首页 > 最新文献

Resource and Energy Economics最新文献

英文 中文
The economics of climate change with endogenous preferences 具有内生偏好的气候变化经济学
IF 2.9 3区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-08-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101312
Linus Mattauch , Cameron Hepburn , Fiona Spuler , Nicholas Stern

Avoiding unmanageable climate change implies that global greenhouse gas emissions must be reduced rapidly. Carbon prices and technological development are essential to deliver such reductions. Changes in preferences, however, are rarely considered, even though other major socioeconomic transitions – such as those from reducing smoking and drink-driving – have succeeded partly because preferences have changed. This article examines the impact of climate policy-induced changes in consumers’ preferences. We show that low-carbon policies could be better designed if it is recognised that preferences can be endogenous to such policies. For instance, carbon taxes must be adjusted, if they crowd-in or -out social preferences, to achieve a given target. Further, when the urban built environment changes mobility preferences, the value of low-carbon infrastructure investments can be underestimated if such effects are ignored. Third, policy-induced changes in preferences for active travel and plant-based diets could increase the net benefits of the transition to zero emissions.

避免难以控制的气候变化意味着必须迅速减少全球温室气体排放。碳价格和技术发展对实现这种减排至关重要。然而,偏好的变化很少被考虑在内,尽管其他主要的社会经济转型——比如减少吸烟和酒驾——的成功部分是因为偏好的改变。本文考察了气候政策引起的消费者偏好变化的影响。我们表明,如果认识到偏好可以内生于低碳政策,就可以更好地设计低碳政策。例如,如果碳税挤占或排挤社会偏好,就必须对其进行调整,以实现既定目标。此外,当城市建筑环境改变出行偏好时,如果忽视这种影响,低碳基础设施投资的价值可能会被低估。第三,政策引发的对积极出行和植物性饮食偏好的改变可能会增加向零排放过渡的净收益。
{"title":"The economics of climate change with endogenous preferences","authors":"Linus Mattauch ,&nbsp;Cameron Hepburn ,&nbsp;Fiona Spuler ,&nbsp;Nicholas Stern","doi":"10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101312","DOIUrl":"10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101312","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p>Avoiding unmanageable climate change implies that global greenhouse gas emissions<span> must be reduced rapidly. Carbon prices and technological development are essential to deliver such reductions. Changes in preferences, however, are rarely considered, even though other major socioeconomic transitions – such as those from reducing smoking and drink-driving – have succeeded partly because preferences have changed. This article examines the impact of climate policy-induced changes in consumers’ preferences. We show that low-carbon policies could be better designed if it is recognised that preferences can be endogenous to such policies. For instance, carbon taxes must be adjusted, if they crowd-in or -out social preferences, to achieve a given target. Further, when the urban built environment changes mobility preferences, the value of low-carbon infrastructure investments can be underestimated if such effects are ignored. Third, policy-induced changes in preferences for active travel and plant-based diets could increase the net benefits of the transition to zero emissions.</span></p></div>","PeriodicalId":47952,"journal":{"name":"Resource and Energy Economics","volume":"69 ","pages":"Article 101312"},"PeriodicalIF":2.9,"publicationDate":"2022-08-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"43013254","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 10
Confronting climate change: Adaptation vs. migration in Small Island Developing States 应对气候变化:小岛屿发展中国家的适应与移民
IF 2.9 3区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-08-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101301
Lesly Cassin , Paolo Melindi-Ghidi , Fabien Prieur

This paper examines the adaptation policy of Small Island Developing States (SIDS) facing climate change. We consider a dynamic economy with the following ingredients: (i) natural capital is an input in local production that is degraded as a result of climate change; (ii) the government has two instruments to cope with climate-related damages: it can adjust the population size thanks to migration policies and/or it can undertake adaptation measures in order to slow the degradation of natural assets; (iii) expatriates send remittances back home. We identify two critical conditions on the fundamentals of the economy that helps understand the features of the optimal policy. We especially show that in most situations, the migration policy is a valuable instrument. Calibrating the model for Caribbean SIDS, we find that the optimal policy of the Caribbean region displays heterogeneity, that is explained by the different degradation rate, population size, and endowment in natural capital. We also highlight that the higher the climate damages, the higher the incentives to conduct an active adaptation policy, combining conventional adaptation actions and migration.

