。由于企业破产会影响他们连任的机会,政客们可能会鼓励加快破产程序,以减轻选举前选民的惩罚。我们使用2005-2017年期间82个国家的样本,研究了立法和总统选举如何影响解决公司破产所需的时间。令人惊讶的是,小组的估计数显示,在立法选举期间,解决破产的时间实际上往往会增加,而在恢复程序方面,在选举前一年往往会增加。由于新政府的政治议程会影响重组计划的效率,立法选举结果的不确定性会激励债务人和债权人延长企业重组的决议,以调整计划和/或采取最合适的计划。此外,我们的计量经济学方法报告称,破产程序的持续时间与总统选举的周期之间没有显著关联。
{"title":"Time to resolve insolvency and political elections","authors":"Nicolae Stef ,&nbsp;Sami Ben Jabeur ,&nbsp;Robert F. Scherer","doi":"10.1016/j.irle.2022.106104","DOIUrl":"10.1016/j.irle.2022.106104","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p>Theories on electoral accountability argue that politicians have strong incentives to avoid punishment from voters for poor administrative abilities. As their chances of reelection can be harmed by failure of businesses, politicians may encourage the speed up of insolvency proceedings to mitigate the voters’ punishment before the elections. Using a sample of 82 countries covering the period 2005–2017, we examined how legislative and presidential elections affect the time required to resolve corporate insolvency. Surprisingly, panel estimates reveal that the length of time to resolve insolvency tends to actually increase during periods of legislative elections and one year prior to such elections in the case of rehabilitation procedures. As the political agenda of the new government can affect the efficiency of restructuring plans, the uncertainty of legislative election outcomes can incentivize debtor and creditors to prolong the resolution of a firm’s reorganization to adjust the plan and/or adopt the most suitable plan. Additionally, our econometric approach reports no significant association between the duration of insolvency procedures and the cycle of presidential elections.</p></div>","PeriodicalId":47202,"journal":{"name":"International Review of Law and Economics","volume":"72 ","pages":"Article 106104"},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2022-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"48359205","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Borrowers’ discouragement and creditor information 借款人的气馁和债权人的信息
IF 1.1 3区 社会学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-12-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.irle.2022.106098
Jérémie Bertrand, Paolo Mazza

Bank discouragement is one of the most important factors preventing firms from accessing credit. This discouragement stems from strong information asymmetry between firm and bank. To reduce this asymmetry, the latter can either gather information from the firm or access public information on the firm through credit databases. We argue that the presence of credit bureaus, set up by the regulator, which reduces information asymmetry, helps reduce banking discouragement. More specifically, this study is the first to use credit registries to capture the occurrence of screening errors. Our results clearly suggest that the probability of being discouraged decreases when creditor information is available. This phenomenon is even more obvious in regard to more opaque structures, such as risky firms or small and medium-sized firms. In contrast, relationship lending reduces the importance of external creditor information in determining the extent to which borrowers are discouraged. Our results are consistent with previous research on information asymmetry in financial intermediation and show the importance of the legal environment in which firms operate for their financial decisions.

银行的不信任感是阻碍企业获得信贷的最重要因素之一。这种沮丧源于企业和银行之间强烈的信息不对称。为了减少这种不对称,后者要么从企业收集信息,要么通过信用数据库获取企业的公开信息。我们认为,由监管机构设立的征信机构的存在,减少了信息不对称,有助于减少银行业的气馁情绪。更具体地说,这项研究是第一次使用信用登记来捕捉筛选错误的发生。我们的研究结果清楚地表明,当债权人信息可用时,气馁的可能性会降低。这种现象在结构不透明的公司中更为明显,比如高风险公司或中小型公司。相反,关系贷款降低了外部债权人信息在确定借款人受挫程度方面的重要性。我们的研究结果与之前关于金融中介中信息不对称的研究结果一致,并显示了企业经营的法律环境对其财务决策的重要性。
{"title":"Borrowers’ discouragement and creditor information","authors":"Jérémie Bertrand,&nbsp;Paolo Mazza","doi":"10.1016/j.irle.2022.106098","DOIUrl":"10.1016/j.irle.2022.106098","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p>Bank discouragement is one of the most important factors preventing firms from accessing credit. This discouragement stems from strong information asymmetry between firm and bank. To reduce this asymmetry, the latter can either gather information from the firm or access public information on the firm through credit databases. We argue that the presence of credit bureaus, set up by the regulator, which reduces information asymmetry, helps reduce banking discouragement. More specifically, this study is the first to use credit registries to capture the occurrence of screening errors. Our results clearly suggest that the probability of being discouraged decreases when creditor information is available. This phenomenon is even more obvious in regard to more opaque structures, such as risky firms or small and medium-sized firms. In contrast, relationship lending reduces the importance of external creditor information in determining the extent to which borrowers are discouraged. Our results are consistent with previous research on information asymmetry in financial intermediation and show the importance of the legal environment in which firms operate for their financial decisions.</p></div>","PeriodicalId":47202,"journal":{"name":"International Review of Law and Economics","volume":"72 ","pages":"Article 106098"},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2022-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"41669359","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
ON THE DECLINE IN STATE POPULATION DISTRIBUTION: A COASEAN ROLE FOR SECTION 111 OF THE AUSTRALIAN CONSTITUTION? 论各州人口分布的下降:澳大利亚宪法第111条的协调作用?
IF 1.1 3区 社会学 Q3 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-12-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.irle.2022.106092
Benjamen Franklen Gussen