本文研究了小岛屿发展中国家面对气候变化的适应政策。我们认为一个充满活力的经济具有以下要素:(i)自然资本是当地生产的投入,但由于气候变化而退化;(ii)政府有两种手段来应对与气候相关的损害:它可以通过移民政策来调整人口规模和/或采取适应措施以减缓自然资产的退化;(三)外派人员向国内汇款。我们确定了经济基本面的两个关键条件,这有助于理解最优政策的特征。我们特别表明,在大多数情况下,移民政策是一个有价值的工具。通过对加勒比小岛屿发展中国家的模型进行校正,我们发现加勒比地区的最优政策表现出异质性,这可以用不同的退化率、人口规模和自然资本禀赋来解释。我们还强调,气候损害越严重,就越有动力采取积极的适应政策,将传统的适应行动与移民相结合。
{"title":"Confronting climate change: Adaptation vs. migration in Small Island Developing States","authors":"Lesly Cassin ,&nbsp;Paolo Melindi-Ghidi ,&nbsp;Fabien Prieur","doi":"10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101301","DOIUrl":"10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101301","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p>This paper examines the adaptation policy of Small Island Developing States (SIDS) facing climate change. We consider a dynamic economy with the following ingredients: <em>(i)</em> natural capital is an input in local production that is degraded as a result of climate change; <em>(ii)</em> the government has two instruments to cope with climate-related damages: it can adjust the population size thanks to migration policies and/or it can undertake adaptation measures in order to slow the degradation of natural assets; <em>(iii)</em><span><span><span> expatriates send remittances back home. We identify two critical conditions on the fundamentals of the economy that helps understand the features of the </span>optimal policy. We especially show that in most situations, the migration policy is a valuable instrument. Calibrating the model for Caribbean SIDS, we find that the optimal policy of the Caribbean region displays heterogeneity, that is explained by the different </span>degradation rate, population size, and endowment in natural capital. We also highlight that the higher the climate damages, the higher the incentives to conduct an active adaptation policy, combining conventional adaptation actions and migration.</span></p></div>","PeriodicalId":47952,"journal":{"name":"Resource and Energy Economics","volume":"69 ","pages":"Article 101301"},"PeriodicalIF":2.9,"publicationDate":"2022-08-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"49320566","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 4
One or two non-fossil technologies in the decarbonized transport sector? 在脱碳运输领域使用一两种非化石燃料技术?
IF 2.9 3区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-08-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101314
Gøril L. Andreassen , Knut Einar Rosendahl

What factors determine whether policymakers should promote one or more technologies in a decarbonized road transport sector, and what policies should governments choose? We investigate these questions theoretically and numerically through a static, partial equilibrium model for the road transport market. We find that one important factor is how close substitutes the two vehicle technologies are. Further, the number of vehicles of one technology depends on the number of vehicles of the other technology, both in the market and in the first-best solution. The first-best policy involves a subsidy of the markup on charging and filling, where the markup is higher the more utility increases with the number of stations. However, as there are several possible market equilibria, additional policies may be needed to avoid an unwanted lock-in.

哪些因素决定决策者是否应该在脱碳道路运输部门推广一种或多种技术?政府应该选择什么样的政策?我们通过一个静态的、部分均衡的道路运输市场模型从理论上和数值上研究了这些问题。我们发现一个重要的因素是两种汽车技术的替代程度。此外,一种技术的车辆数量取决于另一种技术的车辆数量,无论是在市场上还是在最佳解决方案中。最佳政策包括对充电和加油的加价进行补贴,随着充电站数量的增加,效用增加越多,加价越高。然而,由于存在几种可能的市场均衡,可能需要额外的政策来避免不必要的锁定。
{"title":"One or two non-fossil technologies in the decarbonized transport sector?","authors":"Gøril L. Andreassen ,&nbsp;Knut Einar Rosendahl","doi":"10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101314","DOIUrl":"10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101314","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p>What factors determine whether policymakers should promote one or more technologies in a decarbonized road transport sector, and what policies should governments choose? We investigate these questions theoretically and numerically through a static, partial equilibrium model for the road transport market. We find that one important factor is how close substitutes the two vehicle technologies are. Further, the number of vehicles of one technology depends on the number of vehicles of the other technology, both in the market and in the first-best solution. The first-best policy involves a subsidy of the markup on charging and filling, where the markup is higher the more utility increases with the number of stations. However, as there are several possible market equilibria, additional policies may be needed to avoid an unwanted lock-in.</p></div>","PeriodicalId":47952,"journal":{"name":"Resource and Energy Economics","volume":"69 ","pages":"Article 101314"},"PeriodicalIF":2.9,"publicationDate":"2022-08-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0928765522000318/pdfft?md5=cb96cc30fd852dcd36f87c08c0287d07&pid=1-s2.0-S0928765522000318-main.pdf","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"45126280","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Optimal protected area implementation under spillover effects 溢出效应下的最优保护区实施
IF 2.9 3区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-05-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101284
S. Schwartz , J. Choumert-Nkolo , J.-L. Combes , P. Combes-Motel , E. Kere

This paper determines the best political implementation level of protected areas in the presence of two spillover effects, the infrastructure and scarcity effects. We show that decentralized regulation always leads to an overall decrease in deforestation under the infrastructure effect but not under the scarcity effect. Centralized regulation always leads to a larger protected area than decentralized regulation under the scarcity effect, which is not always true under the infrastructure effect. Finally, we conduct a case study of the Brazilian Legal Amazônia and find that spillover effects matter in the size of protected area design.

本文确定了在基础设施和稀缺性两种溢出效应存在的情况下,保护区的最佳政治实施水平。我们发现,在基础设施效应下,分散监管总是导致森林砍伐的总体减少,而在稀缺性效应下则不会。在稀缺性效应下,集中式监管往往比分散式监管导致的保护区面积更大,而在基础设施效应下,情况并非总是如此。最后,我们对巴西法律Amazônia进行了案例研究,发现溢出效应与保护区设计的大小有关。
{"title":"Optimal protected area implementation under spillover effects","authors":"S. Schwartz ,&nbsp;J. Choumert-Nkolo ,&nbsp;J.-L. Combes ,&nbsp;P. Combes-Motel ,&nbsp;E. Kere","doi":"10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101284","DOIUrl":"10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101284","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p>This paper determines the best political implementation level of protected areas in the presence of two spillover effects, the infrastructure and scarcity effects. We show that decentralized regulation always leads to an overall decrease in deforestation under the infrastructure effect but not under the scarcity effect. Centralized regulation always leads to a larger protected area than decentralized regulation under the scarcity effect, which is not always true under the infrastructure effect. Finally, we conduct a case study of the Brazilian Legal Amazônia and find that spillover effects matter in the size of protected area design.</p></div>","PeriodicalId":47952,"journal":{"name":"Resource and Energy Economics","volume":"68 ","pages":"Article 101284"},"PeriodicalIF":2.9,"publicationDate":"2022-05-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"47150988","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Beyond marginal: Estimating the demand for water quality 超越边际:估计水质需求
IF 2.9 3区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-05-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101299
David Wolf , H. Allen Klaiber , Sathya Gopalakrishnan

Using micro-level data across Wisconsin covering over 100 inland lakes, we recover first- and second-stage hedonic welfare estimates for non-marginal changes in water quality. We overcome longstanding endogeneity concerns with Rosen (1974)’s second stage hedonic framework and recover slope estimates for water quality demand using instruments based on sorting behavior. For near lake Wisconsin households, we find the slope of their water quality demand function is bounded by − 2087 when imperfect instruments are employed, which is significantly more price inelastic than the naïve OLS estimate of − 895. Applying these estimates to a hypothetical policy scenario where water quality reduces by 24.2% due to a 30-year continuation of current trends, we find welfare losses of at least $7554 per household. These losses are 22% ($1658) more than what is predicted from marginal willingness to pay estimates recovered from the first-stage hedonic. For policymakers, our results highlight the importance of recovering underlying demand functions when evaluating non-marginal water quality improvements.

利用威斯康星州覆盖100多个内陆湖泊的微观数据,我们恢复了水质非边际变化的第一阶段和第二阶段的享乐福利估计。我们利用Rosen(1974)的第二阶段享乐框架克服了长期存在的内生性问题,并利用基于分选行为的工具恢复了水质需求的坡度估计。对于威斯康星湖附近的家庭,我们发现当使用不完善的工具时,他们的水质需求函数的斜率为- 2087,这比naïve OLS估计的- 895的价格非弹性明显更强。将这些估计应用于假设的政策情景,即由于当前趋势持续30年,水质下降24.2%,我们发现每个家庭的福利损失至少为7554美元。这些损失比从第一阶段享乐中恢复的边际支付意愿预测的损失高出22%(1658美元)。对于政策制定者来说,我们的研究结果强调了在评估非边际水质改善时恢复潜在需求函数的重要性。
{"title":"Beyond marginal: Estimating the demand for water quality","authors":"David Wolf ,&nbsp;H. Allen Klaiber ,&nbsp;Sathya Gopalakrishnan","doi":"10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101299","DOIUrl":"10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101299","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p>Using micro-level data across Wisconsin covering over 100 inland lakes, we recover first- and second-stage hedonic welfare estimates for non-marginal changes in water quality. We overcome longstanding endogeneity concerns with Rosen (1974)’s second stage hedonic framework and recover slope estimates for water quality demand using instruments based on sorting behavior. For near lake Wisconsin households, we find the slope of their water quality demand function is bounded by − 2087 when imperfect instruments are employed, which is significantly more price inelastic than the naïve OLS estimate of − 895. Applying these estimates to a hypothetical policy scenario where water quality reduces by 24.2% due to a 30-year continuation of current trends, we find welfare losses of at least $7554 per household. These losses are 22% ($1658) more than what is predicted from marginal willingness to pay estimates recovered from the first-stage hedonic. For policymakers, our results highlight the importance of recovering underlying demand functions when evaluating non-marginal water quality improvements.</p></div>","PeriodicalId":47952,"journal":{"name":"Resource and Energy Economics","volume":"68 ","pages":"Article 101299"},"PeriodicalIF":2.9,"publicationDate":"2022-05-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"47245731","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Estimating welfare impacts of climate change using a discrete-choice model of land management: An application to western U.S. forestry 利用土地管理的离散选择模型估算气候变化对福利的影响:在美国西部林业的应用
IF 2.9 3区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-05-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101295
Yukiko Hashida , David J. Lewis