Since Federation,2 the ratio of people living outside capital cities to those living within these cities have been declining in all six States. Historically, Australia opted for a regulatory approach that favoured in favouring satellite towns around state capitals, such as Newcastle and the Gold Coast, over the alternative of decentralised regional urban centres, such as Wagga Wagga or Townsville. The latest phase of this planning paradigm envisages integrating these satellites and their capital cities into mega-metropolises. Notwithstanding the benefits from agglomeration, rectifying the observed imbalance assumes an urgency not only through a national security imperative but also through social equity. To analyse the cause of this population decline, I use a theoretical model to explain how sub-national state political accountability distorts incentives when it comes to the provision of public goods. The equilibrium provision is not Pareto optimal given the observed population distribution externality. The inefficient provision of public goods is causing more people to choose to live in the capital city, which in turn creates a vicious circle of worsening population distribution. The model suggests that breaking this circle requires Coasean bargaining so that eliminating the externality is assigned to the Australian jurisdiction that can do so at the lowest cost. Surrender and acceptance agreements under section 111 of the Australian Constitution furnish a modality for the envisaged bargaining to the end of transforming regional Australia into a national jurisdiction. Whether this efficiency can be realised remains a question of transaction costs and income effects flowing from such jurisdictional reassignment.

自联邦成立以来2,在所有六个州,居住在首都城市以外的人口与居住在这些城市内的人口的比例一直在下降。从历史上看,澳大利亚选择了一种监管方式,倾向于支持州首府周围的卫星城,如纽卡斯尔和黄金海岸,而不是分散的区域城市中心,如沃加沃加或汤斯维尔。这一规划范式的最新阶段设想将这些卫星国及其首都城市整合为超级大都市。尽管集聚带来了好处,但纠正这种观察到的不平衡不仅是国家安全的需要,也是社会公平的需要。为了分析这种人口下降的原因,我使用了一个理论模型来解释次国家的政治问责制是如何扭曲公共产品提供方面的激励的。考虑到观察到的人口分布外部性,均衡供给不是帕累托最优的。公共产品供给的低效导致更多的人选择居住在首都,这反过来又造成了人口分布恶化的恶性循环。该模型表明,打破这一循环需要科斯讨价还价,以便将消除外部性的任务分配给能够以最低成本做到这一点的澳大利亚司法管辖区。《澳大利亚宪法》第111条规定的移交和接受协议为设想的谈判提供了一种方式,最终将澳大利亚的区域管辖权转变为国家管辖权。这种效率能否实现,仍然是交易成本和这种管辖权重新分配带来的收入效应的问题。
{"title":"ON THE DECLINE IN STATE POPULATION DISTRIBUTION: A COASEAN ROLE FOR SECTION 111 OF THE AUSTRALIAN CONSTITUTION?","authors":"Benjamen Franklen Gussen","doi":"10.1016/j.irle.2022.106092","DOIUrl":"10.1016/j.irle.2022.106092","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p>Since Federation,<span><sup>2</sup></span><span> the ratio of people living outside capital cities to those living within these cities have been declining in all six States. Historically, Australia opted for a regulatory approach that favoured in favouring satellite towns around state capitals, such as Newcastle and the Gold Coast, over the alternative of decentralised regional urban centres, such as Wagga Wagga or Townsville. The latest phase of this planning paradigm envisages integrating these satellites and their capital cities into mega-metropolises. Notwithstanding the benefits from agglomeration, rectifying the observed imbalance assumes an urgency not only through a national security imperative but also through social equity. To analyse the cause of this population decline, I use a theoretical model to explain how sub-national state political accountability distorts incentives when it comes to the provision of public goods. The equilibrium provision is not Pareto optimal given the observed population distribution externality. The inefficient provision of public goods is causing more people to choose to live in the capital city, which in turn creates a vicious circle of worsening population distribution. The model suggests that breaking this circle requires Coasean bargaining so that eliminating the externality is assigned to the Australian jurisdiction that can do so at the lowest cost. Surrender and acceptance agreements under section 111 of the </span><em>Australian Constitution</em> furnish a modality for the envisaged bargaining to the end of transforming regional Australia into a national jurisdiction. Whether this efficiency can be realised remains a question of transaction costs and income effects flowing from such jurisdictional reassignment.</p></div>","PeriodicalId":47202,"journal":{"name":"International Review of Law and Economics","volume":"72 ","pages":"Article 106092"},"PeriodicalIF":1.1,"publicationDate":"2022-12-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"45646655","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
International Review of Law and Economics
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1