This study develops a method to estimate the welfare impacts of climate change on landowners using a discrete-choice econometric model of land management. We apply the method to forest management in the Pacific states of the U.S. and estimate welfare effects on the region that holds the largest current commercial value – western Oregon and Washington. We find evidence that a warmer and drier climate will induce an approximate 39 % loss in the economic value of timberland by 2050, though there is heterogeneity across space. The discrete-choice approach allows us to determine that the welfare losses are primarily driven by estimated losses to Douglas-fir, the most commercially valuable species. An alternative approach to welfare analysis from climate change is the Ricardian method, which gives conceptually similar estimates to the discrete-choice method. While we find similar empirical findings between the discrete-choice and Ricardian approaches, the discrete-choice approach provides more heterogeneity and somewhat larger negative welfare impacts. Our analysis is notable for providing the first empirical evidence that climate change can induce welfare losses to timberland owners, even while accounting for optimal adaptation.

本研究利用土地管理的离散选择计量经济模型,提出了一种估算气候变化对土地所有者福利影响的方法。我们将该方法应用于美国太平洋各州的森林管理,并估计了当前商业价值最大的地区(俄勒冈州西部和华盛顿州)的福利影响。我们发现证据表明,到2050年,温暖和干燥的气候将导致林地经济价值损失约39%,尽管在空间上存在异质性。离散选择方法使我们能够确定福利损失主要是由道格拉斯冷杉的估计损失驱动的,道格拉斯冷杉是最具商业价值的物种。从气候变化进行福利分析的另一种方法是李嘉图方法,它在概念上给出了与离散选择方法相似的估计。虽然我们在离散选择方法和李嘉图方法之间发现了类似的实证结果,但离散选择方法提供了更多的异质性和更大的负面福利影响。我们的分析值得注意的是,它首次提供了经验证据,表明气候变化会导致林地所有者的福利损失,即使考虑到最优适应。
{"title":"Estimating welfare impacts of climate change using a discrete-choice model of land management: An application to western U.S. forestry","authors":"Yukiko Hashida ,&nbsp;David J. Lewis","doi":"10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101295","DOIUrl":"10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101295","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p>This study develops a method to estimate the welfare impacts of climate change on landowners using a discrete-choice econometric model of land management. We apply the method to forest management in the Pacific states of the U.S. and estimate welfare effects on the region that holds the largest current commercial value – western Oregon and Washington. We find evidence that a warmer and drier climate will induce an approximate 39 % loss in the economic value of timberland by 2050, though there is heterogeneity across space. The discrete-choice approach allows us to determine that the welfare losses are primarily driven by estimated losses to Douglas-fir, the most commercially valuable species. An alternative approach to welfare analysis from climate change is the Ricardian method, which gives conceptually similar estimates to the discrete-choice method. While we find similar empirical findings between the discrete-choice and Ricardian approaches, the discrete-choice approach provides more heterogeneity and somewhat larger negative welfare impacts. Our analysis is notable for providing the first empirical evidence that climate change can induce welfare losses to timberland owners, even while accounting for optimal adaptation.</p></div>","PeriodicalId":47952,"journal":{"name":"Resource and Energy Economics","volume":"68 ","pages":"Article 101295"},"PeriodicalIF":2.9,"publicationDate":"2022-05-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0928765522000124/pdfft?md5=dbe069ee0fdc2abb3ddbb6a009930e98&pid=1-s2.0-S0928765522000124-main.pdf","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"49297661","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"OA","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1
Drive less, drive better, or both? Behavioral adjustments to fuel price changes in Germany 少开车,开得好,还是两者兼而有之?德国燃料价格变化的行为调整
IF 2.9 3区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-05-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101292
Anna Alberini , Marco Horvath , Colin Vance

The demand for motor fuel should decline when its price rises, but how exactly does that happen? Do people drive less, do they drive more carefully to conserve fuel, or do they do both? To answer these questions, we use data from the German Mobility Panel from 2004 to 2019, taking advantage of the fluctuations in motor fuel prices over time and across locales to see how they affect Vehicle Kilometers Traveled (VKT) and on-road fuel economy (expressed in kilometers per liter) for gasoline and diesel cars. Our reduced-form regressions show that while the VKTs driven by gasoline cars decrease when the price of gasoline rises, there is virtually no response among diesel cars. Likewise, the on-road fuel economy is largely unresponsive to fuel price changes, irrespective of the fuel type. Since the price elasticity of fuel consumption is the difference between the price elasticity of VKT and the price elasticity of the fuel economy, our results suggest that the fuel economy might be the “weakest link” of price-based policies that seek to address environmental externalities.

当汽车燃料价格上涨时,对汽车燃料的需求应该会下降,但这究竟是怎么发生的呢?人们是少开车,还是更小心地开车以节省燃料,还是两者兼而有之?为了回答这些问题,我们使用了德国交通小组2004年至2019年的数据,利用汽车燃料价格随时间和地区的波动,来了解它们如何影响汽油和柴油汽车的车辆行驶公里数(VKT)和道路燃油经济性(以公里每升表示)。我们的简化形式回归表明,虽然汽油车驱动的VKT在汽油价格上涨时会下降,但柴油车几乎没有反应。同样,无论燃油类型如何,道路燃油经济性在很大程度上对燃油价格变化没有反应。由于燃料消耗的价格弹性是VKT的价格弹性和燃料经济性的价格弹性之间的差异,我们的研究结果表明,燃料经济性可能是寻求解决环境外部性的基于价格的政策中“最薄弱的一环”。
{"title":"Drive less, drive better, or both? Behavioral adjustments to fuel price changes in Germany","authors":"Anna Alberini ,&nbsp;Marco Horvath ,&nbsp;Colin Vance","doi":"10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101292","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101292","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p>The demand for motor fuel should decline when its price rises, but how exactly does that happen? Do people drive less, do they drive more carefully to conserve fuel, or do they do both? To answer these questions, we use data from the German Mobility Panel from 2004 to 2019, taking advantage of the fluctuations in motor fuel prices over time and across locales to see how they affect Vehicle Kilometers Traveled (VKT) and on-road fuel economy (expressed in kilometers per liter) for gasoline and diesel cars. Our reduced-form regressions show that while the VKTs driven by gasoline cars decrease when the price of gasoline rises, there is virtually no response among diesel cars. Likewise, the on-road fuel economy is largely unresponsive to fuel price changes, irrespective of the fuel type. Since the price elasticity of fuel consumption is the difference between the price elasticity of VKT and the price elasticity of the fuel economy, our results suggest that the fuel economy might be the “weakest link” of price-based policies that seek to address environmental externalities.</p></div>","PeriodicalId":47952,"journal":{"name":"Resource and Energy Economics","volume":"68 ","pages":"Article 101292"},"PeriodicalIF":2.9,"publicationDate":"2022-05-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"72290572","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Discriminatory subsidies for energy-efficient technologies and the role of envy 对节能技术的歧视性补贴和嫉妒的作用
IF 2.9 3区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-05-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101298
Valeria Fanghella , Corinne Faure , Marie-Charlotte Guetlein , Joachim Schleich

Discriminatory subsidies, that is, subsidies for which only a subset of the population is eligible, are widespread. However, research on social preferences suggests that non-eligible households may negatively respond to these subsidies. We investigate both eligible and non-eligible households’ response to discriminatory subsidies for smart thermostats using a discrete choice experiment with 3071 owner-occupiers from France and Romania. Households are randomly exposed to discriminatory subsidies through a between-subject design that manipulates two factors: type of discrimination (positive or negative) and eligibility criteria (based on geographical location or on household characteristics). A control condition (uniform subsidy) is also included. In addition, we elicit envy via an incentivized game in the sample from France. Our results show that eligible households are more likely to adopt a smart thermostat, regardless of whether the subsidy is uniform or discriminatory. By contrast, non-eligible households are less likely to adopt it, especially when eligibility criteria are based on household characteristics. We find no evidence for a moderating effect of envy.

歧视性补贴,即只有一小部分人口有资格获得的补贴,是普遍存在的。然而,对社会偏好的研究表明,不符合条件的家庭可能会对这些补贴作出负面反应。通过对来自法国和罗马尼亚的3071名自住业主进行离散选择实验,我们调查了符合条件和不符合条件的家庭对智能恒温器歧视性补贴的反应。家庭通过操纵两个因素的主体间设计随机暴露于歧视性补贴中:歧视类型(积极或消极)和资格标准(基于地理位置或家庭特征)。还包括一个控制条件(统一补贴)。此外,我们在法国的样本中通过一个激励游戏来引发嫉妒。我们的研究结果表明,无论补贴是统一的还是歧视性的,符合条件的家庭更有可能采用智能恒温器。相比之下,不符合条件的家庭不太可能采用它,特别是当资格标准是基于家庭特征时。我们没有发现嫉妒有调节作用的证据。
{"title":"Discriminatory subsidies for energy-efficient technologies and the role of envy","authors":"Valeria Fanghella ,&nbsp;Corinne Faure ,&nbsp;Marie-Charlotte Guetlein ,&nbsp;Joachim Schleich","doi":"10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101298","DOIUrl":"10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101298","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p>Discriminatory subsidies, that is, subsidies for which only a subset of the population is eligible, are widespread. However, research on social preferences suggests that non-eligible households may negatively respond to these subsidies. We investigate both eligible and non-eligible households’ response to discriminatory subsidies for smart thermostats using a discrete choice experiment with 3071 owner-occupiers from France and Romania. Households are randomly exposed to discriminatory subsidies through a between-subject design that manipulates two factors: type of discrimination (positive or negative) and eligibility criteria (based on geographical location or on household characteristics). A control condition (uniform subsidy) is also included. In addition, we elicit envy via an incentivized game in the sample from France. Our results show that eligible households are more likely to adopt a smart thermostat, regardless of whether the subsidy is uniform or discriminatory. By contrast, non-eligible households are less likely to adopt it, especially when eligibility criteria are based on household characteristics. We find no evidence for a moderating effect of envy.</p></div>","PeriodicalId":47952,"journal":{"name":"Resource and Energy Economics","volume":"68 ","pages":"Article 101298"},"PeriodicalIF":2.9,"publicationDate":"2022-05-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"46003793","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2
Cross-country spillovers of renewable energy promotion—The case of Germany 可再生能源推广的跨国溢出效应——以德国为例
IF 2.9 3区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-05-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101293
Jan Abrell , Mirjam Kosch

Electricity generation based on renewable energy (RE) sources such as wind and solar replace the most expensive generators that often rely on fossil fuels. In response to RE promotion, wholesale electricity prices and carbon emissions are therefore expected to decrease. In interconnected electricity systems, this so-called merit-order effect stimulates a change in electricity trade flows. Therefore, conventional generation and prices in neighboring countries are also likely to decrease. The impact of these trade reactions on carbon offsets is ambiguous and depends on installed generation and interconnector capacities. Moreover, the cross-border merit-order effect causes opposing effects on consumers and producers: generators’ profits decline, while consumers benefit from lower electricity costs and an increase in the consumer surplus. Using a rich data set of hourly technology-specific generation and wholesale market price data for ten central European countries, we estimate the domestic and cross-border impacts of German RE for the years 2015–2020. We find that German RE generation offset 79–113 MtCO2 per year. The major emission effect took place in Germany (64–99 MtCO2). The average cost of emission offset of 212–321/t were almost entirely borne by German market participants. Neighboring countries do not bear costs, but a significant shift from producer to consumer rents is observed.

基于风能和太阳能等可再生能源的发电取代了通常依赖化石燃料的最昂贵的发电机。因此,为了应对可再生能源的推广,预计批发电价和碳排放量将下降。在相互连接的电力系统中,这种所谓的择优顺序效应刺激了电力贸易流的变化。因此,邻国的常规发电量和价格也可能下降。这些贸易反应对碳抵消的影响是模糊的,取决于发电装机和互联线路的容量。此外,跨境优序效应对消费者和生产者产生了相反的影响:发电商的利润下降,而消费者则从较低的电力成本和消费者盈余的增加中受益。使用10个中欧国家的每小时技术特定发电和批发市场价格数据的丰富数据集,我们估计了德国可再生能源在2015-2020年的国内和跨境影响。我们发现德国可再生能源发电偏移量为79–113 MtCO2每年。主要的排放影响发生在德国(64–99 MtCO2)。212–321欧元/吨的排放抵消平均成本几乎完全由德国市场参与者承担。邻国不承担成本,但观察到租金从生产者向消费者的显著转变。
{"title":"Cross-country spillovers of renewable energy promotion—The case of Germany","authors":"Jan Abrell ,&nbsp;Mirjam Kosch","doi":"10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101293","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101293","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p>Electricity generation based on renewable energy (RE) sources such as wind and solar replace the most expensive generators that often rely on fossil fuels. In response to RE promotion, wholesale electricity prices and carbon emissions are therefore expected to decrease. In interconnected electricity systems, this so-called merit-order effect stimulates a change in electricity trade flows. Therefore, conventional generation and prices in neighboring countries are also likely to decrease. The impact of these trade reactions on carbon offsets is ambiguous and depends on installed generation and interconnector capacities. Moreover, the cross-border merit-order effect causes opposing effects on consumers and producers: generators’ profits decline, while consumers benefit from lower electricity costs and an increase in the consumer surplus. Using a rich data set of hourly technology-specific generation and wholesale market price data for ten central European countries, we estimate the domestic and cross-border impacts of German RE for the years 2015–2020. We find that German RE generation offset 79–113 MtCO<span><math><msub><mrow></mrow><mn>2</mn></msub></math></span> per year. The major emission effect took place in Germany (64–99 MtCO<span><math><msub><mrow></mrow><mn>2</mn></msub></math></span>). The average cost of emission offset of 212–321<span><math><mo>€</mo></math></span>/t were almost entirely borne by German market participants. Neighboring countries do not bear costs, but a significant shift from producer to consumer rents is observed.</p></div>","PeriodicalId":47952,"journal":{"name":"Resource and Energy Economics","volume":"68 ","pages":"Article 101293"},"PeriodicalIF":2.9,"publicationDate":"2022-05-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"72290573","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Environmental and socio-economic implications of woody biomass co-firing at coal-fired power plants 燃煤发电厂木质生物质共烧的环境和社会经济影响
IF 2.9 3区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS Pub Date : 2022-05-01 DOI: 10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101296
Paul Picciano , Francisco X. Aguilar , Dallas Burtraw , Ashkan Mirzaee

We apply a detailed power sector model to explore the near-term role of woody biomass co-firing at existing coal facilities in the Eastern US in the decarbonization of US electricity generation. We evaluate five public policy interventions: a biomass co-firing subsidy, two carbon emissions fees, and two clean energy standards. Treating woody biomass as a carbon neutral feedstock, we find co-firing weakly supports decarbonization. However, policies subsidizing co-firing can delay retirement of coal facilities and reduce generation from nuclear, natural gas, wind and solar. Consequently, corresponding sector-wide emissions of CO2 and SO2 may increase (slightly) due to greater utilization of coal plants including relatively inefficient facilities. We assume NOX emissions increase due to generation efficiency losses, but this remains uncertain. Due to higher emissions, a biomass subsidy for co-firing yields small (near zero) economic welfare losses, while in contrast other policies advance decarbonization and yield significant welfare gains. We find justification for biomass use from a local perspective based on first-order impacts on employment and economy activity, but less so air quality.

我们应用一个详细的电力部门模型来探索美国东部现有煤炭设施的木质生物质联合燃烧在美国发电脱碳中的近期作用。我们评估了五项公共政策干预措施:一项生物质联产补贴、两项碳排放费和两项清洁能源标准。将木质生物质作为碳中和的原料处理,我们发现共烧对脱碳的支持较弱。然而,补贴共烧的政策可能会推迟煤炭设施的退役,并减少核能、天然气、风能和太阳能的发电量。因此,由于燃煤电厂(包括相对低效的设施)的更多利用,相应的部门范围内的二氧化碳和二氧化硫排放量可能会(略有)增加。我们假设NOX排放量由于发电效率损失而增加,但这仍然不确定。由于排放量更高,对共烧的生物质补贴产生的经济福利损失很小(接近零),而相比之下,其他政策促进了脱碳,并产生了显著的福利收益。我们从当地的角度出发,根据对就业和经济活动的一阶影响,找到了使用生物质的理由,但对空气质量的影响较小。
{"title":"Environmental and socio-economic implications of woody biomass co-firing at coal-fired power plants","authors":"Paul Picciano ,&nbsp;Francisco X. Aguilar ,&nbsp;Dallas Burtraw ,&nbsp;Ashkan Mirzaee","doi":"10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101296","DOIUrl":"https://doi.org/10.1016/j.reseneeco.2022.101296","url":null,"abstract":"<div><p>We apply a detailed power sector model to explore the near-term role of woody biomass co-firing at existing coal facilities in the Eastern US in the decarbonization of US electricity generation. We evaluate five public policy interventions: a biomass co-firing subsidy, two carbon emissions fees, and two clean energy standards. Treating woody biomass as a carbon neutral feedstock, we find co-firing weakly supports decarbonization. However, policies subsidizing co-firing can delay retirement of coal facilities and reduce generation from nuclear, natural gas, wind and solar. Consequently, corresponding sector-wide emissions of CO<sub>2</sub> and SO<sub>2</sub> may increase (slightly) due to greater utilization of coal plants including relatively inefficient facilities. We assume NO<sub>X</sub> emissions increase due to generation efficiency losses, but this remains uncertain. Due to higher emissions, a biomass subsidy for co-firing yields small (near zero) economic welfare losses, while in contrast other policies advance decarbonization and yield significant welfare gains. We find justification for biomass use from a local perspective based on first-order impacts on employment and economy activity, but less so air quality.</p></div>","PeriodicalId":47952,"journal":{"name":"Resource and Energy Economics","volume":"68 ","pages":"Article 101296"},"PeriodicalIF":2.9,"publicationDate":"2022-05-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":null,"resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":"72290575","PeriodicalName":null,"FirstCategoryId":null,"ListUrlMain":null,"RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":"","EPubDate":null,"PubModel":null,"JCR":null,"JCRName":null,"Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
期刊
Resource and Energy Economics
全部 Acc. Chem. Res. ACS Applied Bio Materials ACS Appl. Electron. Mater. ACS Appl. Energy Mater. ACS Appl. Mater. Interfaces ACS Appl. Nano Mater. ACS Appl. Polym. Mater. ACS BIOMATER-SCI ENG ACS Catal. ACS Cent. Sci. ACS Chem. Biol. ACS Chemical Health & Safety ACS Chem. Neurosci. ACS Comb. Sci. ACS Earth Space Chem. ACS Energy Lett. ACS Infect. Dis. ACS Macro Lett. ACS Mater. Lett. ACS Med. Chem. Lett. ACS Nano ACS Omega ACS Photonics ACS Sens. ACS Sustainable Chem. Eng. ACS Synth. Biol. Anal. Chem. BIOCHEMISTRY-US Bioconjugate Chem. BIOMACROMOLECULES Chem. Res. Toxicol. Chem. Rev. Chem. Mater. CRYST GROWTH DES ENERG FUEL Environ. Sci. Technol. Environ. Sci. Technol. Lett. Eur. J. Inorg. Chem. IND ENG CHEM RES Inorg. Chem. J. Agric. Food. Chem. J. Chem. Eng. Data J. Chem. Educ. J. Chem. Inf. Model. J. Chem. Theory Comput. J. Med. Chem. J. Nat. Prod. J PROTEOME RES J. Am. Chem. Soc. LANGMUIR MACROMOLECULES Mol. Pharmaceutics Nano Lett. Org. Lett. ORG PROCESS RES DEV ORGANOMETALLICS J. Org. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. J. Phys. Chem. A J. Phys. Chem. B J. Phys. Chem. C J. Phys. Chem. Lett. Analyst Anal. Methods Biomater. Sci. Catal. Sci. Technol. Chem. Commun. Chem. Soc. Rev. CHEM EDUC RES PRACT CRYSTENGCOMM Dalton Trans. Energy Environ. Sci. ENVIRON SCI-NANO ENVIRON SCI-PROC IMP ENVIRON SCI-WAT RES Faraday Discuss. Food Funct. Green Chem. Inorg. Chem. Front. Integr. Biol. J. Anal. At. Spectrom. J. Mater. Chem. A J. Mater. Chem. B J. Mater. Chem. C Lab Chip Mater. Chem. Front. Mater. Horiz. MEDCHEMCOMM Metallomics Mol. Biosyst. Mol. Syst. Des. Eng. Nanoscale Nanoscale Horiz. Nat. Prod. Rep. New J. Chem. Org. Biomol. Chem. Org. Chem. Front. PHOTOCH PHOTOBIO SCI PCCP Polym. Chem.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
0
微信
客服QQ
Book学术公众号 扫码关注我们
反馈
×
意见反馈
请填写您的意见或建议
请填写您的手机或邮箱
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
现在去查看 取消
×
提示
确定
Book学术官方微信
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术
文献互助 智能选刊 最新文献 互助须知 联系我们:info@booksci.cn
Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。
Copyright © 2023 Book学术 All rights reserved.
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号 京ICP备2023020795号-1